Skip to main content

Full text of "Mohammedan theories of finance; with an Introduction to Mohammedan law and a bibliography"

See other formats


inn 


" 


MOHAMMEDAN    THEORIES 
OF  FINANCE 


WITH  AN 


Introduction  to  Mohammedan  Law 
and  a  Bibliography 


. 

NICOLAS  P.1  AGHNIDES 

B.  L.  (OonttantinopU) 
A.  M.  (Columbia) 


j 


SUBMITTED    IN    PARTIAL    FULFILMENT    OF    THE    REQUIREMENTS 

FOR    THE    DEGREE    OF    DOCTOR    OF    PHILOSOPHY 

IN  THE 

FACULTY  OF  POLITICAL  SCIENCE 
COLUMBIA  UNIVERSITY 


NEW  YORK 
1916 


COPYRIGHT,  1916 
BY 

THE  FACULTY  OF  POLITICAL  SCIENCE  OF 
COLUMBIA  UNIVERSITY,  NEW  YORK 


PREFACE 

THE  raison  d'etre  of  this  dissertation  is  found  in  the  in- 
trinsic interest  of  its  subject  and  in  the  fact  that  this  subject 
up  to  the  present  time  has  never  been  treated  in  its  entirety 
and  for  its  own  sake.  There  is  indeed  some  literature 
bearing  upon  it  in  European  translations  of  Moham- 
medan legal  text-books,  but  the  treatment  of  finance  in  these 
text-books  is  naturally  terse  and  incidental  and  covers  but 
a  portion  of  the  entire  subject.  Hamilton's  English  trans- 
lation of  the  Hidayah  is  a  case  in  point.  The  few  chapters 
in  it  bearing  on  finance  are  at  times  very  inaccurate  —  a 
defect  explained  by  the  fact  that  the  translation  was  made 
from  a  Persian  translation  of  the  original  Arabic  instead 
of  direct  from  the  original — and  lack  all  historical  perspec- 
tive. Moreover,  they  do  not  give  a  full  insight  into  the 
arguments  invoked  in  support  of  the  particular  views.  The 
translations  into  the  other  European  languages  unfortun- 
ately cannot  lay  claim  to  greater  perfection,  the  chief  dif- 
ference among  them  being  their  varying  degree  of  accuracy. 

In  this  dissertation  an  attempt  has  been  made  to  give  a 
comprehensive  exposition  of  the  Mohammedan  financial 
theories  in  their  entirety  with  especial  emphasis  when  pos- 
sible on  the  reasons  underlying  them.  To  this  end  all  the 
available  primary  sources  have  been  used  and  the  divergent 
views  which  they  contain  frequently  cited.  A  body  of 
ancient  theories,  however,  no  matter  how  fully  set  forth, 
would  convey  but  little  meaning  to  the  modern  mind,  unless 
the  origin  of  those  theories  were  indicated  and  their  practical 
bearings  pointed  out.  These  two  last  needs  are  met  by 

5 


6  PREFACE 

Parts  I.  and  III.,  Part  II.  being  devoted  to  the  theories 
themselves. 

The  general  purpose  of  Part  I.  is  to  explain  the  terms 
and  concepts  of  Part  II.  More  particularly,  with  a  view 
to  settling  the  question  of  the  origin  of  Mohammedan 
financial  theories,  it  attempts  to  determine  the  degree  to 
which  those  theories,  as  a  matter  of  theoretical  possibility, 
were  subject  to  foreign  influences.  Its  title,  Introduction 
to  Mohammedan  Law,  seems  at  first  blush  to  bear  no 
relation  to  these  purposes.  The  connection,  however, 
becomes  at  once  clear  when  it  is  remembered  that  Mo- 
hammedan financial  theory  is  but  an  integral  part  of 
fiqh  or  Mohammedan  law  in  general.  An  explanation 
of  the  origin  of  fiqh  is,  therefore,  also  an  explanation  of 
the  origin  of  Mohammedan  financial  theory.  According 
to  the  Mohammedan  doctors  fiqh  has  been  derived  from  the 
revealed  sources  of  the  Koran  and  the  Prophetic  conduct 
or  sunnah  exclusively,  in  conformity  with  a  body  of  prin- 
ciples called  usul-al-fiqh.  This  construction  would  seem  to 
preclude  any  foreign  influence  in  the  development  of 
Mohammedan  law.  It  was,  therefore,  to  these  principles 
collectively  called  usul-al-fiqh  that  we  had  to  turn  to  deter- 
mine how  far  they  allowed  foreign  ideas  to  enter  fiqh. 

The  three  conventional  parts  of  the  Mohammedan 
treatises  on  usul-al-fiqh  are :  ( i )  an  introduction  on  the  in- 
terpretation of  terms  (tafsir  wa  ta'wll)  ;  (2)  an  explanation 
of  the  principles  (arkan  or  usul)  on  the  basis  of  which 
Mohammedan  law  (fiqh)  is  derived  from  the  above  men- 
tioned revealed  sources;  (3)  an  exposition  of  the  values 
(ahkam)  or  legal  provisions  so  derived.  Of  these  parts,  the 
first  and  third  have  been  practically  omitted.  The  first, 
because  as  regards  the  question  of  the  extent  to  which 
foreign  influences  were  allowed  to  enter  the  structure  of  fiqh, 
it  is,  in  comparison  with  the  second,  of  negligible  import- 


PREFACE 


ance;  the  third,  because  it  is  not  quite  relevant  to  the  pur- 
pose in  view.  However,  inasmuch  as  a  secondary  purpose 
of  Part  I.  is  to  offer  a  background  for  the  understanding 
of  Part  II.,  an  exception  to  the  rule  was  made  in  incor- 
porating from  this  third  part  the  chapter  entitled  Classifica- 
tion of  the  Sharl'ah  Values.  The  two  purposes  mentioned 
will  not  account  for  every  line  of  Part  I.,  but  it  was  con- 
sidered expedient,  at  the  risk  of  adding  to  the  length  of  the 
book,  to  make  Part  I.  a  fairly  comprehensive  introduction  to 
Mohammedan  law.  The  absence  of  such  an  introduction 
in  any  language,  more  than  warranted,  in  the  author's 
opinion,  the  few  additional  pages  which  might  have  been 
spared  the  reader. 

The  purpose  of  Part  II.,  the  main  part  of  the  book,  is  to 
present  in  an  orderly  and  clear  fashion  the  views  and 
opinions  of  the  Mohammedan  doctors  in  regard  to  financial 
theory.  Part  II.  concerns  itself,  accordingly,  with  theory 
exclusively,  purely  descriptive  and  historical  matter  being 
carefully  avoided.  The  reader  should,  therefore,  remember 
that,  whether  or  not  included  within  quotation  marks,  the 
views  expressed  in  Part  II.  are  merely  the  views  of  the 
Mohammedan  doctors  and  as  such  they  need  not  always 
coincide  with  the  facts,  nor  agree  with  the  conclusions 
reached  in  Part  III. 

The  purpose  of  Part  III.,  finally,  is  to  inquire  into  the 
origins  of  Mohammedan  financial  practice  and  trace  out  its 
relation  to  Mohammedan  financial  theory.  Part  III.,  then, 
tests  by  the  light  of  history  the  conclusions  reached  in  Part 
I.  as  to  the  theoretical  possibilities. 

The  doctrines  and  views  brought  together  in  this  boo 
are  it  must  be  borne  in  mind,  the  orthodox,  particularly  the 
Hanifite,  and  to  a  less  extent,  the  Shafiite  and  Malikite  ones. 
The  views  of  other  schools  are  only  occasionally  mentioned, 
not  only  because  they  have  enjoyed  but  scant  recognition, 


8  PREFACE 

but  also  because  the  sources  concerning  them  are  few  and 
inadequate.  In  quoting  the  views  of  the  doctors,  the  source 
of  each  view  has  been  indicated  whenever  it  was  considered 
important  or  was  found  in  only  one  or  few  of  the  sources. 
In  most  cases,  however,  it  was  deemed  sufficient  to  indicate 
the  sources  consulted  collectively,  either  at  the  beginning 
of  the  section  or  the  end  of  the  paragraph.  In  referring 
to  the  sources  a  shorter  title,  usually  the  one  employed  by 
the  Mohammedan  doctors,  has  been  used.  The  full  title  of 
each  reference  will  be  found  in  an  alphabetical  list  at  the 
end  of  the  book.  As  an  aid  to  the  reader,  the  gist  of  the  dis- 
cussion has  been  indicated  by  the  words  printed  in  bold 
faced  type.  It  is  hoped  that  this  device  and  the  analytical 
table  of  contents  and  topical  index  that  have  been  supplied 
will  permit  ready  reference  to  any  part  of  the  discussion. 

In  transliterating  the  Arabic  words  the  object  has  been 
to  reproduce  exactly  their  spelling,  but  only  to  approximate 
their  pronunciation.  Therefore,  in  order  to  avoid  con- 
fusion for  those  ignorant  of  Arabic,  the  inflective  Arabic 
endings,  except  in  the  case  of  certain  pronouns,  have  been 
omitted.  As  regards  the  method  of  transliteration  itself, 
the  one  followed  by  most  European  orientalists  has  been 
adhered  to,  barring  a  few  slight  modifications  making  for 
greater  simplicity  and  better  conforming  to  the  peculiarities 
of  English.  Thus,  instead  of  the  two  usual  diacritical  signs, 
the  point  and  the  dash,  only  the  dash  has  been  used.  Gh  has 
been  replaced  by  g,  and  u  (standing  for  silent  waw  as  in 
quam)  by  w.  The  pronouncing  value  of  the  different  letters 
is  approximately  as  follows :  y  is  to  be  pronounced  always  as 
a  consonant  as  in  year ;  g  as  gh  in  Buckingham ;  all  the  single 
consonants,  whether  or  not  underlined,  must  be  pronounced 
as  in  English;  th  as  in  thorn',  dh  like  th  in  then;  sh  as  in 
should ;  kh  like  ch  in  the  Scottish  word  loch ;  the  signs  '  and  ' 
may  be  ignored ;  all  the  vowels  are  to  be  pronounced  as  in 


PREFACE  9 

French,  the  accented  ones  longer.  Consecutive  consonants 
have  been  set  off  by  a  hyphen,  when  necessary,  to  indicate 
that  they  are  not  to  be  pronounced  as  one  letter.  In  general, 
combinations  of  words  used  currently  as  single  names,  as 
usill-al-fiqh  or  bayt-al-mal,  have  been  treated  as  single 
words.  Furthermore  the  article  al  has  always  been  united 
to  the  word  it  defines.  Where  capitals  or  bold  faced  type 
are  used  the  accents  are  omitted. 

The  author  wants  to  take  this  opportunity  to  express  his 
thanks  to  all  those  who  have  aided  him  in  his  work,  and 
particularly  to  Professor  R.  J.  H.  Gottheil.  He  feels  es- 
pecially grateful  to  Professors  H.  R.  Seager  and  V.  G. 
Simkhovitch  for  assistance  with  the  proofs  and  to  Professor 
E.  R.  A.  Seligman,  but  for  whose  encouragement  this  work 
might  never  have  seen  the  light.  His  thanks  are  also  due 
to  the  authorities  of  the  Columbia  University  Library  and 
the  New  York  Public  Library  for  the  special  facilities 
which  they  have  afforded  him.  But  for  the  rich  collection  of 
Oriental  books  of  the  New  York  Public  Library,  the  prepar- 
ation of  this  dissertation  in  this  country,  would  have  been 
well-nigh  impossible. 

The  discussion  for  Christian  readers  of  Mohammedan 
institutions,  because  of  the  long  and  bitter  animosities  that 
have  separated  Christians  and  Mohammedans,  is  a  matter 
of  great  delicacy.  The  writer  has  sought  to  treat  with  ab- 
solute impartiality  all  of  the  topics  that  he  has  considered 
and  trusts  that  the  fact  that  he  was  reared  as  a  Christian 
has  been  so  fully  offset  by  his  strong  Mohammedan  sym- 
pathies that  he  has  attained  this  aim.  It  is  sincerely  hoped 
that  all  the  sources  consulted  have  been  given  due  credit 
and  that  the  instances  are  not  many  where  accuracy,  the 
chief  aim  of  the  author,  has  been  missed.  In  such  in- 
stances, the  pioneer  character  of  the  work  will  perhaps  be 
considered  sufficient  ground  for  indulgence. 


CONTENTS 


PART  I 

THE  BACKGROUND — INTRODUCTION  TO  MOHAMMEDAN 
LAW  AND  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

FACE 

CHAPTER  I 
PRELIMINARY  CONCEPTS 

Definitions  of  shari'ah,  sharl'ah  evidences,  shari'ah  value,  fiqh,  bases 
of  fiqh  and  ujul-al-fiqh ;  relation  of  the  latter  to  fiqh;  classification 
of  sciences;  relative  position  of  us&l-al-fiqh,  fiqh,  and  finance 23 

CHAPTER  II 
THE  FIRST  BASIS  OF  FIQH  :  THE  KORAN 

Definition;  the  two  periods  of  revelation;  the  meaning  of  Hijrah; 
its  effect  on  Islam;  nature  of  the  revelations;  codification  of  the 
Koran ;  commentaries  30 

CHAPTER  III 
THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNNAH  (PROPHETIC  CONDUCT) 

Sec.  I.  General  Considerations: 

Sunnah  an  important  source  of  law;  hadlth  and  its  difference 
from  sunnah;  latter  a  generic  term  for  custom;  bid'ah,  or  inno- 
vation, its  opposite;  great  importance  of  sunnah  after  Moham- 
med's death ;  resulting  inducements  to  falsification  of  sunnah ; 
memory  versus  writing;  the  science  of  hadiths;  collections  of 

hadiths;  commentaries  35 

Sec.  II.  The  Different  Kinds  of  the  Sunnah  with  Respect  to  Trans- 
mission : 

(i)  "Continuity"  of  sunnah;  (a)  the  mutawdtir;  its  defini- 
tion; three  necessary  conditions;  other  conditions;  how  to  tell 
that  conditions  have  been  met;  the  value  of  the  mutawdtir;  is 
knowledge  produced  by  the  mutawdtir  axiomatic?;  (b)  the 
mash-hur;  (c)  the  "individual";  (2)  "discontinuity"  of  sun- 
nah; (a)  "formal";  (b)  "real";  (i)  contradiction;  (ii)  defect 

in  the  transmitter 39 

II 


I2  CONTENTS 


Sec.  III.    Qualifications  Regarding  the  Transmitter  as  Such: 

(i)  The  "well-known"  transmitter,  (a)  who  is  a  faqlh,  (b) 

who  is  not  a  faqlh;  (2)  the  "  unknown  "  transmitter  48 

Sec.  IV.  Conditions  of  Retention  and  Transmission  49 

Sec.  V.    The  Impeachment  of  Hadiths: 

(A)  Impeachment  by  the  transmitter  himself:  (i)  express; 
(2)  implicit.  (B)  By  others:  (i)  the  -Companions;  (2)  the 
hadith-teachers :  (a)  the  impeachment  is  indefinite;  (b)  it  is  de- 
finite: (i)  motivated  by  partisan  spirit;  (ii)  not  so  motivated. 

(C)  Impeachment  by  some,  confirmation  by  others 51 

Sec.   VI.     Are  the   Rules    Concerning  the   Sunnah   an   Adequate 

Guarantee  of  its  Reliability? 

General  nature  of  these  rules;  theoretically,  a  mutawdtir  might 
be  no  stronger  than  a  mash-hur;  rules  concerning  the  "individ- 
ual" no  absolute  guarantee  of  its  truth;  rules  on  justice  and 
impeachment;  in  fact,  mutawdtir  superior  to  mash-hur,  and  latter 
to  "  individual  " ;  sunnah  on  the  whole  reliable 52 

CHAPTER  IV 

THE  THIRD  BASIS  OF  FIQH  :  THE  IJMA'  (THE  CONSENSUS  OF  THE 
COMMUNITY) 

Importance,  justification  and  denial  of  ijmd1;  ijma,  as  a  theory,  a 
later  product;  ijmd'  terminates  controversy;  some  divergence  of 
opinion  an  indication  of  God's  grace;  definition  and  formal  cause 
of  ijmd' ;  who  is  eligible  for  ijmd'^  conditions,  value,  abrogation, 
basis,  and  transmission  of  ijma  60 

CHAPTER  V 
THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  (ANALOGY) 

Sec.  I.    General  Considerations: 

At  first  no  special  rules  on  use  of  analogy;  the  two  tendencies 
in  Mohammedan  law;  the  hadith-folk,  and  the  ra'y-io\k;  contro- 
versy between  them  occasioned  by  Abu  Hamfah;  qiyds  identified 
with  ra'y;  dislike  of  hadit}i-fo\k  for  abstract  speculation  and 
scholastic  subtleties ;  qiyds  in  reality  curbed  use  of  ra'y  (personal 
opinion)  instead  of  fostering  it;  use  of  ra'y  restored  by  intro- 
duction of  istihsdn,  istishdb,  and  istisldh;  controversy  largely  a 
quibble  over  words ;  both  sides  used  personal  opinion,  though 
the  hadith-iolk  less;  qiyds  accepted  by  most  orthodox  schools; 
definition  of  qiyds;  justification  of  qiyds  and  arguments  for  and 
against  it  67 


CONTENTS  13 

TACK 

Sec.  II.     Is  It  Lawful  to  Investigate  the  "Effective"  Causes  of 

Divine  Prescriptions  ?  77 

Sec.  III.    How  to  Determine  the  "Effective"  Cause: 

To  be  an  "  effective  "  cause,  an  attribute  must  be  convenient ; 
also  "effective";  the  four  kinds  of  effectiveness;  the  tardi 
causes;  the  methods  of  tard  or  dawrdn,  and  tnasdlih  tnursalah. . .  80 

Sec.  IV.  The  Conditions  of  Qiyds 86 

CHAPTER  VI 

ABROGATION  AND  CONFLICT  OF  THE  EVIDENCES 

(i)  Abrogation;  conditions;  only  Koran  and  sunnah  can  abro- 
gate; (2)  conflict  without  preference;  what  is  done  in  case  of 
conflict  between  two  qiydses,  or  two  verses  of  the  Koran,  etc. ; 

(3)  conflict  of  evidences  unequal  by  virtue  of  a  secondary,  or 

(4)  an  essential  difference:  inequality  in  (a)  content,  (b)   sup- 
port          89 

CHAPTER  VII 

OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  LEGISLATION 
Sec.  I.    Istihsdn: 

The  four  kinds  of  istihsdn;  fourth  kind  condemned  by  al- 
Shafi'i  on  ground  that  it  is  a  case  of  using  personal  opinion ; 
Hanifites  contend  istihsdn  is  a  kind  of  qiyds;  contention  not 
borne  out  by  historical  records ;  a  later  fiction ;  even  granting 
this  fiction,  istihsdn  is  a  liberating  principle;  illustrations;  istib- 
sdn  personal  opinion  in  disguise 94 

Sec.  II.   The  Other  Principles : 

(i)  Istisldh',  the  three  kinds  of  "useful  purpose";  (2)  isti- 
jhdb;  the  extended  scope  given  to  it  by  al-Shafi'i;  (3)  the  sun- 
nah of  the  Companions;  its  great  importance;  the  sunnah  of  the 
Followers;  (4)  custom;  its  value  in  opposition  to  (a)  the  re- 
vealed texts,  (b)  the  doctors'  opinions;  (5)  the  previous  dispen- 
sations .  .  102 


I4  CONTENTS 


CHAPTER  VIII 
CLASSIFICATION  OF  THE  SHARI'AH  VALUES 

I.  The  shari'ah  value  consists  in  correlation  (rukn,  'illah,  sabab, 
shar^  'aldmah).  II.  It  does  not  consist  in  correlation:  (A)  It  is 
the  effect  (athar)  of  an  act;  (B)  the  quality  of  an  act:  (i)  em- 
phasis is  laid  on  the  "worldly  consideration"  (validity,  nullity, 
imperfection,  etc.)  ;  (2)  emphasis  is  laid  on  the  "  religious  con- 
sideration": (a)  'azimah:  (i)  fard;  (ii)  wdjib;  (iii)  sunnah 
and  no/?;  (iv)  mubdh;  (v)  makrah;  (vi)  hardm;  (b)  rukhsah. 
Performance  of  obligation  of  three  kinds:  (i)  add;  (2)  qadd; 
(3)  i'ddah  109 

CHAPTER  IX 

IjTIHAD   OR   THE   EXERCISE  OF    INDEPENDENT  THOUGHT 

Definition;  subject-matter;  scope;  obligation  of  mujtahid  to  exer- 
cise ijtihdd;  qualifications  of  the  mujtahids;  the  "splitting"  of 
ijtihdd,  or  general  education  versus  specialization;  limited  muj- 
tahids like  muqallids;  legal  effect  of  ijtihdd;  classes  of  mujta- 
hids; fiction  of  "closing  of  door  of  ijtihdd"  a  later  development 
due  to  historical  causes ;  no  theoretical  basis ;  classification  of 
doctors'  writings;  muqallids,  intermediate,  'dmtnis  lowest  in  in- 
tellectual hierarchy;  the  process  of  ifta;  the  mufti  who  is  not  a 
mujtahid;  who  is  a  mujtahid;  duties  of  the  'dmmis;  may  an 
'dmmi  follow  a  definite  school?  may  he  change  it?  taharri,  or 
resort  to  intuition 117 

CHAPTER  X 
THE  FiQH-ScHOOLS  AND  THEIR  FOUNDERS 

Fi<7/i-schools  result  of  conflicting  interests  and  opinions ;  most  im- 
portant schools;  origin  and  content  of  orthodoxy;  who  is  a  Mos- 
lem? three  classes  of  Moslems;  what  is  Islam,  faith  (imdn), 
and  kufr  (unbelief)  ?  differences  between  orthodox  schools 
mainly  in  field  of  fiqh;  the  Hanifites ;  Abu  Hanlfah;  the  charges 
igainst  him;  first  to  codify  Mohammedan  law  on  basis  of  qiyds; 
liberal  in  his  views;  Abu  Yusuf;  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan ;  the 
followers  of  the  school;  the  Malikites;  Malik  Ibn  Anas;  cham- 
pion of  hadith-folk ;  his  use  of  ra'y ;  his  followers ;  the  Shafiites ; 
al-Shafi'i;  his  emphasis  on  precedent;  his  eclecticism;  the  Han- 
balites ;  Ahmad  Ibn  Hanbal ;  his  conservatism ;  the  Zahirites ; 
Dawud  Ibn  'Ali ;  Al-Awza'i ;  al-Thawri  133 


CONTENTS 


15 

PAGE 


CHAPTER  XI 

CONCLUDING  REMARKS  148 

BIBLIOGRAPHY  157 

PART  II 

THE  FINANCIAL  THEORIES 

A-  Revenue 

CHAPTER  I  IQQ 

PRELIMINARY  REMARKS 
I.  Religious  Revenue 
CHAPTER  II 

THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 

Sec.  I.    General  Principles: 

Definition  of  zakdt;  zakdt  also  called  jadaqah;  obligation  and 
cause  of  zakdt;  nifdb;  real  and  hypothetical  productivity;  other 
requirements;  exemptions;  zakdt  becomes  due  upon  lapse  of 
year ;  "  dissolution "  of  year ;  must  nifdb  be  complete  through 
the  entire  year?  acquisition  during  year;  how  nifdb  is  reckoned; 
case  of  joint  ownership  in  cattle;  in  other  property;  lapse  of  zakdt 
debt ;  destruction ;  death  of  owner ;  apostasy ;  sale  of  animals  on 
which  zakdt  is  due ;  the  Taglib  tribe;  zakdt  of  converts;  of  rebels.  203 

Sec.  II.  The  Zakdt  of  Sawd'im  or  Flocks  and  Herds : 

What  animals  are  sawd'im;  how  their  nifdb  is  reckoned;  zakdt 
of  camels;  of  oxen  or  bulls  and  cows  (baqr)  ;  of  sheep  and 
goats;  of  horses;  case  of  mules  and  asses;  zakdt  of  the  young. . .  244 

Sec.  III.  The  Zakdt  of  Gold  and  Silver  and  the  Articles  of  Trade: 
Trade  zakdt  different  from  cattle  zakdt;  conflict  between  the 
two;  zakdt  of  gold  and  silver;  their  ni$db;  wrought  gold  and 
silver  like  bullion ;  ornaments ;  value  or  weight  in  payment  of 
zakdt;  alloys;  determination  of  zakdfs  amount;  use  of  Archi- 
medes' law;  articles  of  trade;  intention  of  trade  supported  by  an 
act;  what  are  articles  of  trade;  implied  intention  of  trade;  ex- 
amples; appraisal  of  articles  of  trade;  zakdt  of  claims;  three 
kinds  of  claims ;  zakdt  of  rentals  and  wages 261 


j6  CONTENTS 

FAO* 

Sec.  IV.  The  Zakdt  of  the  Produce  of  the  Earth  or  the  Tithe: 

Dispute  as  to  nature  of  tithe;  obligation  and  cause  of  tithe; 
property  subject  to  it;  nijdb;  appraisal  of  dates  and  grapes; 
rates;  consumption  before  payment  of  tithe;  lands  of  minors, 
etc.,  with  respect  to  tithe;  tithe  of  honey;  tithe  due  on  tithe  lands 
only;  combination  of  tithe  and  khardj;  habitations  and  ceme- 
teries; habitations  made  into  gardens;  springs  of  tar,  etc.;  lapse 
of  tithe;  tenant  in  regard  to  tithe;  case  of  free  lease;  the  Taglib 
tribe  282 

CHAPTER  III 
COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT 

Sec.  I.  The  Collectors  (General)  : 

Distinction  between  "  apparent "  and  "  non-apparent "  prop- 
erty; collectors'  jurisdiction;  failure  to  pay  sakdt;  case  of  un- 
just collectors;  concealment  of  sakdt;  classes,  qualifications  and 
powers  of  collectors;  collector's  delay;  owners'  contentions;  are 

receipts  necessary ;  collectors'  contentions,  etc 296 

Sec.  II.  The  'Ashirs  or  Collectors  on  the  Public  Road : 

Institution  justified  by  Hanifites  and  Malikites,  condemned  by 
Shafiites;  jurisdiction  of  'dshirs;  rates;  case  of  dhitnmis  and 
harbis;  tax  of  wine  and  pigs ;  perishable  goods ;  mukdtabs;  mu$d- 

ribs,  tribe  of  Taglib  314 

Sec.  III.  The  Discharge  of  the  Zakdt  Obligation  (General)  : 

Necessity  of  intention;  intention  by  the  sultan;  delay  in  pay- 
ment; advance  payment  of  zakdt;  of  tithe;  substitution  of  values; 
payment  of  zakdt  in  terms  of  claims ;  payment  to  rebels  and 

tyrants ;  to  others  than  beneficiaries  323 

Sec.  IV.  The  Place  of  Intuition  (Taharri)  in  the  Discharge  of  the 
Zakdt  Obligation    339 

Sec.  V.   The  Use  of  Cunning  in  the  Discharge  of  the  Zakdt  Obli- 
gation       342 

CHAPTER  IV 

THE  FINANCIAL  CONTRIBUTION  FOR  THE  CONDUCT  OF  HOLY  WAR  AND 

FOR  OTHER  PUBLIC  PURPOSES 
A 

II.  Secular  Revenue   348 


CONTENTS  I7 

rxcc 

CHAPTER  V 
PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS 

Sec.  I.  Classification  of  Persons : 

"  Moslem  world  " ;  "  enemy  world  " ;  "  world  of  allies  " ;  state 
of  war,  the  normal  state;  terminated  in  three  ways;  conversion; 
temporary  amdn;  perpetual  amdn;  should  infidels  be  allowed  to 
settle  in  "Moslem  world"  ;  how  perpetual  amdn  is  dissolved; 
effect  of  refusal  to  pay  jizyah;  four  classes  of  persons  354 

Sec.  II.  Classification  of  Lands : 

Tithe  lands;  tithe  water;  khardj  lands;  dhimmi  buying  land 
from  a  Taglabi ;  from  a  Moslem,  and  vice  versa;  a  third  class 
of  lands  359 

CHAPTER  VI 
THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX 

Meaning  of  term;  proportional,  and  fixed  khardj;  muqdta'oh 
khardj;  khardj  a  charge  on  land  irrespective  of  owner ;  rates  of 
fixed  khardj;  factors  determining  tax-bearing  capacity;  quality 
of  land;  kind  of  crop;  method  of  irrigation;  distance  to  markets; 
modes  of  assessment;  change  in  land's  productivity;  lands  lying 
fallow ;  change  of  crop ;  khardj  due  irrespective  of  cultivation ; 
nature  of  khardj  of  Egypt  and  Syria;  no  khardj  on  habitations; 
fixed  khardj  due  once  a  year;  lapse  of  khardj;  seller  versus 
buyer;  proportional  khardj;  tenant  versus  landlord;  debts  of 
khardj;  advance  payment ;  payment  to  rebels ;  currency  accepted 
for,  and  measures  used  in,  khardj;  dispute  between  taxpayer 
and  collector;  who  pays  cost  of  collection?;  officials  of  fa'y 
revenue  377 

CHAPTER  VII 
THE  JIZYAH  OR  POLL-TAX 

Meaning  of  term;  justification  of  jizyah;  who  may  pay  it;  two 
kinds;  rates;  persons  liable  to  it;  exemptions;  time  of  collection; 
lapse  of  jizyah ;  humiliation  in  collection  398 


!8  CONTENTS 

FAGB 

CHAPTER  VIII 
OTHER  SOURCES  OF  REVENUE 
Sec.  I.    The  Spoils  of  War: 

Options  of   calif  as   regards   spoils;   difference  between   land 
and  chattels;  where  and  how  spoils  are  divided;  giving  of  extra 

shares ;  public  treasury's  share  one-fifth  of  spoils  409 

Sec.  II.  The  Tax  on  Mines  and  Treasure-Trove  (Rikds)  : 

Dispute  as  to  nature  of  tax;  as  to  meaning  of  rikdz;  three 
kinds  of  mines;  only  first  kind  pays  tax;  pearls  and  other  sea 

products;  quicksilver;  treasure-trove;  three  kinds  413 

Sec.  III.  The  Tax  on  non-Moslem  Traders,  and  the  Estates  of  De- 
ceased Persons  422 

B.  Expenditure 
CHAPTER  IX 

THE  PUBLIC  TREASURY  AND  THE  MOHAMMEDAN  COUNTERPART  OF  A 

BUDGET 

Concept  of  public  treasury;  three  classes  of  revenue,  sadaqah  (re- 
ligious), booty,  and  fa'y;  points  of  resemblance  and  difference; 
revenue  forming  a  part  of  public  treasury;  detailed  list  of  assets 
of  public  treasury;  some  principles  concerning  expenditure;  case 
of  dhimmis;  of  real  estate ;  liabilities  of  public  treasury 423 

CHAPTER  X 

EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  (RELIGIOUS  REVENUE) 

Beneficiaries  of  zakdt  taxes:  the  poor;  indigent;  collectors;  mukd- 
tabs;  debtors;  "the  way  of  God";  wayfarers;  "  mu'allafah 
qulitbuhum  " ;  how  beneficiaries  are  determined ;  mode  of  distri- 
bution among  them ;  who  may  not  be  a  beneficiary ;  amount  of 
assistance;  zakdt  of  one  town  may  not  be  spent  in  another 439 

CHAPTER  XI 
EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE 

Sec.  I.  The  Booty  Revenue: 

Spoils  originally  divided  into  five  shares;  the  Prophet's  share; 
that  of  his  relations ;  mode  of  distribution  465 


CONTENTS  ig 

PAOB 

>ec.  II.  The  Fa'y  Revenue  : 

Disbursed  for  Moslem  community;  the  Shafiite  and  Malikite 
views;  beneficiaries  of  fa'y  different  from  those  of  sadaqah;  the 
imdm's  presents;  shares  of  children  and  slaves;  death  of  bene- 
ficiary ........................................................  470 

Sec.  III.  The  Military  Stipends  (Fa'y  Revenue  Continued)  : 

Qualifications  of  stipendiaries;  method  of  registration;  order 
of  registration;  among  Arabs;  non-Arabs;  amounts  of  stipends; 
stipendiaries  examined  yearly;  time  of  payment;  rights  and 
duties  of  stipendiaries  ;  subsistence  of  stipendiaries'  offspring  .  .  .  477 

CHAPTER  XII 
(TAX  GRANTS 

^~~"^r-^ 

(i)  Grant  of  tithe;  (2)  grant  of  khardj;  (a)  grantee  is  a  bene- 
ficiary of  sadaqah;  (b)  or  of  share  of  masdtih;  (c)  or  of  fa'y; 
grant  of  jisyah;  grant  of  khardj:  (a)  for  a  definite  term;  (b) 
hereditary  grants;  (c)  life-grants:  (i)  grant  in  payment  of  tem- 
porary services;  (ii)  of  permanent  services;  (Hi)  of  wages  ...  484 

CHAPTER  XIII 

CONCERNING  PUBLIC  RECORDS 
Sec.  I.    The  Public  Registers: 

Records  of  cities;  tithe-lands;  khardj-\ands  ;  dhimmis;  mines; 
frontier  cities  ;  tolls  ..........................................  490 

Sec.  II.  The  Duties  of  the  Public  Registrars: 

Records  of  laws  ;  settlement  of  accounts  ;  recording  of  reports  ; 
audit  of  collectors  ...........................................  404 


C.  - 

(^CHAPTER  XIV 
PUBLIC  DOMAIN 

(i)  Waste  lands;  (2)  cultivated  lands:  (a)  owners  known;  (b) 
owners  unknown:  (i)  lands  set  apart  for  public  treasury;  (ii) 
khardj  lands;  (iii)  lands  reverted  to  public;  exposed  and  con- 
cealed mines  ;  public  reservations  ;  forests  ;  meadows  ;  fishing  and 
hunting  ;  water  ;  markets  ;  schools,  etc  .........................  -500 

CHAPTER  XV 
SUMMARY  AND  CONCLUSION  .....................................  523 

INDEX   ..........................................................  537 


PART  I 

INTRODUCTION  TO  MOHAMMEDAN  LAW 
AND  BIBLIOGRAPHY 


CHAPTER  I 
PRELIMINARY  CONCEPTS 

THE  word  shari'ah  is  the  general  name  given  to  the 
Mohammedan  dispensation  and  is  defined  by  the  doctors  as 
4<  that  which  would  not  be  known  had  there  not  been  a  divine 
revelation."  1 

This  definition  of  sharVah  is  broad  enough  to  include  the 
revelations  made  by  the  Hebrew  Prophets  and  Jesus,  but 
their  revelations  are  considered  valid  only  in  so  far  as  they 
have  been  confirmed  by  those  made  through  Mohammed. 
The  latter  therefore  are  the  shari'ah  par  excellence.  A 
second  corollary  from  the  above  definition  is  that  only  what 
is  expressly  stated  in  the  divine  revelations,  or  may  be  in- 
ferred from  them  by  analogy,  properly  comes  under  shari'ah. 
Matters  determined  by  intellectual  processes  remain,  there- 
fore, outside,  e.  g.,  the  obligation  of  belief  in  God  or  the 
Prophets  is  outside  of  shari'ah  because  it  is  a  matter  to  be 
established  intellectually. 

Inasmuch  as  the  prescriptions  contained  in  the  shari'ah,  to 
use  a  judicial  analogy,  serve  as  evidences  for  the  establish- 
ment of  shari'ah  values,  they  have  been  called  by  the  doctors 
"shari'ah  evidences"  (adillah  shari'yyah).  With  refer- 
ence to  the  source  from  which  these  evidences  are  obtained, 
the  doctors  have  distinguished  four  types  of  shari'ah  evi- 
dences, namely,  the  Koran,  the  sunnah,  the  ijma',  and  the 
qiyas. 

lTawfch,  p.  21. 

23 


24  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

A  shari'ah  value  (hukm  shar'i)  is  defined  as  the  quality 
"  determined  as  a  result  of  divine  revelation,"  e.  g.,  the 
fact  of  a  human  act  like  lying  being  prohibited  in  the 
shari'ah  is  its  shari'ah  value.1 

The  science  which  derives  the  shari'ah  values  from  the 
shari'ah  evidences  is  the  "  science  of  fiqh,"  or  simply  fiqh, 
and  the  person  conversant  with  this  science  is  the  faqih. 

Fiqh  has  been  defined  by  Abu  Hanifah  in  a  general  way 
as  "  the  self's  knowledge  of  what  is  to  its  advantage  and 
disadvantage."  This  definition,  it  will  be  observed,  is  very 
broad  and  includes  matters  of  conduct  (' amaliyyat)  as  well 
as  matters  of  belief  (i'tiqadiyyat),  and  of  ethics  (wijdan- 
iyyat).  Some  have  restricted  fiqh  only  to  matters  of  con- 
duct, such  as  civil  transactions  (mu'amalat)  and  religious 
ritual  ('ibadat). 

Fiqh  has  been  defined  also  in  a  specific  way  as  "  the 
deduction  of  the  shari'ah  values  relating  to  conduct  from 
their  respective  particular  (tafsili)  evidences."  By  the  use 
of  the  term  "  shari'ah  "  it  is  intended  to  leave  out  intellec- 
tual and  perceptual  values,  such  as  the  obligation  of  belief 
in  God  and  the  Prophets.  The  word  "  conduct "  excludes 
points  of  theory,  e.  g.,  that  the  ijma'  is  a  lawful  evidence 
for  the  establishment  of  shari'ah  values.  "  Deduction  " 
excludes  knowledge  acquired  from  a  mujtahid,  instead  of 
by  direct  inquiry  into  the  evidences.  According  to  this,  a 
person  is  not  called  a  faqih  when  he  only  knows  the  shari'ah 
values.  He  is  called  a  faqih  only  if  he  has  himself,  by  per- 
sonal inquiry  and  thought,  deduced  those  values.  This 

1  The  Arabic  word  hukm  (plural,  ahkdm)  is  used  in  various  slightly 
different  meanings  which  no  single  English  word  would  exactly  render. 
At  least  two  words  will  be  used  to  express  the  Arabic  hukm,  the  word 
value,  as  in  this  case,  and  the  expression  "legal  result".  For  example, 
when  the  doctors  say  that  the  hukm  of  a  sale  is  the  transfer  of  owner- 
ship in  a  thing  from  the  seller  to  the  purchaser,  they  mean  only  to 
describe  the  legal  result  of  a  sale. 


PRELIMINARY  CONCEPTS  25 

definition  is  according  to  the  Shafiite  doctors.  The  Hanifite 
definition  and  the  one  adopted  in  the  modern  Ottoman  civil 
code  (majallah) ,  ignore  the  way  in  which  this  knowledge 
has  been  obtained.  Consequently  the  mere  knowledge  of 
the  sharVah  values  is  fiqh,  and  the  person  who  has  this 
knowledge  is  a  faqih.  In  other  words,  a  faqlh  need  not  be 
a  mujtahid.1  Finally,  the  term  "  particular  "  indicates  that 
the  premises  which  fiqh  uses  are  not  directly  obtained  from 
the  four  sharfah  evidences,  namely,  the  Koran,  the  sunnah, 
the  ijma',  and  the  qiyas.  These  evidences,  as  they  stand, 

1  This  division  between  the  Shafiites  and  the  Hanifites  is  only  a  phase 
of  a  more  fundamental  division  among  the  doctors  concerning  the  defi- 
nition of  science  in  general.  One  group  of  doctors  holds  that  knowl- 
edge without  an  understanding  of  the  underlying  reasons  is  not  sci- 
ence ('i/m)  but  narration  (hikdyah).  The  other  group  contends  that, 
in  addition  to  the  above  meaning,  science  also  means  the  mere  knowl- 
edge of  the  rules  (masd'il)  as  well  as  the  ability  (malakah)  to  recall 
to,  or  bring  before  the,  mind  (istiljtfdr)  those  rules.  For  instance, 
they  say,  when  it  is  claimed  that  a  person  knows  syntax,  it  is  only 
meant  that  he  has  the  ability  to  bring  before  the  mind  the  rules  of 
syntax,  not  that  he  actually  remembers  them.  The  first  group  replies 
that,  although  science  may  also  mean,  as  contended  by  the  second 
group,  the  mere  knowledge  of  the  rules,  or  the  mere  ability  to  recall 
those  rules,  it  is  so  only  when  that  knowledge  or  that  ability  is  coupled 
with  a  proper  understanding  of  the  reasons. 

There  has  also  been  a  dispute  as  to  what  exactly  is  meant  by  the 
word  ability  in  this  connection.  Some  say,  it  is  the  ability  to  know  all 
the  rules  of  the  science,  either  by  recalling  to  the  memory  what  has 
already  been  stored  away  in  it,  or  by  discovering  (istih$dl)  what  is  as 
yet  unknown.  It  is  not,  they  add,  the  ability  to  recall  only,  known  as 
actual  intellect  ('aql  bi '/-/»'/),  nor  is  it  the  ability  to  discover  only, 
known  as  potential  intellect  ('aql  bi  'i-malakah).  For  if  the  latter  were 
the  case,  a  person  who  has  not  as  yet  learned  a  single  rule  of  a  sci- 
ence, although  he  has  the  ability  to  discover  those  rules,  would  have 
to  be  called  a  scientist.  In  the  al-atwal  it  is  stated  that  the  ability  to 
recall  what  has  already  been  learned  is  sufficient.  The  ground  for  this 
view  is  that  it  is  not  an  uncommon  thing  for  sciences  to  be  in  a  state 
of  development.  In  such  cases  a  knowledge  of  the  entire  subject- 
matter  is  out  of  the  question,  but  such  knowledge  of  it  as  has  been 
already  acquired  may  properly  be  called  science.  (Tech.  Diet.,  pp.  2-3.) 


26  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

are  too  general  (ijmali)  and  are  not  available  for  the  pur- 
poses of  fiqh,  until  after  they  have  been  reduced  by  a  par- 
ticular science  to  logical  propositions,  each  relating  to  one 
particular  set  of  values. 

This  particular  science,  which  prepares  its  premises 
for  fiqh,  is  the  so-called  science  of  usul=al=fiqh,  literally, 
the  science  of  the  bases  of  fiqh.  It  has  been  called  so, 
because  the  four  shari'ah  evidences  above-mentioned  which 
form  its  subject-matter,  are  in  the  last  analysis,  the  four 
bases  on  which  the  deductions  of  fiqh  rest. 

The  science  of  usul-al-fiqh  has  been  defined  by  the  doc- 
tors as  "  the  science  of  the  principles  whereby  one  reaches 
fiqh  in  the  true  way."  *  The  definition  needs  explanation. 

Usul-al-fiqh  discusses  only  those  principles  which  are 
immediately  necessary  for  reaching  fiqh,  in  other  words,  it 
does  not  concern  itself  with  less  immediate  subjects,  like 
language  and  syntax,  or  dogmatics  (kalam),  although  they 
too  are  necessary.  On  the  other  hand,  the  expression  "  in 
the  true  way  "  is  intended  to  exclude  controversial  subjects. 

The  function  of  iisul=al=fiqh  is  then  to  prepare  the 
premises  which  are  to  be  used  in  fiqh  in  establishing 
the  shari'ah  values  in  particular  cases.  Thus,  usul-al- 
fiqh  provides  for  fiqh  as  premises  certain  universal  pro- 
positions (qawaid  kulliyyah)  to  be  used  by  fiqh  in  deriving 
the  provisions  of  the  law  applicable  to  particular  cases. 
For  example,  usul-al-fiqh  tells  that  under  such  and  such 
conditions  ijma'  constitutes  an  evidence  for  the  establish- 
ment of  a  shari'ah  value.  Fiqh  takes  this  proposition  as 
a  premise  and  deduces  from  it  the  conclusion  that  the  prac- 
tice e.  g.,  of  istisna',2  is  lawful  because  there  is  an  ijma'  to 
that  effect.  Or,  again,  usul-al-fiqh  tells  us  that  under  cer- 

1  Towdih,  p.  27. 

J  Istisnd1  is  placing  an  order  with  an  artisan. 


PRELIMINARY  CONCEPTS  27 

tain  conditions  analogy  (qiyas)  is  a  lawful  means  of 
establishing  a  sharTah  value. 

In  short,  usiil-al-fiqh  discusses  the  shari'ah  evidences, 
that  is,  the  bases  of  fiqh,  in  so  far  as  they  may  be 
used  as  evidences  for  the  establishment  of  the  sharTah 
values,  and  the  shari'ah  values  in  so  far  as  they  are  deduced 
from  the  sharTah  evidences,  but  it  does  not  discuss  what 
the  shari'ah  values  are  in  particular  cases,  that  being  the 
function  of  fiqh. 

The  component  parts  of  usul-al-fiqh  and  fiqh,  as  well  as 
the  position  of  these  two  disciplines  among  sciences  in  gen- 
eral will  be  made  clear  by  the  following  classification  out- 
lined by  the  Hanifite  doctors.1 

The  established  sciences  ('ulurn  mudazuzvanah)  are: 

I.  Intellectual  ('aqliyyah),  acquired  through  the  exercise 
of  the  intellect  and  the  senses  ; 

II.  Traditional  (naqliyyah),  acquired  by  way  of  tradition. 
The  contrast  is  thus  that  between,  what  we  would  call  the 
speculative  and  the  historical  sciences. 

The  traditional  sciences  are  : 

1.  The  literary  or  instrumental  (aliyyah  or  lisaniyyah), 

2.  The  sharTah  sciences. 

The  shari'ah  sciences  are  : 

1.  fundamental  (asliyyah),  pertaining  to  the 

(a)  reading  of  the  Koran, 

(b)  interpretation  of  the  Koran  (tafsir), 

(c)  hadlths  or  traditions; 

2.  deduced  (mustanbatah)  ,  comprising 

(a)  dogmatics  (itiqadiyyah),  i.  e.,  the  science  of 
the  unity  and  the  attributes  of  God,  (kalam  or 
usiil-al-din,  or  al-fiqh  al-akbar,  or  'Urn  al-tawhid 


1  Cf.  Ford'id,  p.  2,  fn.;  also  Savvas,  chap,  ii,  p.  8. 


28  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

(b)  the  practical *  ('amaliyyah)  or  fiqh  sciences. 
The  practical  or  fiqh  sciences  comprise : 

1.  The  science  of  the  bases  of  fiqh  ((ilm  usul-al-fiqh) , 

2.  The  science  of  the  applications  of  fiqh  (film  furue  al- 
fiqh,  or  simply  fiqh). 

Finally,  fiqh  relates  to 

1.  human  acts  which  are  entirely  a  matter  of  divine  rights 
(huquq  allah),  namely,  (a)  prayers  (saldt),  (b)  fast- 
ing (sawm),  (c)   legal  alms  (sakat),   (d)  holy  war 
(jihad),  covering  war  and  peace,  the  latter  including 
the  fiscal  and  other  relations  of  the  Moslem  state  to 
its  non-Moslem  subjects,  and  (e)  pilgrimage  to  Mecca; 

2.  human  acts  which  are  entirely  a  matter  of  private 
rights  (huquq  cibad)  ; 

3.  human  acts  of  a  mixed  nature,  namely,  the  tithe (fushr) . 

1  By  "practical",  the  doctors  mean  three  different  things:  (i)  That 
which  relates  to  practice,  as  opposed  to  what  is  merely  academic.  In 
this  sense,  logic,  practical  medicine,  and  the  science  of  tailoring,  are 
all  practical,  because  they  all  relate  to  practice,  either  mental,  as  in  the 
case  of  logic,  or  physical,  as  in  the  case  of  the  others.  (2)  "Practical" 
in  philosophy  means  the  science  of  things  made  by  man,  as  distinguished 
from  theoretical  which  means  the  science  of  things  whose  existence  is 
outside  the  reach  of  human  power  and  will.  In  this  sense,  logic  is 
theoretical,  because  its  subject-matter,  the  mental  processes,  is  not  a 
human  institution;  fiqh  is  practical,  because  its  subject-matter,  namely, 
human  acts,  is  a  matter  of  human  will  and  power.  (3)  Applied  to  the 
arts,  "  practical "  refers  to  those  whose  mastery  depends  on  experi- 
ment and  practice,  as  contrasted  with  "theoretical".  In  this  last  sense, 
fiqh,  syntax,  logic,  practical  medicine  are  theoretical  because  their  ac- 
quisition does  not  depend  on  practice;  the  art  of  tailoring,  however,  is 
practical.  In  the  first  sense  practical  is  more  general  than  in  the  sec- 
ond, for  while  logic  is  practical  in  the  first  sense,  it  is  not  so  in  the 
second.  Likewise,  practical  in  the  second  sense  is  more  general  than 
in  the  third  sense,  because  fiqh  is  practical  in  the  second  sense  but  not 
in  the  third,  since  practice  is  not  necessary  for  its  learning.  (For  more 
information  on  the  divisions  of  science  and  on  the  so-called  "  eight 
heads"  (al-ru'us  al-thamdniah)  to  which  every  author  must  conform, 
see  Tech.  Diet.,  Introduction). 


PRELIMINARY  CONCEPTS  29 

The  second  of  these  three  classes,  namely,  the  human  acts 
which  concern  individual  rights  alone,  may  be  acts  of 

(1)  the  living  (ahya'),  that  is, 

(a)  marriage  and  divorce  (mun&kah&t), 

(b)  civil  or  commercial  transactions  (mu'dmalat), 

(c)  transgressions  ('uqubat) ; 

(2)  the  deceased   (amwat),  that  is  matters  relating  to 
inheritance  ( far  a' id  ) . 

It  is  thus  seen  that  fiqh  and  usul-al-fiqh  constitute  the  two 
branches  of  the  so-called  practical  sciences  which  are  the 
counterpart  of  the  dogmatic,  the  two  making  up  the  deduced 
shari'ah  sciences. 

The  above  table  also  points  out  the  relative  position  of 
Mohammedan  finance.  It  will  be  observed  that  in  the  above 
scheme,  zakat,  which  comprises  the  taxes  paid  by  the 
Moslems,  is  a  matter  of  religious  obligation  and  is  differ- 
entiated from  the  taxes  paid  by  the  non-Moslems.  The 
latter  come  under  the  caption  of  "  holy  war."  In  other 
words,  the  taxes  paid  by  the  non-Moslems  are  based  on 
the  relation  between  conqueror  and  conquered,  rather 
than  on  that  of  the  state  to  its  citizens,  or  of  God  to  His 
worshippers,  as  in  the  case  of  zakat. 


CHAPTER  II 

THE  FIRST  BASIS  OF  FIQH  :  THE  KORAN 

'1 
THE  word  Koran  literally  means,  reading,  recitation.     It 

is  technically  called  the  Book,  and  is  defined  as  "  that  which 
has  been  transmitted  to  us  (i.  e.,  the  Mohammedans)  by 
way  of  mutawatir,  between  the  two  covers  of  the  holy 
Mushafs  (i.  e.,  copies  of  the  Koran  collected  and  edited  dur- 
ing the  calif  ate  of  'Uthman)."  * 

The  Koran  is  the  Holy  Scripture  of  the  Mohammedans 
and,  according  to  the  doctors,  consists  of  the  very  words 
of  God  as  they  were  revealed  through  the  angel  Gabriel 2 
to  the  Prophet  Mohammed  during  his  prophetic  career,  at 
first  at  Mecca  and  later  at  Medina.3  The  different  stages 
of  this  career,  as  might  be  expected,  find  their  reflection  in 
the  Koran.  Indeed  the  revelations  contained  in  the  Koran 
may  be  usefully  divided  into  two  classes — those  revealed 
during  the  Prophet's  stay  in  Mecca  and  those  revealed  after 
his  arrival  in  Medina. 

Before  the  last  event,  Mohammed  did  not  intend  to  teach 
a  new  religion  but,  according  to  his  own  account  of  the 
matter,  merely  to  bring  his  people  to  the  worship  of  the  one 
true  God,  whose  commandments  the  Hebrew  prophets  before 
him  had  preached  to  their  peoples.4  Therefore,  the 

1  Tawdlh,  p.  36. 

1  For  full  details  concerning  the  various  views  as  to  the  actual  way 
in  which  Gabriel  communicated  the  Koran  to  the  Prophet,  consult 
Tech.  Diet.,  pp.  1161  et  seq. 

3  Of.  Gazali,  p.  100. 

4  Juynboll,  p.  3. 

30 


THE  FIRST  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  KORAN  $i 

verses  revealed  in  Mecca,  especially  the  oldest  of  them, 
all  enjoin  upon  the  Meccans  belief  in  the  resurrection,  the 
last  day  of  judgment,  and  the  final  reward  or  punishment 
of  human  acts  in  the  world  to  come. 

After  thirteen  years  of  effort  in  Mecca,  the  Prophet  had 
utterly  failed  and  was  forced  to  give  up  home  and  kin- 
dred and  work  among  the  tribes  of  Medina.  This  rupture 
of  the  Prophet  with  his  native  city  and  kinsmen  and  his  pact 
at  'Aqabah  with  outsiders,  under  the  existing  Arabian  so- 
cial conditions,  had  political  as  well  as  religious  significance. 
Probably  it  was  the  identification  of  the  movement  with 
pi  >lidcal  motives  that  was  the  most  potent  factor  in  bringing 
about  the  phenomenal  success  of  Islam  in  Medina  during  the 
last  ten  years  of  Mohammed's  life. 

The  Mohammedans  call  the  flight  of  Mohammed  from 
Mecca  to  Medina  Hi j rah  (literally,  flight)  and  have  fittingly 
chosen  it  as  the  beginning  of  their  era.  The  Hijrah  ends 
the  first  unsuccessful  period  of  Islam  in  Mecca  and  ushers 
in  the  Medinian  period  during  which  it  may  be  said  that 
Islam  knew  nothing  but  success.  In  this  second  period, 
Islam  was  no  longer  the  purely  religious  and  passive  little 
group  which  it  was  in  Mecca,  but  a  vigorous  religious  and 
political  organization  which  could  defend  itself  and  was 
eager  to  expand.  What  is  more  natural,  therefore,  than 
that  this  great  change  in  the  material  conditions  of  Islam  and 
the  success,  which  it  began  to  enjoy  in  Medina,  should  react 
upon  the  very  nature  of  the  movement  and  be  reflected  in  the 
verses  revealed  during  this  second  period  ?  There  could  not 
be  a  more  eloquent  witness  of  this  transformation  than  the 
following  quotation  from  the  Arab  historian  of  Mohammed, 
Ibn  Hisham : * 

Before  the  pact  of  allegiance  at  'Aqabah,  the  Prophet  was 

1  Ibn  Hisham,  p.  313. 


32  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

not  permitted  to  go  to  war,  nor  to  shed  blood ;  he  was  com- 
manded [by  God]  only  to  call  people  to  God,  to  be  patient 
under  persecution,  and  to  turn  away  from  the  ignorant  .  .  . 
but  when  the  Quraysh  [i.  e.,  the  Meccans]  rebelled  against 
God,  .  .  .  denied  His  Prophet,  tormented  and  exiled  those 
who  followed  Him,  who  believed  in  His  unity  and  His 
Prophet,  and  who  clung  fast  to  his  religion,  God  permitted 
His  Prophet  to  fight  and  to  revenge  himself  for  their  op- 
pression, and  tyranny. 

The  revelations  of  the  second  period,  therefore,  relate 
principally  to  questions  of  war  and  internal  organization, 
such  as  spoils,  zakat,  marriage,  inheritance,  usury,  transgres- 
sions, etc.  The  general  characteristic  of  these  revelations  is 
that  they  are  casual,  for  they  were  revealed  as  the  circum- 
stances required.  They  were  never  meant  to  be,  and  they 
are  not,  a  well-rounded  system  of  law.  They  nevertheless 
form  one  of  the  cornerstones  on  which  the  elaborate  edifice 
of  fiqh  has  been  gradually  erected. 

During  the  life  of  Mohammed  the  Koran  was  in  a  scat- 
tered form,  there  being  no  complete  collection  of  all  the 
revelations.  As,  however,  many  of  the  Companions  of  the 
Prophet,  who  knew  by  heart  shorter  or  longer  passages  of 
the  Koran,  fell  dead  in  battle  after  the  death  of  the  Prophet, 
it  was  feared  that  some  of  the  holy  passages  might  be 
forever  lost. 

The  first  successor  of  Mohammed  in  the  leadership  of 
Islam,  Abu  Bakr,  charged  a  young  man  by  the  name  of 
Zayd  Ibn  Thabit,  who  had  formerly  served  as  scribe  to  the 
Prophet  himself,  to  make  a  written  collection  of  all  the  re- 
vealed passages.  Out  of  the  existing  notes,  as  they  had 
been  inscribed  on  scraps  of  paper,  palm-leaves,  flat  bones, 
stones,  etc.,  and  by  reference  to  the  memories  of  reliable 
persons,  Zayd  gathered  together  as  many  as  possible  of 
the  scattered  revelations.  The  first  collection  was  probably 
intended  for  the  personal  use  of  Abu  Bakr  and  received  no 
official  character. 


343]         THE  FIRST  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  KORAN  33 

A  truly  official  codification  of  the  Koran  was  first  made 
during  the  califate  of  'Uthman,  the  third  calif.  This 
was  undertaken  as  a  result  of  disputes  over  the  read- 
ings of  certain  verses.  The  work  was  again  entrusted  to 
the  hands  of  Zayd  Ibn  Thabit,  this  time  in  collaboration 
with  several  other  persons.  When  they  had  completed  the 
work,  'Uthman  ordered  the  destruction  of  all  previous 
Koran  collections,  and  had  copies  of  the  new  and  offi- 
cial Koran  sent  to  the  different  provinces  of  the  Moslem 
empire.  This  collection  of  4Uthman  has  come  down  to  our 
own  times  unchanged  and  is  the  only  authentic  text.  Con- 
cerning its  genuineness  no  doubt  can  be  entertained.1 
Furthermore,  it  can  be  accepted  as  a  complete  col- 
lection, at  least  as  complete  as  was  humanly  possible. 
The  Shiites,  chiefly  a  political  sect,  have  always  claimed 
that  the  verses  referring  to  the  special  sanctity  of  'Ali, 
the  fourth  calif,  and  his  family  were  intentionally  left  out. 
This  accusation  has  no  foundation  in  fact.  For,  if 
such  had  been  the  case,  the  contemporaries  of  Mohammed 
who  were  still  alive  would  have  seen  to  it  that  those  verses 
were  included  or  have  complained  about  their  omission ;  but 
even  the  enemies  of  'Uthman  accepted  his  edition  of  the 
Koran  as  absolutely  authoritative,  thus  affording  ample 
proof  of  its  genuineness. 

The  Koran  text  is  divided  into  114  chapters  of  unequal 
length,  arranged  according  to  their  length,  the  longest  com- 
ing first.  A  chronological  arrangement  would  result  in 
very  much  the  opposite  order.  Each  chapter  is  called  a 
surah.2  Most  of  the  surahs  pertain  to  more  than  one  sub- 
ject. Each  surah  consists  of  a  certain  number  of  verses 

1  Juynboll,  p.  9. 

*  Juynboll,  p.  9.  A  word  of  Hebrew  origin  meaning  number,  also  a 
number  of  written  lines. 


34  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [344 

called  ayah  (literally,  sign,  miracle).  It  is  claimed  that 
every  ayah  is  a  sign  of  wonder. 

The  revelations  contained  in  the  Koran  were  not  all  re- 
vealed on  one  occasion,  but  at  long  intervals  and  in  response 
to  special  needs.  Mohammed  by  no  means  resorted  to  Divine 
revelation  in  order  to  decide  every  case  that  came  up  for 
solution.  Tradition  tells  us  that  the  Prophet,  especially  in 
Mecca,  only  in  extremely  rare  cases  and  upon  the  reiterated 
requests  of  his  most  influential  followers  made  up  his  mind 
to  ask  God  for  a  revelation.  The  case  of  'Omar  is  cited 
who  had  to  apply  several  times  before  obtaining  a  revela- 
tion.1 The  Koran  consequently  is  fragmentary  and  often 
mystical  in  its  sense,  with  frequent  allusions  to  contemporary 
events  and  persons,  and  can  only  be  understood  fully  on  the 
basis  of  a  complete  knowledge  of  the  circumstances  which 
surrounded  its  revelation.  This  fact  explains  the  origin  of 
film  al-tafsir,  i.  e.,  the  science  of  the  interpretation  of  the 
Koran,  and  the  reason  for  the  many  voluminous  commen- 
taries that  were  written  upon  it. 

The  commentaries  on  the  Koran  form  an  important  part 
of  Mohammedan  literature.  They  comment  on  the  holy 
text  from  every  point  of  view,  grammatical,  literary,  reli- 
gious, legal,  etc.  Furthermore,  they  give  the  history 
that  attaches  to  each  verse  and  go  more  or  less  fully  into  the 
legal  prescriptions  that  follow  from  it.  There  are  also 
commentaries  compiled  with  one  single  purpose,  e.  g.,  from 
the  grammatical  or  the  literary  viewpoint  alone.  The  more 
favored  are  those  dealing  in  a  compact  form  with  all  of 
these  viewpoints.  The  one  written  by  al-Baydawi  is  prob- 
ably the  most  serviceable  of  all. 

1  Hurgronje,  "  Le  droit  musulman  ",  pp.  5-6. 


CHAPTER  III 
THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH  :  THE  SUNNAH 

SECTION  i 
General  Considerations 

FROM  the  very  beginning,  the  conduct  of  the  Prophet 
served  as  a  standard  as  much  as  the  Koran  itself.  In  fact, 
we  have  seen  that  the  Koran  was  revealed  to  the  Prophet 
in  the  course  of  years,  and  that  the  Prophet,  rather  than 
decide  every  case  by  applying  to  God  for  a  revelation,  would 
solve  many  of  them  by  his  own  proper  judgment.  Such 
judgments  were  not  respected  the  less  on  this  account. 

Mohammed  was  not  only  the  transmitter  of  the  Koran 
but  he  also  interpreted  and  completed  it.  The  only  dif- 
ference between  the  ordinary  expressions  of  the  Prophet  and 
his  revelations  consists  in  the  fact  that,  whereas  the  former 
are  divine  in  content  alone,  the  latter  are  divine  in  form 
also.  According  to  the  Mizan  *  the  ground  for  this  view 
is  afforded  by  the  Koran  itself  in  the  verse :  "  and  we  have 
revealed  to  you  the  exhortation  (i.  e.,  the  Koran)  in  order 
that  you  may  explain  to  men  what  has  been  revealed  to 
them."  The  Prophetic  conduct  then  is  as  important  a 
source  of  fiqh  as  the  Koran  itself,  and  indeed,  when  later 
that  the  Koran  in  point  of  time,  supersedes  it. 

The  word  sunnah  literally  means  way,  custom,  habit  of 
life.  Technically  2  it  is  defined  by  the  canonists  as  utter- 

1  P.  45- 

*  Sunnah  has  also  another  techincal  meaning  in  reference  to  religious 
duties,  namely,  that  which  is  recommended  although  not  obligatory. 
See,  chapter  on  Classification  of  the  Shari'ah  Values. 

345]  35 


36  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [346 

ances  of  the  Prophet  (other  than  the  Koran)  known  as 
hadiths?  or  his  personal  acts  and  acts  or  sayings  of  others 
tacitly  approved  by  him.2 

A  hadith  is  to  be  carefully  distinguished  from  a  sunnah, 
although  some  jurists  have  claimed  that  they  are  identical. 

Sunnah  is  the  custom  or  mores,  which  was  prevalent  in 
the  Arabian  community,  with  regard  to  a  religious,  social,  or 
legal  matter.  After  the  advent  of  Mohammedanism  the  old 
customs  of  the  Arabs  were  partly  modified  by  the  conduct 
of  the  Prophet,  and  to  a  lesser  degree,  of  his  companions. 
This  change,  however,  only  affected  the  content,  for  the 
sunnah  still  continued  as  a  rule  of  conduct.  A  hadith,  on 
the  other  hand,  is  a  statement  of  the  Prophet.  A  sunnah 
may  be  embodied  in  a  hadith,  but  is  not  itself  a  hadith. 
Thus  Ahmad  Ibn  Hanbal  says  concerning  a  hadith :  "  fi 
hadha  'l-hadlth  khams  sunan,"  i.  e.t  "  in  this  hadith  there 
are  five  sunnahs."  It  is  also  possible  for  a  hadith  to  con- 
tradict the  sunnah.3 

Opposed  to  the  concept  of  sunnah  is  that  of  bid'ah,  i,  e., 
innovation,  departure  from  the  established  sunnah.  Just 
as  conformity  to  the  sunnah  is  commendable,  so  innovation 
is  to  be  condemned.  The  Prophet  has  said :  "  the  worst  of 
things  are  the  newly  made  [i.  e.,  contrary  to  the  sunnah], 
for  such  things  are  innovations,  and  every  innovation  is  a 
deviation  from  the  right  way,  and  every  deviation  leads 
into  the  Fire." 

Such  a  theory  of  social  control,  although  expedient  from 
the  standpoint  of  religious  conservatism,  naturally  limits  the 
possibility  of  social  readjustment.  Later,  the  canonists  were 

1  The  word  hadith,  literally  means  saying  and  may  apply  to  a  saying 
of  any  person,  but  usually  it  means  a  saying  of  the  Prophet  unless 
otherwise  indicated. 

2  Tawdih,  p.  359- 

•'  Goldziher,  M.  Studien,  vol.  ii,  p.  n;  cf.  Taw&h,  p.  362. 


-547]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNN  AH         37 

compelled  to  modify  it  by  the  fiction  that  all  innovations  are 
not  blameworthy  and  that  some  may  be  praiseworthy.  At 
an  early  date  Malik  said  about  an  innovation,  "  ni'mat  al- 
bid'ah  hadha  "  i.  e.,  "  this  innovation  is  good."  1 

The  theory  that  the  sunnah  is  a  supplement  to  the  Koran 
and  even  supersedes  it  in  case  of  contradiction  when  later  in 
time,  gave  the  sunnah  a  predominant  position  as  a  source 
of  law.  Such  a  theory  amounted  to  no  less  than  a  shifting 
of  the  center  of  gravity  from  the  Koran  to  the  sunnah. 
For  it  meant  that  if  there  were  unintelligible  or  contradic- 
tory passages  in  the  Koran,  or  if  the  sunnah  contradicted 
the  Koran,  the  decision  rested  with  the  sunnah. 

These  circumstances  naturally  served  as  so  many  induce- 
ments to  the  unconscientious  and  the  ambitious  to  invent 
and  circulate  false  traditions  in  order  to  support  their 
political  or  other  schemes.  As  time  went  on  and  the  Com- 
panions of  the  Prophet  began  one  by  one  to  pass  away,  it 
became  relatively  easier  to  put  false  traditions  in  circulation, 
and  the  number  soon  became  very  large.  Some  were 
even  so  unscrupulous  as  to  ascribe  to  the  Prophet  state- 
ments referring  to  litigations  that  had  arisen  after  his  death. 
A  certain  Ibn  Abu  'Awga  confessed  before  his  execution 
in  155  H.  that  he  had  put  in  circulation  4000  false  hadiths.2 
In  this  matter  of  falsifications  the  /iadf£/t-teachers  of  Kufah 
became  especially  notorious. 

This  zeal  for  circulating  false  hadiths,  however,  is  to  be 
contrasted  with  the  great  caution  which  characterized  the 
Companions  of  the  Prophet  and  other  pious  Moslems.3 
The  biographies  of  Ibn  Sa'd  offer  us  many  a  remarkable 
example  of  this  kind.  E.  g.,  people  who  had  long  been 

1  Goldziher,  M.  Studien,  vol.  ii,  p.  26. 

1  Kremer,  p.  481. 

8  Goldziher,  "  Kampfe  ",  p.  860. 


38  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [348 

in  the  company  of  'Abdallah  Ibn  Mas'ud  relate  that  they 
scarcely  ever  heard  him  report  a  hadith,  but  when  he  did 
so,  his  forehead  perspired  from  anxiety,  while  his  cane 
shook  in  his  hand,  and  even  his  dress  betrayed  the  trembling 
of  his  body.  Furthermore,  he  qualified  his  statements  with 
all  sorts  of  limitations.  This  was  also  true  of  the  other 
Companions.  They  were  afraid  that  in  repeating  the  words 
of  the  Prophet  they  might  unwittingly  add  to  or  subtract 
from  them. 

This  state  of  mind  explains  why  in  the  beginning  the 
hadiths  were  not  written  down.  For,  if  distortion  of  a 
hadith  in  saying  it  was  so  dreadful,  how  much  more  so 
in  writing  it.  Therefore  a  hadith  was  not  considered 
canonical  unless  it  was  kept  in  memory  and  orally  handed 
on.1  This  does  not  mean  that  writing  was  not  used  at  all. 
From  the  very  first,  writing  was  resorted  to,  but  only  as  an 
aid  to  the  memory,  and  when  a  hadith  was  written,  it  was 
destroyed  as  soon  as  committed  to  memory.  Nevertheless 
the  writing  down  of  hadiths  became  general  early  in  the  first 
century  of  the  Hi j rah. 

The  study  and  preservation  of  the  hadiths  had  a  great 
fascination  for  the  early  Moslems,  who  often  traveled  long 
distances  to  hear  hadiths  from  a  renowned  teacher.  The  in- 
struction and  transmission  of  the  hadiths  in  time  developed 
into  a  special  discipline  called  film  al-hadith,  i.  e.,  science 
of  the  hadith.  Its  rules  2  were  more  or  less  exacting  and 

1  Goldziher,  ibid.,  p.  862 ;  cf.  M.  Studien,  vol.  ii,  p.  196 ;  Juynboll,  p. 
15 ;  Kremer,  p.  475. 

1  The  rules  mentioned  in  the  following  sections  represent  the  views 
of  the  authorities  on  usul-al-Hqh  (u$uliyytin)  and  do  not  always  coin- 
cide with  those  of  the  /tacfrf/t-teachers  (mubaddithun)  inasmuch  as 
the  former  are  interested  in  the  hadiths  primarily  as  a  source  of  law. 
When  there  is  a  variance  between  them,  the  Shafiite  authorities  gen- 
erally are  likely  to  side  with  the  hadith-tezchers  and  the  Hanifites  to 
hold  the  opposite  view.  This  is  because  the  Hanifites  emphasized  the 


349]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNNAH         39 

formed  some  sort  of  a  critical  method  to  check  and  elimin- 
ate the  false  hadiths. 

There  are  six  collections  of  hadiths  in  the  making  of 
which  it  was  attempted  to  be  critical  and  to  include  only 
reliable  (sahih)  hadiths.  They  were  all  compiled  in  the  third 
century  of  the  Hijrah  and  are  considered  standard  works. 
They  are  denominated  briefly  as  "  the  six  books  "  (al-kutub 
al-sittah)  or  the  six  sahihs,  i.  e.,  the  six  reliable  collections. 
Two  of  them,1  namely  that  by  al-Bukhari  (f  256/870)  and 
the  one  by  Muslim  (f  261/875)  are  especially  esteemed. 
The  reason  for  this  lies  in  the  fact  that  by  the  time  they 
were  compiled  some  of  the  most  bitterly  fought  questions 
had  been  almost  settled  and  the  structure  of  orthodoxy  fairly 
established.  These  two  collections  therefore  represented 
in  a  way  the  current  views  and  found  ready  and  general 
acceptance.  As  in  the  case  of  the  Koran,  voluminous  com- 
mentaries were  written  on  the  sunnah,  as  well.  Among  the 
most  well-known  is  the  commentary  of  al-Qastallani  on  the 
sahih  of  al-Bukhari. 

SECTION  II 

The  Different  Kinds  of  Sunnah  with  Respect  to 
Transmission 

From  the  viewpoint  of  "continuity"  (ittisdl),  i.  e.,  the 
completeness  of  the  chain  of  transmission  from  the  last  trans- 
speculative  elements  in  the  law,  whereas  the  Shafiites  laid  emphasis  on 
the  hadiths.  For  full  information  concerning  the  science  of  badiths 
see  the  Introductions  in  the  commentaries  of  al-Qastallani  and  al- 
Nawawi  on  al-Bukhari  and  Muslim  respectively.  The  latter  is  on  the 
margin  of  the  former.  (Qastallani,  pp.  2-46  and  2-60.) 

1  The  other  four  collections  are  those  made  by  Ibn  Majah  (+273/ 
886),  Abu  Dawud  (+275/888),  al-Tirmidhi  (+279/892),  and  al- 
Nasa'i  (+303/915).  (Juynboll,  fn.  2,  p.  20;  cf.  Goldziher,  M.  Studien, 
vol.  ii,  pp.  254  et  seq.). 


40  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [350 

mitter  all  the  way  back  to  the  Prophet,1  the  canonists  have 
distinguished  four  kinds  of  sunnah,2  the  first  three  being 
"  continuous  "  and  the  fourth  "  discontinuous." 

The  "continuous"  (muttasil)  report  (of  the  sunnah) 
includes : 

( i )  The  Mutawatir.  It  is  the  report  of  a  people  numeri- 
cally indefinite  (la  yuhsa  fadaduhum)  s  whose  agreement 
upon  a  lie  is  inconceivable,  in  view  of  their  large  number, 
reliability  ('adalah),  and  diversity  of  residence.4  According 
to  one  view,  the  name  mutawatir  applies  only  to  the  report 
which  inspires  confidence  by  virtue  of  the  large  number  of 
its  reporters.  According  to  this  view  a  report  would  not  be 
called  mutawatir  if  its  content  is  believed  on  other  grounds, 

1  Tech.  Diet.,  p.  1507. 

2  By  sunnah  here  is  meant  only  the  sayings  of  the  Prophet.     The 
doings  of  the  Prophet  are  dealt  with  separately  (Kashf,  p.  679),  but 
the  principles  here  mentioned  must  also  apply  to  them,  because  the 
only  difference  between  the  two  would  be,  that  in  one  case  we  have 
the  sayings  of  the  Prophet,  and  in  the  other,  we  have  the  sayings  of 
the  persons  who  witnessed  the  doings  of  the  Prophet.    The  doctors,  in 
speaking  of  the  different  kinds  of  sunnah,  speak  of  them  advisedly  as 
divisions  of  the  report   (khabar)   in  order  to  include  the  reports  of 
both  the  sayings  and  the  doings  of  the  Prophet.    (Cf.  Tawdlh,  p.  358; 
Talwih,  p.  359.) 

•The  Arabic  word  ah$a  means,  to  count,  reach  the  last  number,  col- 
lect into  an  aggregate  by  numbering,  comprehend  (see  Lane,  under 
has.a).  According  to  the  Talwih  (p.  359)  the  expression  la  yuhsa 
(meaning,  cannot  be  collected  into  an  aggregate  by  numbering)  used 
in  the  above  definition  means,  it  cannot  be  made  a  matter  of  record 
(la  yad-khul  takht  al-dabt),  and  in  this  sense  it  is  opposed  to  qawm 
tnahsiir,  meaning,  a  body  of  people  whose  number  can  be  made  a  matter 
of  record,  for  example,  people  congregated  within  four  walls.  The 
Talwih  further  states  that  no  definite  number  is  required  for  the  muta- 
wdtir  (cf.  Kashf,  p.  681).  In  other  words,  the  expression  la  yuh$a 
must  not  be  taken  to  mean,  too  many  to  be  counted. 

*  Taw$ih,  p.  358 ;  Pazdawi,  p.  681 ;  Shawkani,  p.  44 ;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,, 
pp.  77  et  seq.;  Tech.  Diet.,  pp.  1471-2. 


35 1  ]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNN  AH         4I 

e.  g.,  when  the  report  states  a  matter  of  axiomatic  knowl- 
edge (dariirah)  or  when  it  is  believed  on  grounds  of  reason.1 

Various  conditions  must  be  met  before  a  report  may  be 
classed  as  mutawatir.  Only  three  of  these  are  considered 
necessary  (sahlh)  and  are  as  follows : 2 

(a)  The  number  of  the  reporters  must  be  large  enough 
to  preclude  ordinarily  (ladah)  an  agreement  among  them  to 
spread  a  false  report.3  Some  attempted  to  fix  a  minimum 
varying  from  as  low  as  4  up  into  the  hundreds.  According 
to  one  view,  the  number  required  varies  with  the  character 
of  the  reporters,  as  well  as  the  content  of  the  report;  the 
number  therefore  need  not  be  large,  since  even  the  report 
of  a  single  person,  such  as  a  prophet,  may  engender  positive 
knowledge;  moreover,  the  report  of  a  religious  leader  may 
be  worth  more  than  that  of  10,000  people,  e.  g.,  if  the  latter 
pretended  to  report  concerning  God.  It  is  exactly  on  this 
account,  the  upholders  of  this  view  go  on  to  say,  that  the 
mutawatir  has  been  defined  by  some  doctors  (muhaqqiqiln) 
as  the  report  of  those  who  cannot  ordinarily  be  lying, 
whether  one  or  more.  This  view  is  confirmed  by  what  is  re- 
lated of  al-Pazdawi,  namely,  that  he,  at  one  time,  considered 
as  mutawdtirs  reports  originally  transmitted  by  single  Com- 
panions, but  later  spread  and  reported  by  many.4  Accord- 
ing to  the  Kashf 5  "  the  number  is  not  confined  to  any 
definite  figure,  but  the  mere  fact  that  a  number  inspires 
knowledge  is  a  sufficient  test  of  its  adequacy  .  .  .  the  proof 
that  the  number  is  not  confined  to  any  one  figure  is  that  we 
consider  "  a  report  as  mutawatir  without  actually  determin- 

1  Shawkani,  p.  44. 

2  Tech.  Diet.,  loc.  cit. 
8  Cf.  Kashf,  p.  681. 

*  Pazdawi's  later  opinion  is  the  one  according  to  which  the  muta- 
wdtir  has  been  first  defined. 
6  P.  681. 


42  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [352 

ing  a  definite  number,  "  for  if  we  should  impose  upon  our- 
selves the  knowledge  of  a  number,  we  would  not  be  ordin- 
arily able  to  find  a  way  "  of  ascertaining  the  true  number, 
since  it  is  constantly  changing  and  its  determination  is 
humanly  impossible. 

(b)  The  reporters  must  base  their  reports  on  sense  per- 
ception.     If,   therefore,   a   great   congregation   of   people 
should  report  that  the  universe  has  been  created,  for  ex- 
ample, their  report  would  not  constitute  a  mutawatir. 

(c)  The  above  conditions  must  have  been  met  from  the 
origin  of  the  report  to  the  very  end. 

The  conditions  which  are  not  considered  necessary 
(fasid)  are :  that  the  reporters  should  be  Moslems  and  just; 
that  they  should  live  in  the  same  locality  and  belong  to  the 
same  race  and  religion;  or  as  the  Shiites  claim,  that  they 
should  include  among  themselves  the  "  infallible  "  (al- 
ma'sum)  ; *  or  finally,  as  the  Jews  claimed,  that  they  should 
be  people  deprived  of  power  (ahl  al-dhillah),  as  these  could 
not  conceivably  agree  upon  a  lie  through  fear  of  the 
consequences. 

How  are  we  to  tell  that  the  conditions  have  been  met? 
Those  who  believe  that  the  mutawatir  does  not  engender 
axiomatic  (daruri)  knowledge,  hold  that  a  report  may  not 
be  claimed  as  a  mutawatir  except  after  ascertaining  that  the 
conditions  have  been  actually  met.  On  the  other  hand, 
those  who  believe  that  the  mutawatir  engenders  axiomatic 
knowledge,  hold  that  the  mere  fact  that  a  report  has  in- 
spired conviction  is  normally  a  proof  that  the  conditions 
have  been  met.2  According  to  the  Kashf  3  the  sufficiency 

1  For  example,  the  sect  of  Hisham  Ibn  al-Hakam  believe  that  the 
itndms  or  leaders  of  the  Moslem  community  are  infallible,  in  the  sense 
that  they  cannot  commit  a  mistake  or  sin.  (Bagdadi,  p.  50.) 

»  Tech.  Diet.,  loc.  tit. 

8  Loc.  cit. 


353]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNN  AH         43 

of  the  number  of  the  transmitters  is  inferred,  if  their  re- 
port  has  inspired  knowledge,  for  this  indicates  that  the 
number  was  complete  before  God. 

What  is  the  Value  (hukm)  of  the  mutawatir?  The 
majority  agree  that  the  mutawatir  engenders  positive  knowl- 
edge (yaqm)  and  that  the  person  who  denies  this  is  a 
profligate  (saflh).  Some  said  that  the  mutawatir  is  open 
to  doubt  inasmuch  as  the  report  of  each  transmitter  by  itself 
is  liable  to  be  false,  but  this  is  evidently  nonsense  and  heresy, 
since  it  would  cast  doubt  upon  the  very  existence  of  the 
prophets  and  their  miracles  which  we  at  present  can  learn 
about  only  through  reports.1  There  is  difference  of  opinion 
as  to  whether  the  knowledge  engendered  by  the  mutawatir  is 
axiomatic  (daruri)  or  merely  inferential  (istidlali,  or 
nadari).  According  to  al-Taftazani,2  axiomatic  knowledge 
is  that  which  occurs  in  the  mind  through  intuition  and  not 
as  a  result  of  reflective  thought  (nadar).  Inferential  is  its 
opposite.8 

Those  who  claim  that  the  mutawatir  creates  axiomatic 
knowledge,  support  their  view  by  the  argument  that,  if  it 
were  inferential,  it  would  not  engender  knowledge  in  the 
mind  of  children  and  the  weak-minded,  since  the  latter  do 
not  possess  the  ability  to  make  inferences.4  Their  opponents 
reply  that  the  knowledge  of  the  truth  of  a  report,  among 
others,  implies  a  knowledge  of  the  normal  impossibility  of 

1  Kashf,  p.  683. 

2  Tech.  Diet.,  p.  882. 

1  Axiomatic  has  also  a  more  general  meaning,  i.  e.,  the  knowledge 
which  occurs  in  the  mind  independently  of  human  will,  such  as  a  per- 
son's knowledge  of  his  pain  and  pleasure.  In  this  sense,  axiomatic  is 
opposed  to  "  acquisitional "  (iktisdbi)  which  applies  to  the  knowledge 
that  requires  some  initiative  on  the  part  of  the  knower,  as,  for  ex- 
ample, in  the  case  of  perceptual  or  intellectual  knowledge. 

4  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  80. 


44  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [354 

an  agreement  upon  a  lie  among  the  transmitters  of  that 
report,  as  well  as  a  knowledge  of  the  absence  of  incentives 
for  such  an  agreement;  but  these  are  nothing  but  cases  of 
inference;  hence  the  knowledge  engendered  by  the  muta- 
wdtir is  inferential.  The  first  side  answers  that  such  pre- 
liminary notions  as  are  necessary  are  only  incidental,  and 
occur  in  the  mind  readily  without  any  special  thought  or 
effort. 

When  the  reports  of  several  transmitters  answer  the 
description  of  mutawdtir  but  differ  from  one  another,  only 
their  common  meaning  is  considered  mutawdtir.1 

Examples  of  mutawdtir  are  the  passages  in  the  Koran, 
and  the  sunnah  concerning  the  number  of  prostrations,  the 
rates  of  zakat,  etc. 

(2)  The   Mash-hur   (literally,   widespread).     This  is  a 
report  originally  supported  by  a  few  individuals  (dhdd),2 
but  later  spread  and  transmitted  by  a  numerically  indefinite 
people  whose  agreement  upon  a  lie  is  inconceivable,  these 
people  being  the  generations  succeeding  to  the  Companions. 
In  other  words,  it  is  necessary  that  the  diffusion  of  the 
report  should  have  taken  place  in  the  first  or  second  gener- 
ation after  Mohammed,  not  later.     According  to  the  or- 
thodox view,  the  mash-hur  stands  higher  than  the  "  in- 
dividual ;  "  and  its  non-acceptance  entails  error,  but  not 
heresy.8     The  mash-hur  engenders  conviction  but  not  posi- 
tive knowledge  (yaqm). 

(3)  The  "individual  "  report  (khabar  al-wahid).     This 
is  the  report  transmitted  by  one  or  two  or  even  more,  pro- 

1  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  89. 

2  Their  number  may  be  one  or  more  provided  it  falls  short  of  that 
required  for  the  mutawdtir.    Some  call  the  masli-hur  mustafld,  if  there 
were  at  least  three  individuals. 

8  Pazdawi,  p.  688. 


355]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNN  AH         4$ 

vided  their  number  falls  short  of  that  required  for  the 
mutawatir.  The  value  (hukm)  of  this  report  is,  that 
though  it  does  not  establish  positive  knowledge,  it  creates 
obligation  for  conduct.  This  is  the  Hanifite  view.  Some 
claimed  that  it  does  not  create  obligation  for  conduct  since  it 
does  not  engender  knowledge,  as  conduct  may  be  based  on 
knowledge  alone.  Conversely,  some  hadlth-iolk  expressed 
the  view  that  the  "  individual  "  report  engenders  knowledge 
since  it  creates  obligation  for  conduct.  The  Hanifites  sup- 
port their  view  by  evidences  from  the  Koran,  the  ijma( 
and  reason. 

The  "discontinuous"  report  (al-khabar  al-munqatf)S 
This  is  the  report  in  whose  continuity  of  transmission,  un- 
like that  of  the  former  three  reports,  there  is  a  break. 

"  Discontinuity  "  may  be  either  formal  (zahir)  or  real 
(batin).2 

(a)  "  Formal  discontinuity."  This  occurs  when  the  con- 
tinuity of  transmission  is  not  complete  all  the  way  back  to 
the  Prophet,  as  in  the  case  of  an  unsupported  report 
(mursal)  ,3  that  is,  when  there  is  failure  to  mention  the  chain 
of  transmitters,  as,  for  example,  when  some  one  says,  "  The 
Prophet  said  so  and  so,"  without  supporting  (isnad)  his 
statement  by  saying  "  So  and  so  related  to  us,  on  the  au- 
thority of  so  and  so,  on  the  authority  of  the  Prophet."  The 
unsupported  reports  (mursal)  of  the  Companions  are  ac- 
cepted unanimously,  since  they  are  reputed  to  be  based  on 
direct  hearing  (sima')  from  the  Prophet  himself.  The  un- 

1  Taw fch,  p.  367 ;  Pazdawi,  p.  722. 
*  Tawdih,  p.  367. 

3  According  to  the  usage  of  the  £ad»f/t-teachers,  mursal  means  a  re- 
port, none  of  the  transmitters  of  which  has  been  mentioned;  musnad 
(supported)  is  used  for  the  opposite.  On  the  other  hand,  the  report 
is  called  munqatf,  if  only  one  transmitter  is  omitted,  and  mu'&al,  if 
more. 


46  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [356 

supported  reports  of  the  second  and  third  generations  are 
not  accepted  by  al-Shafi'i,  except  when  their  "  continuity  " 
is  established  in  some  other  way.  However,  such  reports 
are  considered  by  the  Hanifites  and  by  Malik  to  be  superior 
to  supported  reports  (musnad).  They  are  thought  to  be 
superior  because  it  is  customary  that  the  just  man  (W/), 
when  he  is  convinced  about  the  truth  of  a  report  and  its 
support,  omits  the  support  and  links  it  directly  to  the  Pro- 
phet, saying  "  The  Prophet  said;  "  but  when  he  is  not  con- 
vinced about  it,  he  refers  it  to  the  person  from  whom  he 
heard  it.1  Thus,  a  certain  Hasan  is  reported  to  have  said :  2 
"  Whenever  four  of  the  Companions  agreed  before  me  on 
a  hadlth,  I  used  to  ascribe  it  directly  to  the  Prophet."  Simi- 
lar statements  were  made  by  others. 

(b)  "  Real  Discontinuity."  This  happens  when  the  re- 
port contradicts  an  evidence  stronger  than  itself,  such  as, 
for  example,  the  Koran  or  the  mutawdtir,  or  when  there 
is  a  defect  in  the  transmitter  (ndqil). 

Contradiction,  the  first  kind  of  "  real  discontinuity,"  may 
occur  in  the  following  four  ways:  (i)  when  the  report 
contradicts  the  Koran;  (2)  when  it  contradicts  the  "es- 
tablished sunnah  "  that  is  the  sunnah  based  on  the  mutawatir 
and  the  mash-hur;  (3)  when  an  "individual"  report 
has  not  reached  the  degree  of  mash-hur*  in  spite  of  the 
fact  that  there  is  a  general  need  for  such  a  report;  (4) 
when  it  has  been  denounced  by  the  Companions. 

When  it  contradicts  the  Koran,  the  report  is  overruled 
in  every  case.  There  is  invoked  for  justification  of  this 
overruling  the  following  hadlth:  "After  my  death  the 
hadiths  will  multiply;  when  therefore  a  hadlth  is  related  to 

1  Pazdawi,  p.  724. 

1  Kashf,  ibid. 

»  Taqrlr,  vol.  ii,  pp.  295-7;  Talwlh,  p.  371. 


357]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNNAH         47 

you,  compare  it  with  the  Book  of  God  and  when  it  agrees 
with  it,  accept  it;  but  if  it  contradicts  it,  reject  it."  The 
above  view  is  the  Hanifite  one.  The  Shafiites  have  thought 
differently.  When  the  report  contradicts  the  "  established 
sunnah,"  again  it  is  overruled.1 

Similarly  following  the  opinion  of  al-Karkhi,2  an  "  in- 
dividual "  report  is  brushed  aside  when  it  has  failed  to 
reach  the  degree  of  the  mash-hur,  or  to  receive  recognition 
by  widespread  use, — all  this  notwithstanding  the  fact  that 
there  is  a  general  need  for  the  report,  in  that  it  relates  to  a 
matter  of  frequent  occurrence.  For  example,  the  hadith, 
according  to  which  the  first  verse  of  the  opening  chapter  of 
the  Koran  must  be  read  aloud  in  prayer,  is  not  considered 
obligatory.  The  argument  is  that  if  the  hadith  were  true, 
it  would  not  have  failed  to  attain  wide  circulation  or  gen- 
eral use,  considering  that  it  concerns  a  matter  of  every- 
day occurrence  like  prayer.  The  mere  fact  that  it  remained 
an  "  individual  "  report  is  a  presumption  of  its  unreliability. 
However,  the  majority  of  writers  on  usul-al-fiqh,  as  well 
as  al-Shafii  and  all  the  hadlth-iolk  hold  that  such  "  individ- 
uals "  are  valid,  if  they  otherwise  conform  to  the  rules.8 

Finally,  denunciation  of  the  "  individual "  report  by  the 
Companions  is  sufficient  to  cause  its  rejection. 

The  second  kind  of  "  real  discontinuity  "  occurs  when 

1  It  must  be  remembered  here  that  when  we  speak  of  contradiction 
between  a  report  and  the  Koran,  or  between  a  report  and  the  sunnah, 
we  mean  specifically  the  "individual"  report  only,  not  the  ntutawdtir 
or  the  mash-hur.  (Cf.  chapter  on  Abrogation  and  Conflict  of  the  Evi- 
dences; also  Pazdwai,  p.  728. 

8  Kashf,  p.  736. 

s  Riad  Ghali,  in  his  dissertation  on  the  sunnah  (pp.  191-3)  gives  a  quite 
different  version  on  this  point.  Unless  it  is  due  to  the  sources  he  used, 
though  this  is  unlikely,  it  must  be  the  result  of  his  misunderstanding  of 
the  Arabic  expression  fi  'I  balwa  al-dmm  used  by  the  doctors  in  this 
connection. 


48  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [358 

there  is  a  short-coming  in  the  person  of  the  transmitter, 

namely:  (i)  when  he  is  "  unknown  "  (mastur),  i.  e.,  when 
it  is  not  known  whether  he  is  just  or  impious,  although  the 
first  three  generations  are  an  exception  to  this  rule;  (2) 
when  he  is  impious  (fasiq)  ;  (3)  when  he  has  not  attained 
the  age  of,  or  is  not  endowed  with,  complete  understanding, 
as  in  the  case  of  minors,  the  weak-minded  (ma'tuh},  the 
careless  (muggaffal),  and  heretics  (sahib  al  hawa).1 

SECTION    III 

Qualifications  Regarding  the  Transmitter  as  Such  2 
The  transmitter  (al-rawi)  is  of  two  kinds,  the  "  well- 
known  "  (al-mafruf)  and  the  "unknown"  (al-majhul). 
The  "  well-known  "  is  one  known  to  have  transmitted  many 
hadithSj  whereas  the  "  unknown  "  is  one  who  is  not  known 
to  have  transmitted  more  than  one  or  two  hadiths. 

( i )  The  "  well-known  "  transmitter.  He  is  of  two 
kinds:  the  one  who  is  also  a  faqih,  besides  being  a  trans- 
mitter, and  the  other  who  is  only  a  transmitter. 

(a)  The  well-known  transmitters  who  are  also  faqlhs. 
As  such  are  considered  the  first  four  Califs,  'Abdallah  Ibn 
Mas'ud,  'Abdallah  Ibn  'Abbas,  Ibn  'Omar,  Zayd,  Mu'adh, 
Abu  Musa  al-Ash'ari,  'Aishah,  and  others.    The  hadiths  re- 
ported by  these  are  accepted  whether  or  not  in  accordance 
with  qiyas. 

(b)  The  "  well-known  "  transmitters  who  are  not  faqihs. 
These  are  those  who  like  Abu  Hurayrah  are  reputed  for 
their  justice  and  careful  record-taking.     The  hadiths  re- 
ported by  these  are  accepted  if  in  accordance  with  qiyas. 
In  the  contrary  case  they  are  abandoned,  because  these  trans- 
mitters, not  being  faqihs,  may  have  taken  a  wrong  record. 


1  Taw&h,  p.  372. 

2  Tawdih,  p.  362 ;  Pazdawi,  pp.  758  et  seq. 


359]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNN  AH         49 

If  however,  their  reports  are  in  accordance  with  one  qiyas 
and  at  variance  with  another,  they  are  not  abandoned. 

(2)  The  "  unknown  "  transmitter. 

(a)  If  the  salaf  1  have  transmitted  a  hadith  on  the  au- 
thority of  an  "  unknown  "  transmitter  and  testified  to  the 
truth  of  this  hadith,  the  hadith  is  then  considered  like  those 
of  the  non-faqlh  "  well-known  "  transmitters. 

(b)  If  the  salaf  have  desisted  from  denouncing  the  hadith 
after  its  communication  to  them,  it  is  like  the  hadiths  of 
the  "  well-known  "  transmitters,  for  silence  when  speech  is 
necessary  is  equivalent  to  assent. 

(c)  If  some  have  accepted  and  others  denounced  it,  and 
at  the  same  time  trustworthy  people  have  transmitted  it  on 
his  authority,  it  is  accepted,  if  in  accordance  with  qiyas; 
though  if  not  in  accordance  it  is  rejected. 

(d)  If  his  hadith  has  been  rejected  by  all  the  salaf  (mus- 
tankar),  it  is  abandoned. 

(e)  If  it  is  not  known  whether  the  salaf  have  accepted  or 
rejected  it  (mustatir),  the  qiyas  overrules  it,  and  conduct 
in  conformity  with  it  is  not  obligatory,  but  only  permissible 
(ja'iz). 

SECTION  IV 

Conditions  of  Retention  and  Transmission  * 
RETENTION,      (i)   The  transmitter  must  possess  com- 
plete understanding  obtained  only  on  coming  of  age. 

(2)  The  conditions  of  retention  (dabt)  must  be  fulfilled. 

These  conditions  are  the  proper  hearing  of  a  report  from 
beginning  to  end,  as  well  as  the  thorough  understanding  of 

1  Salaf  means  literally  the  predecessors,  and  technically  (see  Tech. 
Diet.)  those  of  the  predecessors  who  are  followed  as  authority,  e.  g.t 
the  Companions  are  salaf  for  Abu  Hanifah. 

*  Tawfch,  p.  376;  Pazdawi,  p.  758. 


50  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [360 

its  meaning,  in  addition  to  its  retention  until  it  is  passed 
on  (add')  to  others.  The  perfection  of  retention  is  reached, 
when  the  retention  of  the  form  and  the  literal  meaning  of 
the  report  is  coupled  with  a  thorough  understanding  of  its 
legal  meaning  as  well.  The  hearing  (simac)  is  considered 
proper  when  the  /md^/M:ransmitter  reads  the  hadith  in  the 
hearing  of  the  listener  and  the  latter  repeats  it  and  then  says : 
"  Is  it  as  I  have  repeated  it?"  the  teacher  replying,  "  Yes." 
Writing  or  delegation  (risalah)  is  deemed  equivalent  to 
actual  addressing. 

The  retention  may  be  effected  by  committing  the  hadith 
or  report  to  the  memory,  or  to  a  record.  In  the  beginning, 
the  former  was  regarded  as  the  ideal  way  ('azlmah) ;  but 
later  the  second  method  came  to  supplant  it. 

TRANSMISSION.  Some  /md^A-teachers  will  not  allow 
transmission  of  the  sense  alone,  but  the  majority  of  the 
doctors  hold  the  opposite  view.  Of  course,  they  all  agree 
that  literal  transmission  is  to  be  preferred.  The  trans- 
mission of  the  sense  of  the  Koran  is  allowed  only  to 
the  mujtahid. 

In  the  transmission  of  the  sense  the  following  points 
must  be  borne  in  mind : 

(a)  If  the  sense  is  clear   (zahir)    the  transmission  is 
allowed  to  the  person  who  knows  the  language. 

(b)  If  the  sense  is  clear  but  the  word  is  liable  to  have 
another  meaning  as  well,  as  in  the  case  of  a  universal 
((dmm)  term  liable  to  restriction  (takhsls),  or  when  there 
is  the  probability  of  a  metaphorical  meaning,  then  the  trans- 
mission is  allowed  to  the  mujtahid  alone. 

(c)  When  a  term  may  have  several  literal  meanings 
(mushtarak),  or  its  meaning  is  hard  to  understand,   or 
mystical,  only  the  literal  transmission  is  allowed. 

(3)  The  transmitter  must  possess  justice  ('adalah),  that 
is,  he  must  refrain  from  the  commission  of  capital  sins 


36l]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNN  AH          5I 

(kabirah)  and  must  not  persist  in  the  commission  of  venial 
sins  (sagirah). 

(4)  The  transmitter  must  be  a  Moslem.  This  require- 
ment is  because  the  fanaticism  of  a  heretic  might  be  apt 
to  prejudice  Islam,  and  not  as  we  might  suppose  because 
all  other  religions  do  not  uniformly  prohibit  lying. 

SECTION  v 
The  Impeachment  of  Hadiths 

The  impeachment  (ta'n)  of  a  hadith  may  originate  with 
the  transmitter  himself  or  elsewhere. 

(1)  When  the  impeachment  originates  with  the  trans- 
mitter himself,  it  may  be  express  or  implicit.     It  is  express, 
when  the  person  claimed  to  be  the  transmitter  of  a  hadith 
angrily  repudiates  the  fact  of  his  transmission,  calling  the 
person  who  claimed  it  a  liar,  or  when  he  contents  himself 
with  a  mere  denial  of  his  transmission.     In  the  first  case, 
the  hadith  is  considered  by  the  majority  as  void,  but  opinion 
is  divided  on  the  second  case.1 

It  is  implicit  when;  (a)  the  transmitter  acts  or  counsels 
in  opposition  to  his  own  hadith.  In  such  case  the  hadith 
is  null,  unless  it  be  that  he  had  acted  thus  before  trans- 
mitting the  hadith,  or  that  the  date  of  his  transmission  is 
not  known;  (b)  he  acts  according  to  some  only  of  the  pos- 
sible meanings  of  the  hadith.  This  amounts  to  the  im- 
peachment of  its  other  meanings,  (c)  He  neither  acts  in 
accordance  with  his  hadith,  nor  contrary  to  it.  It  is  still 
a  case  of  impeachment,  because  to  refrain  from  doing  what 
is  commanded  is  equivalent  to  opposition  to  it.2 

(2)  When  the  impeachment  originates  elsewhere:   (a) 

1  Pazdawi,  pp.  779  et  seq. ;  cf.  Ghali,  pp.  195  et  seq. 
1  Ghali,  p.  205. 


52  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [362 

it  comes  from  the  Companions.  In  such  case,  the  hadith 
is  void,  if  in  all  probability  it  was  known  to  them, 
but  it  remains  valid,  if  the  probability  is  that  it  was  un- 
known to  them,  e.  g.,  if  the  hadith  referred  to  a  chance  oc- 
currence; (b)  it  comes  from  the  hadith-teachers.1 

The  impeachment  of  the  /^ad^-teachers  may  be  of  two 
kinds.  It  may  be  indefinite,2  and  then  it  is  not  taken  into 
consideration.  Or  it  may  be  based  on  a  legally  admissible 
ground,  and  then  the  hadith  is  ruled  out.  It  is  necessary, 
however,  in  this  last  case,  that  the  accuser  be  not  tainted 
with  party  spirit  and  enmity,  otherwise  his  accusation  is 
ignored.  According  to  al-Pazdawi,3  the  accusations  of  the 
heretics  against  the  Sunnites,  and  of  the  Shafiites  against 
some  of  the  early  Hanifites,  have  been  set  aside  for  this 
last  reason.  According  to  the  same  author,  there  are  about 
30  to  40  legitimate  ways  of  impeachment.4 

Finally,  when  the  hadith  is  impeached  by  some  and 
accepted  by  others,  the  hadith  is  not  considered  void,  if  the 
number  of  its  defenders  is  at  least  equal  to  that  of  its  de- 
nouncers, unless  it  be  that  the  defenders  are  not  acquainted 
with  the  facts.5 

SECTION  VI 

Are  the  Rules  Concerning  the  Sunnah  an  Adequate 
Guarantee  of  Its  Reliability 

It  must  be  remarked  at  the  beginning  that  the  preceding 
rules  are  ultimately  intended  for  religious  purposes,  and 

1  Pazdawi,  p.  786;  cf.  Ghali,  p.  207. 

s  For  example,  the  accuser  says,  "  This  hadith  is  abandoned,  or  is 
not  authentic,  or  its  transmitter  is  not  just,"  etc.,  without  explaining 
the  grounds  on  which  he  bases  his  impeachment. 

8  P.  795. 

4  Cf.  Tawdih,  pp.  378  et  seq.;  Taqrtr,  vol.  ii,  p.  258. 

6  Ghali,  p.  213. 


363]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNNAH          53 

therefore  they  are  subject  to  the  limitations  of  all  re- 
ligious reasoning,  no  matter  how  scientific  it  may  appear. 
For  instance,  the  rules  in  question  have  almost  nothing  to 
say  concerning  the  subject-matter  of  the  hadlths.  Thus 
a  hadith  which  claims  the  occurrence  of  things  existing  only 
in  the  wildest  imagination  would  be  accepted  as  genuine, 
if  all  the  mechanical  rules  concerning  its  transmission  were 
conformed  to,  since  no  higher  criticism  would  be  exercised 
as  regards  its  content.  It  follows  that  a  considerable  ma- 
terial of  miraculous  nature  could  easily  find  its  way  into 
the  sunnah.  It  further  follows  that  hadlths  invented  with 
the  object  of  supporting  political  or  other  interests  could  be 
readily  incorporated  in  the  sunnah,  if  only  they  were  put 
in  circulation  by  prominent  and  influential  persons,  such  as 
the  Companions. 

Let  us  briefly  inquire  how  far  the  rules  mentioned  in 
the  preceding  sections  would  serve  to  check  an  accidental  or 
even  an  intentional  falsification  of  the  sunnah.  First  let  us 
examine  the  mutawatir  and  the  mash-hur. 

By  definition  it  would  seem  as  if  the  mutawatir  were  ab- 
solutely above  doubt.  Even  a  perfunctory  examination  into 
the  conditions  deemed  necessary  by  the  doctors  will  show 
that  this  is  not  so.  Theoretically  speaking,  the  mutawatir 
need  not  necessarily  be  superior  to  the  mash-hur,  or  con- 
ceivably, even  to  the  "  individual."  This  may,  at  first  blush, 
seem  to  be  a  preposterous  assertion,  but  it  will  not  be  hard 
to  prove.  According  to  definition,  the  only  difference 
between  the  mutawatir  and  the  mash-hur  is  that  the  muta- 
watir attained  wide  circulation  from  the  time  of  the  Com- 
panions, whereas  the  mash-hur  became  widespread  only  in 
the  next  two  generations.  In  other  words,  during  the  life- 
time of  the  Companions  the  mutawatir  supposedly  had  a 
wide  circulation  which  the  mash-hur  lacked.  But  the  entire 
issue  depends  upon  what  the  doctors  mean  by  a  wide  cir- 


54  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [364 

culation  (tawatur),  for  if  it  could  be  shown  that  a  muta- 
watir may  have  been  transmitted  by  as  few  transmitters 
as  a  given  mash-hur,  the  superiority  of  the  mutawatir  to 
the  mash-hur  as  regards  the  two  given  reports  would  forth- 
with become  imaginary.  We  have,  in  fact  seen,  that  the 
doctors  have  been  unanimous  in  declaring  that  the  number 
of  the  transmitters  of  a  mutawatir  need  not  be  a  fixed  num- 
ber. They  do  not  commit  themselves  to  a  minimum  even 
as  low  as  4.  One  report,  as  noted  above,  goes  so  far  as 
to  ascribe  to  al-Pazdawi  the  view  that  the  report  of  a  single 
Companion  might  spread  and  become  a  mutawatir.  We  need 
not,  however,  make  use  of  this  extreme  position.  Accord- 
ing to  the  orthodox  definition,  a  report  transmitted  origin- 
ally, e.  g.,  by  10  or  more,  may  be  no  more  than  a  mash-hur, 
or  if  it  did  not  later  attain  great  diffusion,  merely  an  "  in- 
dividual," whereas  one  transmitted  by  fewer  than  10  may 
be  a  mutawatir.  It  is  not  then,  so  much  the  number  of  the 
reporters,  at  any  rate,  the  original  reporters,  that  decides 
whether  a  report  shall  be  considered  a  mutawatir,  but  rather 
it  is  the  fact  that  a  report  appeals  as  genuine.  If  a  report 
is  accepted,  that  very  fact  indicates  that  the  number  was 
sufficiently  large.  Al-Bukhari,  in  the  Kashf,  plainly  implies 
that  the  mutawatirs  were  not  so  classed,  because  after  a 
special  inquiry  the  numbers  of  their  reporters  were  found 
to  be  sufficient,  but  because  in  the  first  place  they  had  ap- 
pealed as  genuine  and  received  recognition.  His  justifica- 
tion for  it  is  that  it  is  impossible  actually  to  determine  the 
number  because  it  is  constantly  growing.  Besides,  he  finds 
it  unnecessary,  for  he  assumes  that  God  would  not  cause  a 
report  to  call  forth  conviction,  had  the  number  of  its  re- 
porters been  insufficient. 

Clearly  then  a  report  classed  as  mutawatir  might  have 
been  originally  transmitted  by  the  same  number  or  even 
possibly  a  smaller  number  of  transmitters,  than  a  mash-hur 


365]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNNAH         55 

or  even  an  "  individual."  The  fact  is  that,  the  various  re- 
ports transmitted  from  the  Prophet  have  not  been  accorded 
hierarchical  precedence,  as  statements  of  fact,  on  the  basis 
of  a  previous  inquiry  into  the  circumstances  which  sur- 
rounded their  transmission.  On  the  contrary,  this  preced- 
ence first  appeared  as  a  matter  of  usage,  and  only  later  after 
some  of  the  reports  had  already  attained  great  diffusion, 
has  an  attempt  been  made  by  the  doctors  to  differentiate 
them  into  classes.  Viewed  in  this  light,  the  difference  be- 
tween the  mutawdtir  and  the  mash-hilr  reduces  itself  to  one 
of  wide  circulation,  not  so  much  during  the  earliest  stage 
of  transmission  by  the  Companions,  but  chiefly  during  later 
stages.  The  reports  which  referred  to  matters  of  common 
occurrence  or  general  interest,  or  accorded  with  the  current 
views  and  practices,  at  once  spread  and  became  common 
knowledge,  whereas  other  reports  less  favorably  circum- 
stanced, did  not  spread  so  rapidly,  or  even  at  all.  Of  course, 
the  rapid  diffusion  of  a  report,  in  itself,  constitutes  a  con- 
siderable guarantee  that  the  report  is  true,  but  as  already 
hinted,  the  diffusion  and  favorable  reception  of  a  report 
might  have  been  due  to  the  fact  that  the  report  fitted  in 
with  the  current  tendencies  and  practices.  A  mutawdtir 
of  this  last  type  evidently  would  not  be  any  more  reliable, 
as  a  statement  of  fact,  than  a  report  which  being  less  for- 
tunate became  only  a  mash-hur,  since  the  original  trans- 
mitters of  both  reports  might  have  been  as  numerous  or  as 
trustworthy. 

It  is  therefore  easy  to  understand  the  psychology  of  the 
doctors  who,  on  the  one  hand,  imply  that  the  number  must 
be  large,  and  on  the  other  hand,  carefully  avoid  committing 
themselves  to  any  sort  of  a  minimum.  They  were  indeed 
laboring  under  difficulties.  They  could  not  ignore  the  num- 
ber of  reporters  and  the  matter  of  diffusion,  for  when  they 
made  their  classifications  the  main  distinction  among  the 


56  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [366 

different  reports  was  the  varying  extent  of  their  respective 
diffusions.  But  they  could  not  also  ignore  the  fact  that 
some  mutawatirs  might  have  been  originally  transmitted  by 
no  more  transmitters  than  others,  which  they  had  classed 
only  as  mash-hurs.  Hence  they  only  imply  the  matter  of 
diffusion,  and  as  regards  the  actual  definition  of  the  extent 
of  that  diffusion,  in  other  words,  the  number  of  the  trans- 
mitters, they  take  refuge  in  indetermination  by  using  the 
ingenious  expression  la  yuhsa.1  Thanks  to  this  expression 
they  could  always  claim  that  the  number  might  have  been 
larger  than  any  given  number,  and  in  fact,  as  we  saw,  they 
did  not  concern  themselves  with  its  actual  determination. 
This  expression  appears  to  have  caused  the  doctors  some 
inconvenience,  also,  as  would  seem  to  have  been  the  case 
from  the  following  quotation  from  the  Kashf.2  "  The 
majority  held  the  view  that  numerical  indefiniteness  is  not  a 
necessary  condition,  for  if  the  pilgrims  or  the  congregation 
of  a  mosque  should  report  an  event  which  kept  them  from 
the  pilgrimage  or  the  prayer,  their  reports  would  still  pro- 
duce knowledge,  although  they  may  be  definite  in  number." 
If  one  is  to  believe  the  following  quotation  from  the  same 
work,  even  the  spiritual  fathers  of  this  as  well  as  of  certain 
other  expressions,  providing  for  the  Islam,  justice,  etc.,  of 
the  transmitters,  did  not  seriously  mean  them,  but  rather 
used  them  as  a  means  to  silence  their  opponents :  "  The 
shaykh  (i.  e.,  al-Pazdawi)  adverted  to  these  meanings  (i.  e., 
the  provisions  concerning  the  indefiniteness  of  number,  etc. ) 
because  they  are  best  fitted  to  remove  all  doubt  and  to 
refute  adversaries,  not  because  they  are  real  conditions  ..." 

As  regards  the  "  individual,"  this  too,  like  the  mash-hur, 
theoretically  speaking,  may  have  been  transmitted  by  as 

1  Cf.  supra,  under  Mutawdtir. 

2  P.  681. 


367]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNNAH         57 

many  original  transmitters  as  the  mutawdtir,  the  only  differ- 
ence in  that  case  being  their  varying  diffusion  in  later  times. 
But  this  is  true  only  in  theory.  Doubtless  in  practice,  the 
"individual,"  which  constitutes  by  far  the  greatest  portion  of 
the  sunnah,  has  been,  generally  speaking,  transmitted  by  one 
or  few  transmitters.  But  the  "  individual  "  is  the  report 
which,  in  distinction  from  the  two  previous,  is  considered  by 
the  doctors,  as  a  report  equally  liable  to  be  true  or  false, 
according  as  its  reporters  are  just  or  impious.  It  is  there- 
fore only  to  the  individual  that  the  rules  set  forth  in  the 
previous  sections  concerning  "  discontinuity,"  transmission, 
transmitters  and  impeachment,  apply. 

Are  the  rules  concerning  the  "  individual  "  sufficient  to 

check  falsification?  The  answer  can  hardly  be  in  the  af- 
firmative, since  they  almost  entirely  ignore  the  content  and 
are  mainly  concerned  with  the  "continuity"  of  transmission 
all  the  way  back  to  the  Prophet.  A  hadith  is  declared  re- 
liable if  its  chain  of  transmission  is  unbroken.  But  even 
this  simple  rule  is  not  always  adhered  to.  Thus  according 
to  the  Hanifites  and  to  Malik,  the  hadiths  transmitted  by  the 
first  three  generations  may  have  a  broken  or  no  chain  of 
transmission.1  This  view  is  justified  on  the  ground  that 
the  first  three  generations  were  just.  Al-Shafi'i  takes  ex- 
ception to  this  view  as  regards  the  last  two  generations. 

The  only  rule  which  goes  into  the  substance  of  the  matter 
at  all,  is  that  concerning  the  justice  of  the  transmitters. 
But  the  conception  of  justice  is  very  mechanical.  A  man 
is  considered  just,  if  to  the  knowledge  of  outsiders,  he  has 
not  committed  one  of  the  so-called  capital  sins.  Moreover, 
as  regards  the  first  three  generations  2  it  is  not  necessary 
actually  to  determine  whether  even  this  minimum  of  re- 
quirement has  been  met.  They  are  assumed  to  be  just. 

1  Cf.  supra,  under  "  discontinuity." 
1  Cf.  supra,  mastiir. 


58  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [368 

The  rules  concerning  the  impeachment  of  hadiths  are 

not  less  subject  to  criticism.  Even  the  fact  that  a  person 
angrily  repudiates  having  transmitted  a  certain  hadith,  has 
not  been  deemed  sufficient  cause  for  setting  aside  that 
hadith.  Then,  too,  one  can  always  disregard  an  impeach- 
ment on  the  ground  that  it  has  been  actuated  by  partisan 
motives.  Finally,  the  requirement  that  a  hadith  must  not 
contradict  the  Koran  or  the  "  established  sunnah  "  1  -is  not 
a  sufficient  check,  because  not  only  would  it  apply  to  a  very 
small  proportion  of  hadiths,  but  also,  as  we  have  seen,  the 
mutawdtir  or  mash-hur  are  not  necessarily  superior  to  the 
"  individual." 

The  foregoing  discussion  conclusively  shows  that,  even 
if  we  assume  that  all  the  rules  have  been  obeyed,  the  mere 
fact  that  a  hadith  has  found  a  place  in  the  approved  col- 
lections, the  sahihs,  by  no  means  proves  its  genuineness. 
Unless  otherwise  confirmed,  there  is  always  a  theoretical 
possibility  that  it  might  have  been  forged.  The  Moham- 
medans themselves  have  recognized  this  possibility,  since 
most  of  them  agree  that  the  "  individual "  produces  only 
probable  knowledge  (zann),2  and  since  the  majority  would 
discourage  swearing  on  the  truth  of  the  sahihs  excepting 
those  by  al-Bukhari  and  Muslim.  Compare  also  the  fol- 
lowing statement  in  the  Tahdhib  3  by  'Omar  Ibn  Habib, 
who  in  defense  of  the  /todW/i-transmitters  against  im- 
peachment, is  supposed  to  have  said  to  the  Calif  Harun 
al-Rashid  :  "  Were  the  companions  of  the  Prophet  liars,  then 
the  [entire]  shari'ah  would  become  null  (batil)  and  the  legal 
provisions  (ahkam)  [derived  from  it]  should  be  rejected." 
In  other  words,  there  was  a  certain  reluctance  in  later  times 

1  Cf.  supra,  "  real  discontinuity." 

2  Nawawi,  on  the  margin  of  Qastallani,  pp.  29-30. 

3  Pp.  446-7- 


369]      THE  SECOND  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  SUNN  AH          59 

to  brand  well-known  /mdf//i-transmitters  of  the  first  three 
generations  of  Islam,  as  liars,  because  of  the  fear,  that  if 
this  were  allowed  in  principle,  the  evil  might  go  too  far. 

It  must  be  said  in  conclusion  that  the  preceding  consider- 
ations represent  only  theoretical  possibilities,  and  that  the 
question  whether  and  how  far  these  possibilities  have  be- 
come actualities  is  largely  a  matter  of  how  far  the  actual 
circumstances  offered  inducements  for  making  use  of  the 
possibilities.  Doubtless,  the  latter,  relatively  speaking,  were 
few  and  affected  only  a  small  proportion  of  the  entire 
sunnah.  It  may  therefore  be  said  that,  in  general,  the 
mutawatir  is  certainly  superior  to  the  mash-hur,  and  the 
latter  to  the  "  individual,"  and  that  for  the  most  part,  the 
collections  of  sunnah  considered  by  the  Moslems  as  canoni- 
cal are  genuine  records  of  the  rise  and  early  growth  of 
Islam.1 

1  C'f.  Juynboll,  pp.  16-19. 


CHAPTER  IV 
THE  THIRD  BASIS  OF  FIQH  :  THE  IJMA 

THE  first  two  bases  of  fiqh  which  we  have  already  ex- 
amined are  called  by  the  doctors  the  two  "  primary  "  evi- 
dences of  sharfah,  as  distinguished  from  the  next  two 
evidences  of  ijma'  and  qiyas,  considered  in  the  last  analysis 
as  solely  derived  from,  and  based  on,  the  two  former  pri- 
mary evidences  of  the  Koran  and  the  sunnah.  But  these 
two  latter  sources  are  often  involved  and  contradictory, 
especially  when  they  are  referred  to  for  the  solution  of 
novel  cases.  What  guarantee  is  there,  then,  that  the  law 
has  been  rightly  understood  ?  It  is  precisely  the  ijma'  that 
has  enabled  the  canonists  to  get  around  this  difficulty. 
Ultimately,  the  other  sources  receive  their  final  sanction 
from  the  ijma'.  It  alone  can  put  an  end  to  doubt.  When 
the  Mohammedan  community  has  reached  an  ijmaf,  that 
is,  a  unanimity  of  opinion  concerning  a  divine  prescription, 
its  opinion  is  infallible. 

The  doctors  have  found  justification  for  ijma'  as  a  source 
of  law,  both  in  the  Koran  and  the  sunnah.  The  Koran 
says :  "  It  is  thus  that  we  have  made  of  you  a  nation  of  the 
right  mean  " ; *  and  in  another  instance :  "  .  .  those  who  turn 
away  from  the  Prophet  and  who  do  not  follow  the  way 
of  the  believers."  :  What  else  can  the  way  of  the  believers 
be,  it  was  argued,  but  the  consensus  of  the  Mohammedan 
community  ?  On  the  other  hand,  the  Prophet  has  said : 

1  Chap.  2,  verse  137.  2<Chap.  4,  verse  115. 

60  [370 


371]  THE  THIRD  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  UMA  6 1 

"  My  people  (ummah)  shall  never  agree  on  an  error." 
Al-Shafi'i  justifies  ijma'  on  the  basis  of  a  hadlth  in  which 
the  Moslems  are  enjoined  to  go  with  the  community.  He 
explains  that  while  isolated  individuals  are  subject  to  error, 
the  Moslem  community  as  a  whole  is  immune.1 

Some  doctors  have  denied  the  legitimacy  of  ijma*  on  the 
two  following  grounds:  (i)  It  is  impossible  to  ascertain 
the  existence  of  ijma',  because  the  mujtahids,  living  at 
any  given  period,  cannot  in  fact  be  numbered,  for  among 
them  there  are  those  who  have  not  achieved  fame,  or  even 
possibly  women  who  have  reached  the  degree  of  ijtihad  and, 
being  women,  escape  observation.  Even  granting  that  they 
could  be  known  and  numbered,  it  is  impossible  to  ascertain 
the  consensus  of  their  opinions,  since  some  may  have  spoken 
contrary  to  their  inner  beliefs.  (2)  The  famous  hadlth 
concerning  Mu'adh  does  not  mention  the  ijma'  as  an  evi- 
dence, and  it  would  have  certainly  referred  to  it,  if  it 
were  such.2 

Only  later  was  this  dogma  of  the  infallibility  of  the 
Mohammedan  community  raised  by  the  canonists  into  an 
elaborate  piece  of  epistemological  theory,  after  it  had  ex- 
isted in  practice  for  a  very  long  time.  For  instance,  in 
the  Risalah  of  Al-Shafi'i  which  is  the  first  treatise  on 
usul-al-fiqh,  the  theory  of  ijma'  is  as  yet  far  from  being 
elaborate :  the  whole  chapter  hardly  occupies  a  page.8  The 
first  appearance  of  ijma'  is  probably  to  be  traced  in  the  city 
of  Medina,  among  the  Companions  of  the  Prophet.  After 
his  death,  they  were  the  ones  to  decide  all  points  of  diffi- 
culty, since  they  had  had  the  "  blessing  "  of  companionship 
and  conversation  with  the  Prophet  and,  so  to  speak,  had  got 

1  Risalah,  p.  65. 

*  From  the  Waraqdt,  quoted  in  Goldjiher,  D.  Zahiriten,  p.  33. 

3  Risdlah,  p.  65. 


62  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [372 

into  the  spirit  of  the  new  religion.  When,  therefore,  the 
Companions  could  agree  on  a  point,  their  consensus  would 
be  accepted  by  the  rest  of  the  community  as  conclusive. 
After  the  Companions,  this  leadership  in  religious  matters 
passed  to  the  next  generation,  the  so-called  Followers 
(tabi'un)  and  from  them  to  the  generation  of  jurists 
and  hadlth-teachers  who  followed  them.  When  these 
latter  differed  on  a  point,  they  naturally  referred  to  the  views 
and  practices  of  the  Companions  and  Followers ;  and  if  their 
views  and  practices  could  be  shown  to  have  been  un- 
animous, their  points  would  be  made  so  much  easier.  What 
is  more  natural,  therefore,  than  that  under  such  incentives 
there  should  develop  the  theory  of  ijma'  ? 

The  significance  of  ijma'  in  the  Mohammedan  law  can 
hardly  be  overestimated.  By  its  means,  not  only  is  con- 
troversy on  many  points  forever  done  away  with,  but 
also,  when  new  situations  have  been  met  by  analogy  or 
otherwise,  the  Moslems  may  be  assured  that  they  are  not 
getting  away  from  the  old  basis  and  drifting  into  heresy. 

Notwithstanding  the  unifying  influence  of  ijmaf,  there 
remained  indeed  always  a  certain  residuum  of  divergence 
of  opinion  on  some  minor  questions  on  which  no  consensus 
could  be  attained;  but  this  was  construed  by  the  canonists 
to  be  an  indication  of  God's  grace  to  His  people,  for  there 
is  an  ijmaf  on  this  very  point  too,  namely,  that  such  diverg- 
ence is  not  to  be  deprecated,  because  it  is  a  sign  of  God's 
grace.  This  ijma'  is  based  on  the  hadtth  in  which  the  Pro- 
phet said :  "  The  difference  of  opinion  in  my  community  is 
an  indication  of  grace  from  God's  part." 

Al-Sha'rani,  who  apparently  dislikes  the  idea  of  having 
in  the  shari'ah  any  divergence  of  opinion  (khilaf)  whatso- 
ever, has  taken  the  extreme  position  of  claiming  that,  in 
reality,  there  is  no  such  divergence  in  the  shari'ah',  and  he 
attempts  to  prove  his  contention  by  the  following  ingenious 


373]  THE  THIRD  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  IJMA  63 

argument :  The  whole  of  the  shari'ah  provisions  may  be  re- 
duced to  two  categories,  commandments  and  prohibitions, 
each  of  which  admits  of  a  double  construction, — one  for 
the  case  of  want  of  excuse  ('aslmah),  and  the  other  for  the 
case  of  excuse  (rukhsah).  The  apparent  contradiction  and 
divergence  of  provisions  and  views  in  the  shari'ah,  is  then 
only  a  consequence  of  the  fact  that  while  some  of  these 
provisions  and  views  refer  to  cases  of  want  of  excuse,  others 
refer  to  cases  of  excuse.  The  believer,  however,  should  not 
try  to  benefit  from  this  situation  by  following  the  less  rigor- 
ous prescriptions  which  are  only  meant  for  cases  of  excuse, 
when  he  possesses  no  real  excuse.1 

The  various  theories  and  views  of  the  doctors  concerning 
ijma'  may  be  briefly  summed  up  as  follows : 2 

Ijma'  is  defined  as  "  the  consensus  of  the  Mohammedan 
mujtahids  of  any  period  concerning  a  shari'ah  value." 
This  definition  excludes  both  the  non-Mohammedans  and 
the  non-mujtahids. 

The  formal  cause  (rukri)  of  ijma*.3  The  ijma'  is  re- 
puted to  have  taken  place  whenever  there  has  been  a  con- 
sensus. The  consensus  may  either  be  'azimah  or  simply 
rukhsah.  The  ijma'  is  said  to  be  'azimah  when  the 
mujtahids  have  spoken  with  one  another  concerning  the 
opinion  in  question  or  acted  according  to  it.  The  ijma' , 
on  the  contrary,  is  said  to  be  rukhsah,  when  some  have  dis- 
cussed or  acted  according  to  an  opinion,  and  the  rest  have 
kept  silent,  although  the  matter  has  been  communicated  to 
them  and  there  has  passed  enough  time  for  consideration. 
According  to  some  doctors  and  to  a  report  from  al-Shafi'i, 
the  consensus  is  not  deemed  to  take  place  when  some  of  the 

1  Mvzdn,  pp.  4,  8  et  seq. 

2  Tawfch,  pp.  425  et  seq. ;  Pazdawi,  pp.  946  et  seq. 

8  Formal  cause  here  is  used  in  the  Aristotelian  sense. 


64  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [374 

mujtahids  have  kept  silent.  The  others  reply  that  it  is  very 
difficult  for  all  the  mujtahids  to  express  opinions,  neither 
is  it  customary  to  do  so.  Moreover,  they  say,  silence  when 
speech  is  necessary  amounts  to  oral  assent. 

Who  is  eligible  for  ijma'?  The  opinion  must  be  con- 
sidered of  every  mujtahid  who  is  not  impious  and  hereti- 
cal. It  must  however  be  remarked  that  a  person  need  not 
be  a  mujtahid  if  the  matter  to  be  determined  by  ijma(  is 
one  that  does  not  require  judgment  (ra'y),  if,  for  ex- 
ample, the  matter  to  be  decided  is  the  transmission  of  the 
Koran  or  one  of  the  obligations  considered  fundamental 
in  all  religions,  such  as  the  five  prayers,  and  the  zakat.  For 
an  ijmaf  to  occur  on  these  matters,  it  is  necessary  that  both 
the  mujtahids  (khawass)  and  the  laymen  (fawamm)  should 
reach  agreement.  Consequently,  if  one  layman  should  dis- 
agree on  them  the  ijma  would  fail  to  occur,  "  but  this  has 
never  happened."  1  If  on  the  other  hand,  the  matter  to  be 
determined  is  one  that  requires  reflection  and  judgment, 
such  as,  for  example,  the  determination  of  the  specific  legal 
provisions  concerning  sales  and  marriage,  then  it  is  neces- 
sary that  only  the  mujtahids  should  agree.  The  ijmaf 
therefore  would  not  be  affected  if  some  of  the  laymen  should 
disagree;  as  a  matter  of  fact,  "  they  do  agree  when  all  the 
mujtahids  have  agreed  upon  a  point."  In  this  chapter  we 
are  concerned  only  with  the  ijmac  of  the  mujtahids. 

Some  have  claimed  that  only  the  Companions  qualify  for 
ijmaf.  Others  have  said  that  the  relatives  (fitrah)  of  the 
Prophet  alone  are  entitled  to  this  privilege.  On  the  other 
hand,  Malik  is  said  to  have  claimed  this  for  the  people  of 
Medina  exclusively.  But,  according  to  al-Pazdawi,  none  of 
these  supplementary  qualities  are  necessary,  and  all  the 
Mohammedans  are  equal  in  this  respect. 

1  Kashf,  p.  959 ;  Tawdih,  p.  433. 


THE  THIRD  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  IJMA  65 

The  Conditions  of  Ijma'.  The  Hanifites  hold  that  the 
"lapse  of  the  period"  (inqirdd  al-'asr),  i.  e.,  the  passing 
away  of  all  those  qualified  to  express  an  opinion  on  the 
matter  in  question  after  their  previous  agreement  upon  it,  is 
not  necessary,  but  Al-ShafVi  claimed  that  they  should  all 
pass  away  while  persisting  in  their  agreement.  The  Hani- 
fites reply  that,  once  the  ijmd'  is  reached,  any  later  addition 
or  change  is  not  valid. 

Some  have  claimed  that  the  ijma'  must  not  concern  a 
question  already  discussed  by  the  Companions ;  but,  accord- 
ing to  a  report  from  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  (a  disciple 
of  Abu  Hanifah),  the  ijma'  of  every  period  on  a  point  on 
which  the  former  generations  have  had  divergence  of 
opinion  is  valid,  provided  that  one  of  the  views  then  debated 
is  accepted  and  confirmed,  for  there  cannot  be  reached  an 
ijma'  on  a  new  opinion.  However,  concerning  matters  on 
which  there  has  been  no  previous  controversy,  an  ijma' 
may  be  arrived  at  on  any  opinion  whatsoever.1 

The  value  (hukm)  of  Ijma'.  The  value  of  ijma'  is  that 
a  legal  prescription  based  on  an  ijma'  is  considered  to  be 
positive  (yaqln),  and  therefore,  non-conformity  with  it 
entails  heresy.  After  the  attainment  of  an  ijma'  on  a 
point,  further  controversy  on  that  point  is  barred,  and  the 
point  becomes  acquired  forever,  unless  it  be  abrogated 
(na-skh)  in  accordance  with  the  following  rules. 

Abrogation  of  Ijma*.2  The  abrogation  of  an  ijma'  is 
possible  only  by  another  ijma'  of  a  similar  class.  Thus  an 
ijma  of  the  Companions  can  be  repealed  only  by  another 
ijma'  of  the  Companions;  and  likewise,  the  ijmd's  of  the 
second  generation  may  be  abrogated  by  other  ijmd's  of  the 
same  generation  or  of  following  generations,  because  the 
ijmd's  of  generations  later  than  that  of  the  Companions  are 
all  considered  of  the  same  weight. 

1  Pazdawi,  p.  967.  7  Pazdawi,  p.  982. 


66  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [376 

The  Basis  (sanad)  of  Ijma*.  According  to  the  majority 
of  the  doctors,  an  ijmaf  cannot  be  reached  except  upon 
evidence,  because  to  mention  only  one  reason,  in  religious 
matters,  opinion  without  evidence  is  erroneous  (khataf), 
11  since  evidence  is  what  gets  us  to  truth  and  without  evi- 
dence there  would  be  no  getting  to  it."  Some  said  that  the 
ijmaf  without  authority,  (i.  e.,  one  in  which  the  constituent 
opinions  have  not  been  based  upon  a  shari'ah  evidence)  may 
still  be  valid,  because  God  would  certainly  lead  His  com- 
munity to  the  right  view,  and  because,  if  it  were  necessary 
that  the  ijma'  should  require  authoritative  justification, 
there  would  be  no  longer  any  use  for  the  ijmaf  as  an  inde- 
pendent evidence.  The  other  side  replies  that  this  is  not  true, 
since  the  Prophet  himself  did  not  speak  except  through  in- 
spiration or  by  deduction  from  the  divine  revelations,  and 
that  therefore  it  behooves  the  community  that  it  should  pre- 
ferably speak  on  the  basis  of  evidence.  Furthermore,  they 
say,  it  is  necessary  that  there  should  be  evidence,  since 
opinion  based  on  prejudice  or  conjecture  is  proper  only  to 
heretics.  Finally,  they  deny  that  there  would  no  longer  be 
any  use  for  ijmaf  as  an  independent  evidence,  because,  as 
they  point  out,  upon  the  reaching  of  an  ijmaf  further 
controversy  on  the  point  is  not  allowed,  since  the  ijmaf 
establishes  the  point  in  a  way  that  does  not  admit  of 
doubt.  Consequently,  the  authority  or  evidence  for  the 
opinions  which  make  up  an  ijmaf  may  be  a  probable 
evidence  (dalll  zanni)  such  as  qiyas;  or  it  may  be  an  "  in- 
dividual "  report;  or  it  may  be  a  positive  evidence,  such  as  a 
verse  of  the  Koran  or  a  sunnah  of  the  mutawatir  type. 
The  Zahirites,  Shiites  and  certain  of  the  Mu'tazilites  have 
claimed  that  the  only  valid  basis  for  an  ijma'  is  positive 
evidence. 

The  Transmission  of  Ijma*.  This  is  subject  to  the  same 
rules  as  that  of  the  sunnah. 


CHAPTER  V 
THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH  :  THE  QIYAS 

SECTION   I 

General  Considerations. 

A  hot  controversy  had  to  be  waged  before  qiyas  or  legal 
analogy  was  generally  admitted  to  be  a  lawful  means  for 
establishing  shari'ah  values.  There  is  no  doubt  that  from 
the  time  of  Mohammed  analogy  was  resorted  to  in  order 
to  provide  for  the  solution  of  cases  which  were  left  un- 
settled by  the  two  revealed  sources  of  the  Koran  and  the 
sunnah.  That  such  was  the  case  is  amply  proved  by  the 
hadiths  invoked  by  the  upholders  of  qiyas,  as  will  be  seen 
below.  Besides,  this  is  also  what  reason  would  lead  one  to 
expect,  for  what  can  be  more  natural  than  to  judge  by 
analogy  rather  than  to  dismiss  a  case,  when  the  texts  fail  ? 

Of  course  in  the  earliest  period,  no  special  rules  as  yet 
had  developed  concerning  the  use  of  analogy  and  the  latter 
was  practised  in  a  loose  way,  varying  from  person  to  person 
according  to  temperament,  and  so  offering  more  or  less 
free  scope  for  the  play  of  personal  opinion.  However,  as 
this  new  principle  was  practised  in  an  informal  way,  no 
one  realized  its  significance.  But  presently  the  conditions 
changed.  Islam  in  the  meanwhile  quickly  spread  beyond 
the  limits  of  Arabia,  northward  into  Syria,  and  eastward 
into  Mesopotamia  and  'Iraq,  where,  owing  to  the  peculiar 
agricultural  and  social  conditions,  it  met  with  private-law 
377]  67 


68  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [378 

relations  essentially  different  from  those  of  Arabia.  How 
could  the  Mohammedan  judges  decide  matters  for  which 
the  Arabian  social  and  legal  traditions  offered  no  parallel 
whatever?  They  necessarily  had  to  use  their  personal 
opinion  in  the  form  of  qiyas,  though  always  trying  to  follow 
the  spirit  of  the  sacred  texts.1 

This  material  factor  in  the  growth  of  Islam  occasioned 
two  distinct  tendencies  in  Mohammedan  law.  The 
jurists  of  Medina  and  Mecca,  living  in  the  cities  in  which 
Islam  had  had  its  origin  and  early  development  and  which 
were  saturated  with  hadith-assotiztions,  laid  emphasis  on 
the  preservation  and  study  of  the  hadiths,  and  in  deciding 
legal  questions  they  referred  to  them  as  their  standard. 
This  they  could  easily  do,  because  the  cultural  and  legal 
conditions  under  which  those  hadiths  had  been  uttered  by 
the  Prophet  still  remained  practically  the  same  and  so  the 
hadiths  and  local  customs  would  be  sufficient  to  decide  the 
legal  questions  that  might  arise,  without  resorting  much 
to  the  use  of  analogy. 

But  it  cannot  be  said  that  this  was  true  of  the  jurists  of 
the  conquered  countries  outside  of  Arabia,  especially  of 
'Iraq.  In  'Iraq  the  conditions  were  different  and  the  jurists 
who  lived  there,  being  away  from  the  home  of  the  hadlth- 
lore  and  facing  new  situations,  from  the  very  first  used  and 
had  to  use  personal  opinion  (ra'y)  much  more  extensively. 
They  were  therefore  called  ra'y =f oik  (ahl-al-ra 'y) ,  in  dis- 
tinction from  the  jurists  of  Hijaz  who  were  known  as  the 
hadith-folk  (ahl-al-hadith) . 

This  difference  in  tendency  between  the  two  groups  of 
jurists  grew  to  be  more  and  more  marked  as  time  went  on 
and  eventually  culminated  in  the  famous  controversy  be= 
tween  the  hadith-folk  and  the  ra'y=folk.  Unfortunately 

1  Goldziher,  d.  Zahiriten,  p.  6. 


379]        THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  69 

the  historical  sources  do  not  throw  enough  light  on  the  dif- 
ferent phases  of  this  struggle  but  nevertheless  some  of  them 
may  be  determined. 

Thus  it  is  fairly  certain  that  until  Abu  Hanifah's  ap- 
pearance upon  the  scene,  the  opposition  between  the  two 
sides  was  mild ;  it  assumed  the  form  of  a  violent  controversy 
only  after  Abu  Hanifah's  epoch-making  innovation.  This  we 
may  infer  since  there  are  no  hadiths  to  the  contrary,  and 
since  all  the  existing  hadiths  refer  to  Abu  Hanifah  and  his 
disciples  as  the  persons  at  whose  door  the  blame  should  be 
laid  for  introducing  into  the  law  the  non-revealed  new  ele- 
ment of  personal  opinion  (ra'y).  This  innovation  of  Abu 
Hanifah,  which  launched  the  controversy,  consisted  in  his 
attempt  to  codify  the  Mohammedan  law,  for  the  first  time 
using  qiyas  avowedly  as  a  basis. 

So  long  as  the  use  of  qiyas  was  not  given  a  formal  re- 
cognition, but  was  resorted  to  occasionally  when  judgments 
were  rendered,  no  controversy  broke  out.  It  was,  however, 
a  very  different  matter  when  Abu  Hanifah  openly  declared 
qiyas  to  be  a  legitimate  basis  of  law,  and  proceeded  to 
codify  the  law  using  qiyas  as  one  of  his  bases.  This  was  an 
unmistakable  challenge  and  the  hadith-fo\k  accepted  it.  Ap- 
parently the  hadlth-iolk  were  willing  to  allow  the  use  of 
qiyas,  if  it  were  to  be  applied  in  an  informal  way  when  the 
situation  called  for  it,  but  disliked  to  have  qiyas  put  down 
on  paper  as  a  principle  of  legislation.  Thus  according  to 
the  Mizan?  Mujahid  is  said  to  have  told  his  disciples :  "  Do 
not  write  down  on  my  authority  the  opinions  I  give — only 
the  hadiths  are  written  down — for  I  may  revoke  tomorrow 
all  the  opinions  I  form  today." 

One  great  reason  why  there  was  such  bitter  opposition 
to  qiyas,  was  because  qiyas  was  identified  with  ra'y  (per- 

1  P.  47. 


70  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [380 

sonal  opinion).1  It  was  thought  that  the  use  of  qiyas 
would  result  in  the  setting  aside  of  the  revealed  texts  to 
make  room  for  ra'y.  But  in  the  eyes  of  the  conservative 
hadlth-folk  the  use  of  ra'y  was  almost  as  bad  as  unbelief. 
Thus,  al-Sha'bi  said :  "Ra'y  is  like  carrion;  you  use  it  as  food 
only  when  you  are  in  extreme  need  of  it "  and  in  another 
instance,  "  May  God  curse  '  a  ra'ayta '  ",  '  a  ra'ayta '  being 
the  formula  used  in  introducing  a  question  for  a  legal  opin- 
ion. Ja'far  al-Sadiq  said :  "  The  greatest  test  that  shall  be- 
fall the  Moslem  community  will  be  the  people  who  will  de- 
cide (yaqisuna)  matters  by  their  opinions  (ra'y)  and  will 
forbid  what  God  allowed  and  allow  what  God  forbade."  : 

The  two  features  peculiar  to  the  use  of  ra'y  which  the 
hadith-folk  disliked  most,  seem  to  have  been,  first,  the 
habit  of  the  ra'^y-folk  to  imagine  unreal  cases  in  order  to 
determine  their  legal  solutions;  and,  second,  their  scholastic 
subtleties.  This  may  be  seen  in  the  epigrammatic  ridicule 
heaped  on  Abu  Hanifah  by  the  poet  Musawir,8  and  in  the 
following  quotations.  Thus  Hafs  Ibn  Giyath  said  about 
Abu  Hanifah :  "He  is  the  most  informed  of  people  on  things 
that  have  not  existed  and  the  most  ignorant  of  people  on 
things  that  have  existed."  Likewise,  Malik,  when  asked 
whether  he  had  seen  Abu  Hanifah  answered : 4  "  Yes,  I 
saw  a  man  who,  if  he  told  you  that  he  could  make  this 
column  into  gold,  would  do  it  by  his  arguments."  In  the 
same  spirit  al-Shafi'i  said :  "  I  liken  the  ra'y  of  Abu  Hanifah 
to  nothing  but  the  rope  of  a  witch,  who  stretches  it  in  one 

1  Al-Shafi'i  considers  ijtihdd  and  giyds  as  identical  (Risdlah,  p.  66,  1.  3; 
cf.  also  Kashf,  p.  988). 

8  Mizdn,  p.  46. 

8  Agdni,  vol.  xvi,  p.  169. 

4  Abu  '1  Mahasin,  p.  404. 


381]        THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  ji 

direction,  and  you  see  it  yellow,  and  stretches  it  in  another 
direction,  and  you  see  it  red."  * 

The  hadith-folk,  on  the  contrary,  had  no  liking  for  ab- 
stract speculation,  but  would  only  concern  themselves  with 
concrete  cases.  One  of  them,  Masruq,  when  a  question 
was  put  to  him,  would  say,  "  Has  the  case  already  hap- 
pened ?  ",  and  if  answered  in  the  negative,  would  remark, 
"  Then  let  me  alone  with  the  answer  until  the  case  shall  have 
really  happened." 

In  order  to  discredit  the  methods  of  the  ra'y-folk,  the 
hadith-iolk  invoked  many  hadiths  supposedly  uttered  by 
the  Prophet  in  condemnation  of  the  use  of  ra'y.  Moreover, 
they  claimed  that  ra'y  was  synonymous  with  hawa,  meaning 
a  rash  opinion  formed  under  the  influence  of  passion  and 
prejudice.  However,  this  is  not  true,  because  in  common 
parlance,  the  word  meant  just  the  opposite.2 

In  identifying  qiyas  with  ra'y  in  this  controversy,  the 
hadith-folk  have  really  injured  their  cause,  since  the  re- 
cognition of  qiyas  as  established  by  Abu  Hani f ah  would 
only  curb  the  use  of  independent  opinion  (ra'y)  rather  than 
foster  it,  as  they  feared.  Formerly  there  were  no  strict 
rules  concerning  the  exercise  of  personal  opinion,  and  the 
personal  views  of  the  judge  might  easily  color  his  reasoning. 

1  Goldziher,  d.  Zahiriten,  p.  20. 

The  successive  changes  in  the  meaning  of  the  word  fiqh  (literally, 
judgment,  understanding),  originally  a  synonym  of  ra'y,  singularly  re- 
flect the  phases  of  the  conflict  in  question.  Thus  fiqh  was  first  used  in 
the  sense  of  interpreting  the  revealed  texts  (Goldziher,  d.  Zahiriten,  p. 
19)  ;  then  it  was  contrasted  with  hadith,  as  in  the  expression  "  conver- 
sant with  the  hadith  and  the  fiqh"  (ahl-al-badith  wa  'l-fiqh)  ;  al-Shdfi'i 
uses  'Urn  to  denote  the  knowledge  of  the  revealed  sources ;  finally, 
after  the  subsiding  of  the  controversy,  we  find  fiqh  used  to  mean  the 
science  of  law  in  general,  and  therefore,  in  order  to  distinguish  the 
science  of  hadith  in  particular,  the  expression  fiqh  al-hadith,  i.  e.,  the 
fiqh  of  hadith,  is  used. 


72  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [382 

After  the  introduction  of  qiyas  the  reasoning  of  the  judge 
was  limited  by  the  rules  of  qiyas  which  kept  it  more  with- 
in the  scope  of  the  revealed  sources.  The  best  proof  for 
this  is  probably  afforded  by  Abu  Hanifah's  own  action  when 
he  introduced  a  new  principle  to  supply  the  need  which 
resulted  from  the  limitation  of  personal  opinion  due  to  the 
introduction  of  qiyas.  This  new  principle,  which  consisted 
in  the  free  use  of  personal  opinion  in  the  place  of  qiyas 
when  public  necessity  would  call  for  such  a  procedure,  is 
called  istihsan. 

Taken  all  in  all,  this  controversy  was  largely  a  matter  of 
quibbling  over  words,  for,  as  a  matter  of  fact,  both  sides 
made  free  use  of  personal  opinion,1  although  one  must 
admit  that  the  hadlth-iolk  would  exhaust  the  possibilities 
of  their  system  before  committing  themselves  to  the  use  of 
qiyas.  Thus  it  is  related  of  Ahmad  Ibn  Hanbal,  that  he 
used  to  say :  "A  weak  hadith  is  better  for  us  than  the  ra'y 
of  people."  2  Hafs  Ibn  'Abdallah  al-Nlsaburi  (f  209,  H.) 
is  said  to  have  boasted  that  during  a  judgeship  of  20  years 
he  never  once  used  qiyas.  But  he  must  have  been  an  ex- 
ception. Abu  Hanifah,  on  the  contrary,  had  no  such  dread 
of  qiyas  and  would  use  it  rather  than  countenance  an 
hadith  of  suspicious  origin.  This  difference  of  attitude 
towards  the  use  of  qiyas,  accounts  for  the  small  number  of 
hadiths  said  to  have  been  used  by  Abu  Hanifah,  as  con- 
trasted with  the  28,000,  or  more,  alleged  to  have  been 
accepted  in  the  Musnad  of  Ahmad  Ibn  Hanbal. 

It  is  no  surprise  therefore  that  qiyas  has  been  admitted 
into  most  of  the  schools  that  were  recruited  from  the  ranks 
of  the  hadith-folk,  and  formed  the  by-products  of  the  con- 
troversy. The  person  who  took  the  first  step  in  this  di- 

1  Cf.  Goldziher,  d .  Zahiriten,  p.  36 ;  Mizdn,  p.  53,  1.  — 9. 
*  Mizdn,  p.  50. 


383]        THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  F1QH:  THE  QIYAS  73 

rection  and  who  is  chiefly  responsible  for  the  clearing-up 
of  the  situation  and  the  ending  of  the  controversy,  is  al- 
Shafi'i,  the  founder  of  the  Shafiite  school.  Notwithstand- 
ing that  he  was  reared  in  the  center  of  the  hadith-lore,  he 
came  out  squarely  for  the  lawfulness  of  qiyas,  though  he 
was  very  careful  to  state  in  his  Risdlah,  the  first  treatise 
on  usul-al-fiqh,1  that  qiyas  must  be  strictly  based  on  the  re- 
vealed sources,  and  the  ijmd,'.2  However  al-Shafi'i  strongly 
condemned  the  principle  of  istihsan.  Yet  he  could  not  dis- 
pense with  a  principle  which  should  act  as  a  safety  valve  in 
cases  of  emergency,  any  more  than  Abu  Hanifah  could. 
So  al-Shafi'i  was  forced  to  introduce  the  principle  of 
istishab,  and  to  allow  greater  latitude  in  the  determination 
of  the  "  effective  "  cause  ('illah)  for  purposes  of  qiyas. 

The  Malikite  school  fared  no  better  than  the  others,  for 
it,  too,  has  adopted  an  analogous  principle,  the  istislah. 

We  are  now  ready  to  examine  the  various  principles  and 
rules  concerning  the  use  of  qiyas,  which  have  been  elabor- 
ated 3  by  the  followers  of  Abu  Hanifah,  like  al-Pazdawi, 
and  al-Karkhi,  and  which  may  be  found  in  all  the  treatises 
on  usiil-at-fiqh.* 

The  definition  of  qiyas  is  "  to  extend  [ta'diyah]  the 
[shari'ah]  value  from  the  original  case  [asl]  over  to  the 

1  According  to  the  Tah-dhib  (p.  60),  the  Risdlah  was  written  by  re- 
quest and  approved  by  all. 

J  Risdlah,  pp.  65,  66,  69,  82. 

8  It  must  not  be  thought  that  the  detailed  principles  of  qiyas  as  we  find 
them  in  the  treatises  on  us.ul-al-fiqh  have  all  been  elaborated  by  Abu 
Hanifah.  Probably  he  did  not  do  more  than  lay  down  a  few  working 
principles,  and  the  rest  were  completed  by  his  successors.  This  is  borne 
out  by  the  fact  that  the  treatises  on  us.ul-al-fiqh,  only  very  seldom  (cf. 
Taw&h,  p.  469,  where  a  certain  view  is  ascribed  to  Abu  Hanifah),  in- 
dicate the  persons  responsible  for  the  opinions  cited,  or  else  ascribe 
them  to  later  doctors,  like  al-Pazdawi,  al-Karkhi,  and  al-Marlsi. 
(Kashf,  pp.  1014,  1020,  1021,  1023,  1035.) 

4  Tawdlh,  p.  444  et  seq. ;  Pazdawi,  p.  986  et  seq. 


74  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [384 

subsidiary  [far'},  by  reason  of  an  'effective'  cause 
\fillah]  which  is  common  to  both  cases  and  cannot  be 
understood  from  the  expression  [concerning  the  original 
case]  alone."  *  For  example,  if  a  certain  act  (asl)  has 
been  prohibited  in  the  Koran  or  the  sunnah,  other  acts 
(far')  common  with  that  act  in  regard  to  the  "  effective  " 
cause  ('illah)  for  which  the  prohibition  has  been  decreed, 
are  likewise  prohibited.  It  is  necessary,  however,  that  the 
acts  to  which  the  value  is  extended,  should  not  be  included 
in  the  meaning  of  the  prohibitory  expression,  explicitly  or 
implicitly,  for  in  that  case  they  would  be  prohibited  by 
virtue  of  the  prohibitory  expression  itself,  and  not  by  virtue 
of  qiyas  thereon. 

According  to  al-Pazdawi,2  the  justification  of  qiyas  is 
that  "  all  the  Companions  of  the  Prophet  and  all  the  Fol- 
lowers as  well  as  the  righteous  people  [salihun]  and  the 
theologians  have  unanimously  agreed  that  qiyas,  through 
use  of  personal  opinion  [ra'y]  on  the  basis  of  the  shari'ah 
principles  "  in  order  to  decide  undetermined  cases,  is  a  law- 
ful source  of  law.  The  Zahirites,  who  were  hadith-iolk,  and 
others,  held  that  qiyas  is  not  a  legal  evidence  (hujjah)  and 
that  action  upon  it  is  null  and  void.  Some  of  them  based 
their  dissent  on  the  ground  that  qiyas, being  a  case  of  exercis- 
ing reason,  may  not  constitute  evidence.  Others  contended 
that  while  reason  may  constitute  evidence  in  intellectual 
matters  it  may  not  do  so  in  shari'ah  matters.  Still  others 
maintained  that  resort  to  reason  should  be  only  in  cases 
of  emergency  and  that  no  such  emergency  could  be  said 
to  exist  in  the  case  of  qiyas  t  since  qiyas  could  be  substituted 
for  by  istishdb-al-hal. 

According  to  the  Kashf  3  the  whole  dispute  about  qiyas 

1  Tawfch,  p.  444. 

1  P.  990.  s  P.  990. 


385]        THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  75 

turned  on  the  following  two  points:  (i)  whether  qiyas 
was  lawful  in  intellectual  matters;  and  (2)  whether  it  was 
lawful  in  shari'ah  matters.  The  Kashf  goes  on  to  say  that 
all  the  Companions  and  the  Followers  as  well  as  the  ma- 
jority of  the  jurists  and  theologians  considered  qiyas  law- 
ful in  both  cases ;  that,  among  others,  all  the  Shiites  and  the 
Kharijites  allowed  the  use  of  qiyas  only  in  shari'ah  matters; 
and  that  the  Hanbalites  sanctioned  its  use  only  as  regards 
the  applications  of  fiqh,  in  view  of  the  need  for  it  in  cases 
concerning  which  the  Koran  was  silent,  but  denied  its  law- 
fulness as  regards  the  determination  of  intellectual  matters. 
The  opponents  of  qiyas  argued  in  detail  as  follows : x 

(1)  From  the  Koran: 2  "  We  have  sent  down  to  you  the 
Book,  as  an  explanation  for  every  thing."     To  consider 
qiyas  as  an  additional  evidence  would  be  to  consider  the 
Koran  insufficient. 

(2)  From  the  sunnah:  the  Prophet  said:  "  The  affairs  of 
the  sons  of  Israel  have  continued  to  prosper  until  there  multi- 
plied among  them  the  children  of  the  war  captives,  for  these 
have  measured  (qasii)  what  did  not  exist  on  the  basis  of 
what  did  exist,  and  so  they  have  erred  and  led  others  into 
error." 

(3)  From  reason:  there  is  doubt  about  the  "effective" 
cause  ('illah)   for  which  a  sharl'dk  value  has  been  estab- 
lished, because  the  revealed  texts  do  not  mention  the  causes, 
and  consequently  one  cannot  know  what  to  use  as  a  basis 
for  qiyas.     Furthermore,  God  is  not  worshipped  according 
to  the  dictates  of  reason.     Are  there  not  in  fact,  divine 
prescriptions  which  cannot  be  grasped  by  human  under- 
standing, as  for  instance,  the  "  stated  quantities  "  (muqad- 

1  Cf.  Tawfch,  p.  446. 

2  Chap.  16,  verse  91. 


76  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [386 

darat)  such  as  the  number  of  prostrations  in  prayer;  and 
are  there  not  prescriptions  which  even  contradict  reason  ? 
To  these  the  defenders  of  qiyas  answered  as  follows  : 

(1)  From  the  Koran:1  "  Consider,  oh  ye  possessors  of 
eyes,"  and  consideration  here  means  the  comparison  of 
things  similar. 

(2)  From  the  sunnah: 2  "  The  had'iths  proving  the  legi- 
timacy of  qiyas  are  innumerable."     Thus  when  Mohammed 
sent  Mu'adh  to  Yaman,  he  asked  him  what  principles  he 
would  use  in  administering  justice.     Mu'adh  answered  that 
he  would  decide  upon  his  personal  opinion  (ra'y)  in  case 
no  provisions  were  to  be  found,  either  in  the  Koran  or  the 
sunnah.     Upon  this  the  Prophet  said :  "  Thanks  to  God 
that  He  has  directed  the  delegate  of  His  Prophet  to  that 
opinion   in  which  the   Prophet   of   God   finds   pleasure." 
Again,  when  the  Prophet  sent  Abu  Musa  to  Yaman,  he  said : 
"  Judge  upon  the  Book  of  God,  and  if  you  do  not  find  in  it 
what  you  need,  upon  the  sunnah  of  the  Prophet,  and  if 
you  do  not  find  in  that,  then  use  your  own  opinion."    More- 
over, the  conduct  of  the  Companions,  and  their  conversa- 
tions and  discussions  bear  this  out  still  more  forcibly.     In 
fact,  it  is  established  by  mutawatirs  3  that  they  used  qiyas, 
especially  in  their  councils  on  the  matter  of  succession, 
where 

each  spoke  using  his  own  opinion  until  the  matter  was 
finally  settled  according  to  what  'Omar  said  in  the  way  of 
opinion  and  qiyas,  when  he  remarked,  "Are  you  not  going 
to  be  satisfied  as  regards  worldly  matters,  with  the  man  with 
whom  the  Prophet  was  satisfied  as  regards  matters  of  re- 
ligion ?  ",  and  they  agreed  upon  his  opinion  notwithstanding 
the  fact  that  the  question  of  succession 

1  Chap.  59,  verse  2. 

2  Pazdawi,  p.  998. 
8  Kashf,  p.  1000. 


THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  77 

to  the  call  fate  is  of  the  utmost  importance.  Again,  when 
the  Companions  held  a  council,  for  determining  the  penalty 
of  the  wine-drinker  (sharib),  'Ali  said:  "  When  one  drinks 
he  gets  drunk,  and  when  he  gets  drunk,  he  raves,  and  when 
he  raves,  he  accuses  falsely,"  hence  the  same  penalty  must 
apply  to  the  drinker  as  to  the  false  accuser. 

(3)  From  reason: l  the  allegation  that  it  is  not  allowed  to 
establish  values  on  the  basis  of  probable  evidence  is  not 
valid,  for  in  matters  which  human  understanding  cannot 
grasp,  probability  is  sufficient  for  purposes  of  conduct. 
"  Besides,"  they  said,  "  do  you  not  yourselves  use  qiyds 
to  determine  the  direction  (qiblah)  of  the  Ka'bah,  or  to  fix 
the  amount  of  damage  to  be  paid  for  destroyed  property?" 
The  other  side  replied  that  these  cases  were  exceptional, 
because  the  original  obligation,  (for  example,  the  thing 
destroyed),  could  no  longer  be  discharged  per  se,  and  be- 
cause these  cases  related  to  individuals'  rights  (huquq  fibad). 
Moreover,  there  was  a  possibility  of  determining  them  by 
means  of  the  senses  and  reason,  for  instance,  through  a 
journey,  or  the  positions  of  the  stars.2 

SECTION   II 

Is  it  Lawful  to  Investigate  the  "  Effective  "  Causes  of 
Divine  Prescriptions  f  a 

We  have  seen  that  qiyas  is  the  extension  of  a  sharfah 
value  from  the  original  case  (asl)  (concerning  which  a 
prescription  has  been  revealed)  to  a  new  case,  because  the 
latter  has  the  same  cause  as  the  former.  In  other  words, 
no  use  of  qiyas  can  be  made  before  the  specific  cause  of  a 
prescription  has  been  actually  determined.  Take,  for  in- 

1  Taw&h,  p.  450. 
8  Taw&h,  p.  447. 
3  Pazdawi,  p.  1013  et  seq.;  Tawfcb,  p.  464- 


7S  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [388 

stance,  the  prohibition  of  usury  concerning  the  six  articles, 
namely,  gold,  silver,  corn,  barley,  dates,  and  raisins.  Now, 
if  it  can  be  found  that  the  specific  cause  (fillah)  of  the 
prohibition  is  a  certain  feature  of  these  articles,  say,  their 
being  measured  by  weight,  then  all  other  articles  measured 
by  weight  would  also  be  covered  by  the  prohibition.  Such 
an  inquiry  into  the  "  effective  "  causes  of  the  divine  pre- 
scriptions is  called  by  the  doctors  ta'lil  al-usul.  There  have 
been  different  views  concerning  the  legitimacy  of  such  a 
procedure. 

One  view  is  that  the  divine  prescriptions  do  not  possess 
an  "  effective  "  cause  except  when  there  is  evidence  to  that 
effect.  The  people  who  hold  this  view  argue  that  the  de- 
termination of  the  cause  of  a  divine  prescription  is  like 
the  use  of  the  metaphorical  meaning  of  a  word,  instead  of 
its  proper  meaning,  but  that  is  allowed  only  upon  evidence. 
Besides,  if  each  attribute  (wasf)  were  taken  as  a  separate 
cause,  what  one  attribute  included  another  would  exclude, 
and  if  all  the  attributes  together  were  taken  as  one  cause, 
they  would  be  combined  only  in  the  original  case  (mansus- 
falayh),  thus  barring  the  use  of  qiyas.  On  the  contrary,  if 
one  of  the  attributes  is  set  down  as  the  causal  one,  it  in- 
volves doubt,  since  some  other  one  may  have  been  the  cause. 
For  instance,  if  every  one  of  the  qualities  possessed  by  the 
six  articles  above  mentioned  is  considered  as  a  separate 
cause  of  the  prohibition,  then  one  of  these  qualities,  for 
example,  being  a  foodstuff,  would  bring  under  the  pro- 
hibition apples,  also  a  foodstuff,  but  would  exclude  plaster, 
whereas  the  attributes  of  being  measured  by  volume  or 
weight  (qadr)  1  and  being  a  genus  (jins)  would  give  a 
different  result.  Again,  if  all  the  qualities  taken  together 
are  considered  to  be  the  one  single  cause  of  the  prohibition, 

1  Tech.  Diet.,  p.  1179. 


389]        THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  79 

then  only  the  six  articles  mentioned  would  be  the  prohibited 
ones,  and  the  door  of  qiyas  would  be  closed,  since  no  other 
articles  would  combine  all  those  qualities.  Finally,  if  only 
one  of  the  attributes  were  taken  as  the  cause,  there  is  no 
guarantee  that  some  other  attribute  is  not  the  cause.  Con- 
sequently, unless  there  is  special  evidence  to  indicate  which 
attribute  is  the  causal  one,  the  best  thing  to  do  is  to  refrain 
(waqf)  from  attempting  to  determine  the  cause. 

A  second  view  is  that  every  attribute  which  can  possibly 
be  regarded  as  a  cause,  and  to  which  a  value  may  properly 
be  attached,  is  considered  a  cause  except  when  an  express 
statement  (nass)  or  ijma'  points  to  the  contrary.  The 
people  who  hold  this  view  insist  that  every  attribute  may  be 
an  actual  cause,  excepting  when  there  is  an  obstacle;  for 
example,  when  the  various  attributes  contradict  one  an- 
other, or  when  there  is  an  express  statement  or  ijma'  to 
the  contrary.  Their  argument  is  that  qiyas  is  one  of  the 
evidences  of  the  sharl'ah,  that  its  evidential  function  would 
have  been  defeated  if  each  attribute  had  not  been  considered 
as  a  separate  cause,  and  that  there  is  no  reason  for  not  so 
considering  it,  unless  there  is  a  real  obstacle.  Thus,  they 
grant  that  all  the  attributes  together  cannot  be  considered  as 
a  single  combined  cause  but,  they  say,  it  is  quite  possible  to 
consider  each  attribute  as  a  separate  cause,  and  it  is  not  true, 
as  has  been  claimed,  that  this  involves  contradiction,  since 
they  would  allow  it  only  in  so  far  as  there  is  no  contradic- 
tion involved. 

A  third  view  is  that  the  divine  prescriptions  do  have 
causes,  but  that  the  right  thing  to  do  is  to  determine  only 
one  attribute  as  the  "  effective  "  cause  of  a  prescription,  pro- 
vided that  the  attribute  singled  out  as  the  causal  one  is  so 
designated  by  a  specific  evidence.  The  people  who  hold 
this  view  argue  that  since  all  the  attributes  together  may 
not  be  a  single  cause,  (as  this  would  make  qiyas  impossible) , 


go  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [390 

it  becomes  clear  that  one  of  the  attributes  must  be  the  causal 
one,  unless  there  is  evidence  that  more  than  one  attribute 
are  causes;  but  as  it  is  not  known  which  of  the  attributes 
is  the  causal  one,  there  is  need  for  a  specific  evidence  to 
designate  one  as  the  distinctly  causal  attribute.  Apparently 
this  is  the  view  of  al-Shafi'i.  However,  his  disciples  held 
that  the  proper  conduct  concerning  the  divine  prescriptions 
was  to  accept  (ta'abbud)  them  with  devotion,  and  not  to 
attempt  to  determine  causes. 

A  fourth  view,  the  generally  accepted  Hanifite  view,1 
is  that  the  prescriptions  are  presumed  to  have  a  single  cause 
which  must  be  determined,  unless  there  is  an  obstacle  to  its 
determination,  as  for  example,  in  the  case  of  prescriptions 
concerning  "  stated  quantities  "  (muqaddarat)  with  respect 
to  ritual  and  punishments.  However,  one  may  not  proceed 
to  determine  the  cause  of  a  prescription,  unless  there  is 
previous  evidence  to  show  that  the  prescription  actually  has 
a  cause ;  and  even  then  a  further  evidence  is  needed,  in  order 
to  determine  which  of  the  several  attributes  is  the  cause  of 
the  prescription.  The  argument  for  this  view  is  that  all 
divine  prescriptions  do  not  have  a  cause,  and  that  a  specific 
evidence  is  needed  to  show  that  the  prescription  in  question 
actually  has  a  cause.  Some  Hanifites  held  that  there  is 
no  need  for  such  specific  evidence  when  there  is  already 
evidence  to  show  which  of  the  attributes  of  the  thing  pro- 
hibited is  the  causal  one,  since  evidently  a  prescription  can- 
not have  a  causal  attribute  and  yet  not  have  a  cause. 

SECTION  III 

How  to  Determine  the  "  Effective  "  Cause 

We  have  seen  that  most  of  the  doctors  have  agreed  that 
not  all  the  attributes  of  the  thing  forbidden  or  recommended 

1  Tawdlh,  p.  465 ;  Kashf,  p.  1014. 


39I]        THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  gl 

may  be  considered  as  causal,  whether  taken  together  or  singly, 
but  that  only  one  or  more  of  them  are  the  causes.  These 
particular  attributes  must  be  determined  by  some  evidence, 
because  all  the  doctors  agree  that  one  may  not  at  random 
hit  upon  some  of  the  attributes  as  the  causal  ones.1 

According  to  the  majority  of  the  doctors,  in  order  to  be 
the  cause  for  a  prohibition  or  permission,  an  attribute, 
must  be  "convenient"  (munasib),  that  is,  it  must  be 
such  that,  when  joined  with  the  value,  it  would  re- 
sult in  the  accruing  of  a  benefit  or  the  removal  of  a  dam- 
age, the  benefit  and  the  damage  viewed  from  the  stand- 
point of  the  shari'ah.  Fasting,  for  example,  is  useful 
to  mankind  from  the  standpoint  of  the  shari'ah,  in  subduing 
the  animal  nature,  though  harmful  from  the  medical  view- 
point.2 According  to  the  Kashf  *  the  attribute  is  "  con- 
venient," if  it  is  like  the  attributes  considered  "  convenient  " 
by  the  early  Moslems,  "  who  used  to  consider  as  causes 
those  attributes  which  were  proper  to  the  values."  Again, 
according  to  the  Kashf,  Al-Gazali  held  that  an  attribute  is 
"  convenient,"  if  the  connection  of  the  value  to  it  would 
lead  to  a  useful  purpose  (maslahah)  ;  for  example,  in  the 
case  of  the  prohibition  of  wine-drinking,  the  "  convenient " 
attribute  is  the  property  of  wine  to  destroy  reason.  Accord- 
ing to  others,  that  attribute  is  "  convenient "  which  appeals 
to  reason  as  the  proper  one.4 

Besides  being  "  convenient,"  the  attribute  must  also 
be  "  effective  "  (mu'ath-thir)  if  its  use  for  qiyas  is  to  be 
obligatory  (wajib),  but  it  is  valid  (sahlh)  to  apply  a  qiyas 
on  the  basis  of  an  attribute  which  is  only  "  convenient," 
without  being  "effective."5  According  to  some  of  the 

1  Kashf,  p.  1070.  '  Talwih,  p.  473. 

1  P.  1072.  4  Shawkani,  p.  200. 

4  Talivib,  p.  475 ;  Kashf,  p.  1073. 


82  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [392 

Shafiites,1  the  attribute  need  not  be  "  effective,"  but  it  is 
sufficient  if  it  occurs  to  one's  mind  that  it  is  the  one 
needed.  However,  in  this  case,  as  a  matter  of  precaution 
one  should  also  refer  to  the  sources  (usul),  in  order  to  make 
sure  that  no  contradiction  to  them  has  been  incurred.  On 
the  other  hand,  some  Shafiites  said  that  this  reference  to 
the  sources  is  to  be  made  first,  and  if  the  attribute  used  as 
causal  is  found  to  contradict  no  principle  of  the  sources,  it 
is  considered  as  the  cause. 

The  Hatiifites,  by  saying  that  the  attribute  must  be 
"effective,"  mean  that  in  the  Koran,  the  sunnah  or  the 
ijmac  this  very  attribute  or  another  of  the  same  genus 
(jins),  should  have  been  indicated  as  an  "  effective  "  cause 
for  the  very  value  (hukm)  in  question  or  another  value  of 
the  same  genus.2  By  genus,  here  is  meant  the  proximate 
genus  (jins  qarib). 

The  doctors  have  distinguished  four  types  of  "  effective- 
ness "  (ta'thlr):* 

(i)  The  very  same  attribute  has  been  indicated  in  the 
sources  as  "  effective "  cause  for  the  very  same  value. 
This  almost  amounts  to  an  application  of  the  original  pre- 
scription, since  the  only  difference  between  the  two  cases 
is  that  the  attribute  in  one  case  qualifies  one  object,  and  in. 
the  other  case  another  object.  It  is  no  wonder,  therefore, 
that  this  kind  of  qiyas  is  often  accepted  by  its  very  oppo- 
nents. An  example  of  this  qiyas  is  the  following :  if  it  has 
been  established  that  the  cause  of  the  prohibition  of  usury 
as  regards  dates  is  their  being  measured  by  volume  (kayl), 
then  without  any  doubt  plaster  would  be  like  dates ;  and  if, 
on  the  other  hand,  the  cause  is  their  being  a  foodstuff,  then 


1  Pazdawi,  p.  1074. 
*  Shawkani,  p.  203. 
8  Taw&h,  p.  478 ;  Kashf,  p.  1073. 


393]        THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  83 

raisins  would  be  like  dates.  Here,  in  both  cases  we  have 
the  very  same  attribute  and  the  very  same  value,  namely, 
being  measured  by  volume,  or  being  a  foodstuff,  on  the 
one  hand,  and  prohibition  for  reason  of  usury,  on  the  other 
hand. 

(2)  The   very   same   attribute   has   been   indicated   as 
"  effective  "  cause  of  the  genus  of  the  value;  for  example, 
in  inheritance  the  attribute  of  being  a  full  instead  of  a 
half  brother  is  a  cause  of  the  value  of  precedence.     By 
analogy,  the  very  same  attribute  is  made  cause,  this  time 
not  of  the  very  same  value,  i.  e.,  precedence  in  matter  of 
inheritance,  but  of  another  value  of  the  same  genus,  namely, 
precedence  in  guardianship  (wildyah)  in  marriage,  preced- 
ence in  both  inheritance  and  marriage  being  a  genus  of  right. 

(3)  The  genus  of  the  attribute  has  been  indicated  as  a 
cause  of  the  very  same  (fayn)  value;  for  example,  when 
a  person  has  to  settle  (qada')  many  debts  of  prayers  (salat) 
which  he  has  failed  to  perform  in  their  right  times,  by 
analogy,  he  is  released  from  these  debts  if  he  has  fainting 
fits.     The  analogy  is  based  on  the  fact  that  both  insanity 
and   menstruation    (hayd)    have   been   considered    in   the 
sources  as  "  effective "  causes  for  the  very  same  value, 
namely  the  cancelling  of  the  obligation  of  prayer.     In  other 
words,  the  doctors  have  considered  as  cause  of  the  value, 
not  one  of  the  two  mentioned  excuses  or  attributes,  already 
indicated  in  the  sources  as  causes,  but  another  attribute  of 
the  genus  of  those  two  attributes,  namely,  fainting.     This 
sort  of  attribute  is  usually  called  mula'im. 

(4)  The  attribute  whose  genus  has  been  indicated  as 
the   cause   of   the   genus   of   the   value.     This   is   usually 
called  al-munasib  al-garib.     An  example  of  this  is  the  can- 
celling by  analogy  of  the  obligation  of  performing  the 

P.  478. 


84  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [394 

prayers  for  cause  of  menstruation  (hayd),  because  an  at- 
tribute of  the  same  genus,  namely  being  on  a  journey,  has 
been  indicated  already  as  cause  for  a  value  of  the  same 
genus,  namely  the  cancelling  of  the  superfluous  two  prostra- 
tions in  prayer.  Here,  from  the  standpoint  of  perform- 
ing the  prayer,  having  menstruation  or  being  on  a  journey 
are  a  genus  of  "inconvenience"  (mashaqqah) ,  while  the 
cancelling  of  the  prayers  and  the  cancelling  of  the  super- 
fluous prostrations  are  a  genus  of  alleviation  of  the  law. 

The  reason  why  the  Hanifites  require  that  the  attribute 
besides  being  "  convenient "  must  also  be  "  effective,"  is 
because,  "  the  attribute  while  being  '  convenient '  may  at 
the  same  time  not  have  been  in  and  of  itself,  (bi-dhatihi) 
the  cause  ('Utah)  of  the  value,  but  simply  considered  as 
cause  by  the  sharl'ah."  To  the  contention  of  the  opposite 
side  that  one  cannot  understand  and  feel  that  a  certain  at- 
tribute is  the  effective  cause  of  a  prescription,  al-Pazdawi 
retorts  that  one  observes  causation  in  the  physical  world, 
both  in  language  and  perception,  as  for  example,  when  one 
says,  "  He  broke  it  and  it  was  broken,"  or  "  He  beat  him 
and  he  was  hurt,"  or  when  one  sees  the  result  (athar)  of 
the  act  of  the  builder  in  the  building,2  and  so  by  inference 
one  can  observe  causation  in  the  shari'ah  also.  Take,  for 
example,  the  prophetic  hadlth  to  the  effect  that  she-cats 
(hirrah)  are  not  impure  because  they  are  "  from  those 
who  are  around "  people  all  the  time.  Clearly,  in  this 
hadlth,  the  attribute  of  being  around  all  the  time  is  con- 
sidered to  be  the  cause  of  the  cleanness  (taharah)  of  she- 
cats.  In  other  words,  the  law  regarding  the  residue  of 
water  or  food  touched  by  she-cats  is  alleviated,  because  of 
the  great  difficulty  of  guarding  against  their  touching  the 

1  Pazdawi,  p.  1078. 
*  Kashf,  p.  1079. 


395]        THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  85 

food,  since  they  are  around  all  the  time.  There  is,  there- 
fore, necessity  (darurah)  to  consider  the  food  touched  by 
she-cats  as  clean,  just  as  there  is  necessity  to  eat  a  dead 
cqrpse  when  on  the  point  of  starvation. 

Of  the  above-mentioned  four  types  of  qiyas,  the  first 
three  are  admitted  by  all  the  upholders  of  qiyas  to  be  law- 
ful, but  there  is  dispute  as  to  the  fourth.  However,  it  also, 
is  lawful  in  the  generally  accepted  view  (mukhtar)  because 
it  expresses  more  than  mere  probability  (zann).v  The  first 
three  types  are  called  mula'im  and  the  fourth  garlb. 

The  Hanifites  who  hold  that  in  order  for  a  qiyas  to  be 
wajib,  the  attribute  must  be  "  effective,"  reject  as  unlaw- 
ful the  kind  of  causes  designated  as  tardi  ('Hal  tardiyyah), 
which  are  used  by  others  and  are  not  "  effective."  2  The 
people  who  use  this  last  type  of  causes,  namely  the  so-called 
ashab-al-tard,  retort  and  say,  that  it  is  not  necessary  that 
the  "  effectiveness  "  of  an  attribute  (ta'thlr  al-wasf)  should 
have  been  indicated  in  the  sources,  but  that  the  mere  con- 
comitance (ittirad)  of  the  value  and  the  attribute  is  an  evi- 
dence on  the  part  of  the  sources  (shahadat  al-asl)  that  the 
attribute  is  the  cause  of  the  value;  and  further,  that  it  is 
not  true  that  the  early  doctors  (salaf)  have  always  applied 
the  qiyas  on  the  basis  of  "  effective  "  causes.  The  argu- 
ment of  these  people  is  that  qiyas  is  valid  on  the  basis  of 
every  attribute,  and  that  each  one  of  the  several  attributes 
is  assumed  to  have  been  expressly  stated  (nass)  ;  for  ex- 
ample, if  wine  has  been  forbidden,  it  is  as  if  every  one  of 
the  attributes  of  wine  has  been  expressly  forbidden;  that 
the  so-called  shari'ah  causes  (rilal)  in  reality  are  not  causes 
of  the  values  which  attach  to  them,  but  simply  signs 
(imarah)  of  them,  the  real  cause  of  all  values  being  God 


1  Kashf,  p.  1074 ;  Talwib,  pp.  477-8. 

2  Kashf,  p.  1085 ;  Talwih,  p.  485. 


86  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [396 

the  Almighty ;  that  therefore  one  need  not  look  for  evidence 
that  they  are  the  "  effective  "  causes.1 

We  need  not  examine  here  the  various  other  methods 
used  by  small  and  less  known  groups.  Let  it  suffice  to 
describe  only  two  of  them,  (i)  The  method  of  tard  or 
dawran,  which  consists  in  considering  an  attribute  as  cause 
of  the  value,  simply  if  every  time  the  attribute  was  present 
or  absent,  the  value  also  was  present  or  absent,  irrespective 
of  whether  there  is  an  indication  in  the  context  to  show 
that  the  attribute  was  meant  to  be  the  cause  of  the  value. 
(2)  The  method  of  masalih  mursalah  or  istislah  used  by 
the  Malikites.  This  consists  in  considering  an  attribute  as 
causal,  although  there  may  be  no  evidence  to  show  that  it 
was  either  approved  or  disapproved  by  the  shari'ah.2 

SECTION   IV 

The  Conditions  of  Qiyas  3 

There  are  four  conditions  of  qiyas : 

(1)  That  the  value  (such  as  prohibition)  which  is  about 
to  be  extended  to  a  new  case,  should  not  be  expressly  limited 
to  the  original  case.     Thus  while  the  testimony  of  Khu- 
zaymah,  by  himself,  is  legal  evidence,  it  may  not  be  argued 
by  way  of  qiyas  that  the  testimony  of  another  single  individ- 
ual would  likewise  be  accepted  as  legal  evidence. 

(2)  That  the  value  of  the  original  case  should  not  have 
been  itself  against  the  rules  of  analogy.     Such  is  supposed 
to  be  the  case,  either  when  the  mind  cannot  understand 
the  value  in  question,  such  as  for  example,  the  number  of 
prostrations  in  prayer;  or  when  it  is  against  the  laws  of 

1  Pazdawi,  p.  1086. 

1  Cf.  supra,  Other  Principles  of  Legislation ;  for  more  details  see  Tech. 
Diet.,  pp.  1366-1372. 
8  Pazdawi,  pp.  1021  et  seq.;  Taw&h,  p.  451. 


397]        THE  FOURTH  BASIS  OF  FIQH:  THE  QIYAS  87 

qiyas,  as  when  fasting  is  not  invalidated  by  eating  through 
inadvertence,  although  qiyas  would  require  that  the  fast 
should  be  considered  broken  by  every  thing  that  enters  the 
body.  It  may  not  be  therefore  argued  that  because  eating 
through  inadvertence  does  not  break  the  fast,  by  analogy, 
eating  by  mistake  or  accident,  also  should  not  break  the  fast. 
(3)  That  the  value  whose  extension  to  a  new  case  is 
sought,  should  be  a  shari'ah  value  established  by  virtue  of 
the  Koran,  the  sunnah,  or  the  ijma*,  but  not  another  qiyas: 
that  the  value  in  the  process  of  transition  to  the  new  case 
should  undergo  no  change;  that  the  new  case  be  similar 
to  the  original  case  in  the  quality  to  which  the  value  at- 
taches; and  finally,  that  concerning  the  new  case  (far') 
there  should  have  been  no  separate  prescription  (nass). 
Ibn  Shurayh,  the  Shafiite,  and  others  have  held  that 
qiyas  is  allowed  also  in  case  of  names.  For  instance, 
they  have  argued  that  because  grape  juice  is  called  wine 
whenever  it  has  reached  the  stage  of  fermentation,  the  name 
wine  may  be  applied  to  any  drink  which  is  in  a  similar  stage, 
for  example,  to  the  drink  nabidh.  The  majority  of  the 
doctors  however,  have  objected  to  the  application  of  qiyas 
in  matters  of  terminology,  because  there  is  no  connection  be- 
tween the  name  of  a  thing  and  the  thing  itself,  and  so  noth- 
ing can  be  pointed  out  as  the  cause  of  a  name.  But  qiyas 
is  allowed  only  in  cases  where  one  can  determine  a  cause. 
An  example  of  the  second  requirement  is  the  following. 
Because  eating  through  inadvertence  during  the  fast  does  not 
legally  break  the  fast,  the  Shafiites  have  argued  by  analogy 
that  eating  by  mistake  (khata')  or  by  threat,  also  must  not 
break  the  fast.  The  Hanifites  replied  that  inadvertence 
(nisa')  is  a  natural  shortcoming  against  which  a  person  can- 
not guard,  but  mistake  and  threat  may  be  avoided  by  excess 
of  care  or  by  appeal  to  the  government.  Therefore,  applying 
the  value  (in  this  case,  nullity  ascribed  to  the  act  of  eating 


88  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [398 

through  inadvertence)  to  the  other  two  acts  would  be  chang- 
ing it,  for  it  would  have  been  attached  to  avoidable  acts, 
while  it  is  intended  to  apply  only  to  unavoidable  acts  like 
those  due  to  inadvertence.  This  case  is  also  an  illustration 
of  the  third  requirement,  namely  that  the  qualities  to  which 
the  value  attaches  (inadvertence,  on  the  one  hand,  mistake 
and  threat,  on  the  other)  should  be  similar,  but  evidently 
they  are  not  in  this  case,  because  the  former  is  unavoid- 
able and  the  latter  two  are  not  so. 

(4)  That  the  application  of  qiyas,  should  not  result  in 
the  altering  of  a  prescription  (nass),  because  this  would 
be  altering  the  divine  prescription  on  the  basis  of  personal 
judgment.  An  example  of  this  is  found  in  the  case  of 
false  accusation,  which  by  express  prescription  is  a  perma 
nent  bar  to  the  acceptance  of  one's  testimony.  Al-Shafi'_ 
has  argued  by  qiyas,  that  because  the  person  punished  for 
other  great  sins  (kabirah)  upon  repentance  may  be  heard 
as  a  witness,  in  the  case  of  false  accusation  also  repentance 
should  remove  the  bar  to  the  acceptance  of  testimony.  The 
Hanifites  have  replied  that  the  application  of  qiyas  to  false 
accusation  would  amount  to  altering  the  divine  prescription 
(nass)  which  declares  that  the  false  accuser  shall  be  forever 
barred  from  rendering  testimony.1 

lKashf,  p.  1051. 


CHAPTER  VI 
ABROGATION  AND  CONFLICT  OF  THE  EVIDENCES 

WHEN  there  exist  in  the  shari'ah  two  evidences,  one  of 
which  refutes  what  the  other  establishes,  the  following  cases 
are  possible.  ( I )  Both  evidences  are  of  equal  strength,  but 
one  is  later  in  time;  (2)  both  evidences  are  of  equal 
strength,  but  it  is  not  known  which  is  the  later;  (3)  one 
of  the  evidences  is  stronger  by  virtue  of  a  secondary  dif- 
ference; (4)  one  of  the  evidences  is  stronger  by  virtue  of 
an  essential  difference.  The  first  case  involves  abrogation 
of  one  evidence  by  another;  the  second  is  a  case  of  conflict 
without  preference;  the  third  is  one  of  conflict,  with  pre- 
ference (mu'aradah  ma'-al-tarjih) ;  the  fourth  properly 
speaking,  is  really  not  a  case  of  conflict  or  preference,  for 
these  terms  are  used  only  when  the  two  evidences  are  of 
equal  strength. 

FIRST  CASE:  ABROGATION  (NASKH)  * 

Abrogation  is  the  occurrence  in  the  sharfah  of  an  evi- 
dence of  later  date  than  another  already  existing,  establish- 
ing the  opposite  of  what  the  earlier  one  does.  The  fact  that 
the  later  evidence  seems  to  mortals  a  reversal  of  the 
earlier  is  simply  because  the  first  evidence  was  indefinite 
(mutlaq)  as  to  time  limit,  and  consequently  was  presumed 
by  them,  owing  to  their  ignorance,  to  be  eternal.  In  reality, 
the  occurrence  of  an  abrogatory  evidence  denotes  only  that 
the  eternal  law-giver  had  decreed  for  the  first  evidence  a 

1  Tawdlh,  p.  408;  Pazdawi,  p.  874. 
399]  89 


90  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [400 

certain  time  limit  finally   revealed   and   made   known   to 
mortals  by  the  fact  of  abrogation. 

Abrogation  is  granted  by  the  Mohammedans  in  distinction 
from  the  Jews  who  deny  it.  There  have  also  been  Moham- 
medans who  denied  it;  but  al-Pazdawi  thinks  that  such 
persons  may  not  properly  be  called  so. 

Inasmuch  as  abrogation  is  nothing  but  the  revelation  of 
the  time  until  which  the  repealed  evidence  was  to  be  valid, 
only  those  evidences  may  be  abrogated  which  are  in  them- 
selves capable  of  time  limitation.  Hence  the  following  are 
not  subject  to  abrogation:  (i)  provisions  concerning  the 
divine  attributes  of  the  Creator,  which  having  existed  for- 
ever, are  not  capable  of  non-existence;  (2)  a  provision  con- 
nected with  a  circumstance  which  negates  the  possibility  of 
time  limitation;  for  example  the  Mohammedan  sharl'ah 
in  its  entirety  can  never  become  abrogated,  because  the 
circumstance  of  Mohammed's  being  the  last  of  the  prophets 
negates  the  possibility  of  its  abrogation.  Furthermore,  the 
abrogating  provision  must  be  later  than  the  abrogated,  both 
of  them  being  sharl'ah  provisions.  Hence  the  suspension 
of  religious  duties  because  of  infirmity  or  death  does  not 
constitute  a  case  of  abrogation. 

There  are  other  conditions  which  are  not  unanimously 
agreed  upon,  some  of  them  being  as  follows :  that  the  two 
provisions  be  of  the  same  genus  (jins)  ;  that  there  must  be 
some  substitute  for  the  repealed  provision ;  that  the  abrogat- 
ing provision  must  be  less  rigorous  than  the  one  abrogated ; 
that  a  provision  cannot  be  repealed  before  enough  time  has 
passed  for  persons  subject  to  the  law  (mukallaf)  to  show 
their  faith  (tamakkun  min  al-iftiqad) ,  although  it  is  not 
necessary,  as  some  claim,  that  the  time  should  be  long 
enough  for  the  actual  carrying  out  of  the  provision.  The 
divine  command  to  Abraham  to  slay  Isaac  is  a  case  in  point. 
According  to  some,  it  is  a  case  of  abrogation,  because  there 


40i]      ABROGATION  AND  CONFLICT  OF  EVIDENCES        9I 

passed  enough  time  for  Abraham  to  show  his  faith,  but 
according  to  others  it  is  not  a  case  of  abrogation. 

Only  the  Koran  and  the  sunnah  may  be  abrogators 
(nasikh).  There  may  be  four  ways  of  abrogation:  abro- 
gation of  Koran  by  Koran,  of  Koran  by  sunnah,1  whether 
of  the  mutawatir  or  the  mash-hfir  kind,2  of  sunnah  by 
Koran,  and  of  sunnah  by  sunnah.  Al-Shafi'i  has  maintained 
that  the  abrogation  of  the  Koran  by  the  sunnah,  and  vice 
versa,  is  not  valid. 

As  regards  the  ijma',  some  Hanifites  and  the  Mu'tazilites 
held  that  the  ijmaf  can  repeal  the  Koran  and  the  sunnah. 
According  to  the  majority  of  the  doctors,  however,  this 
cannot  be,  since  ijmaf  is  unanimity  of  opinion  and  opinion 
may  not  set  a  time  limit  to  the  prescriptions  of  the  shari'ah. 
Besides,  if  the  ijmaf  occurred  after  Mohammed's  time,  it  is 
unanimously  admitted  that  there  cannot  be  abrogation  after 
that  time,  and  if  it  occurred  in  Mohammed's  time,  inasmuch 
as  there  could  not  then  be  an  ijma',  except  upon  his  opinion, 
it  would  not  really  be  a  case  of  ijmd(,  but  of  sunnah. 

Finally,  as  regards  qiyas,  it  evidently  may  not  repeal  the 
Koran  or  the  sunnah,  since  its  function  is  to  extend  their 
prescriptions  to  cases  lying  outside  the  prescripts  of  the 
Koran  and  the  sunnah.  Some  held  the  opposite  view. 

SECOND  CASE:  CONFLICT  WITHOUT  PREFERENCE 

(MU'ARADAH)S 

When  there  is  a  conflict  between  two  verses  of  the  Koran, 
or  between  one  verse  and  a  pair  of  verses,  or  between  one 

1  According  to  the  Tawfch  (p.  416),  the  sunnah  does  not  abrogate  the 
text  of  the  Koran  "but  only  its  legal  value  (hukm),  for  the  Koran 
and  the  sunnah  are  alike  only  from  the  viewpoint  of  being  an  evidence 
for  values,  but  not  in  form  also,  since  the  Koran  alone  is  divine  in 
form." 

1  Tawdlh,  p.  417. 

1  Tcrwfch,  p.  531 ;  cf.  Pazdawi,  p.  796. 


0,2  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [402 

sunnah  and  a  pair  of  sunnahs,  or  between  one  qiyas  and  a 
pair  of  qiyases,  it  is  a  case  of  conflict  between  equals,  since 
strength  does  not  consist  in  number,  and  consequently  the 
single  verse,  sunnah,  or  qiyas  is  not  necessarily  set  aside  to 
make  room  for  the  pair. 

In  the  event  of  a  conflict,  if  between  qiyases,  one  or  the 
other  is  preferred  according  to  one's  convictions.  If,  how- 
ever, the  conflict  is  between  two  verses  or  two  readings  of 
the  Koran,  or  two  sunnahs,  whether  sayings  or  doings  of  the 
Prophet,  or  a  verse  and  a  sunnah,1  and  it  is  not  known 
which  of  the  conflicting  evidences  is  the  later  in  time, 
(otherwise  it  would  be  a  case  of  abrogation)  one  proceeds 
as  follows:  if  it  is  possible  to  reconcile  them,  by  reference 
to  their  value  (hukm),  subject-matter,  or  time,  it  is  done, 
otherwise,  the  conflicting  evidences  are  set  aside,  and  other 
evidences  are  referred  to.  For  example,  if  the  conflicting  evi- 
dences are  verses  of  the  Koran,  reference  is  made  to  the 
sunnah  and,  if  no  provision  is  found  in  the  sunnah,  to  qiyas 
and  the  sayings  of  the  Companions.  Similarly,  if  the  con- 
flict is  between  two  sunnahs,  then  qiyas  and  the  sayings  of 
the  Companions  are  referred  to.  In  going  from  the  sunnah 
to  qiyas  and  the  sayings  of  the  Companions,  two  courses 
are  possible.  According  to  those  who  place  the  sayings  of 
the  Companions  before  qiyas  in  every  case,  reference  is 
first  made  to  the  sayings,  and  if  no  provision  is  found  in 
them,  to  qiyas.  But  according  to  those  who  hold  that  the 
sayings  of  the  Companions,  in  regard  to  points  that  can  be 
established  by  qiyas,  are  nothing  but  qiyases,  one  may  refer 
on  such  points  to  either,  according  to  his  convictions. 

There  cannot  be  a  conflict  between  the  ijma*  and  another 
decisive  evidence  (dalil  qat'i),  namely,  the  Koran  and  the 

1  It  is  only  the  sunnah  of  the  mutawdtir  and  the  mash-hur  type  that  is 
meant  here,  for  the  "  individual "  can  never  conflict  with  the  Koran  or 
the  other  two  kinds  of  sunnah. 


403]      ABROGATION  AND  CONFLICT  OF  EVIDENCES        93 

sunnah,  since  a  valid  ijmdf  may  not  be  reached  in  contra- 
diction to  them. 


THIRD  AND  FOURTH  CASES  I  CONFLICT  OF  EVIDENCES  UN- 
EQUAL BY  VIRTUE  OF  A  SECONDARY  OR  AN  ESSENTIAL 
DIFFERENCE 

The  inequality  may  be  in  the  content  or  in  the  support 
(main  wa  sanad).  Inequality  in  the  content  arises  when 
the  proper  sense  of  a  word  is  contrasted  with  its  meta- 
phorical, or  the  explicit  sense  is  contrasted  with  the  implicit, 
etc.  Inequality  in  the  support  happens  when  the  mash-hur 
is  compared  with  the  "  individual,"  or  the  report  of  the 
transmitter  who  is  a  faqih  is  compared  with  the  report  of 
a  transmitter  who  is  not  a  faqih,  or  a  qiyds  which  is  based 
on  a  cause  ((illah)  expressly  stated  in  the  sources  is  con- 
trasted with  one  whose  cause  is  only  hinted  at.  In  case 
of  inequality,  the  stronger  evidence  is  always  preferred  to 
the  weaker,  for  example,  the  mash-hur  to  the  "  individual." 
The  laws  of  determining  the  stronger  evidence  in  each  case 
have  been  carefully  defined  by  the  doctors  in  the  treatises 
on  usiil-al-fiqh. 


CHAPTER  VII 

OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  LEGISLATION 
SECTION  I 
Istihsan  1 

WE  have  been  examining  so  far  the  four  bases  of  fiqh, 
namely  the  sources  of  law  which  are  accepted  by  all  of  the 
four  important  orthodox  schools  as  lawful,  and  which 
constitute,  as  it  were,  the  sources  par  excellence.  There 
are  however  other  principles  of  legislation  accepted  by  only 
a  few  of  them,  which  need  to  be  briefly  explained. 

Foremost  among  these  principles  is  istihsdn,  advocated 
by  the  Hanifites  alone.  The  word  means  literally,  to 
hold  something  for  good,  right.  According  to  the  treatises 
on  usiil-al-fiqh,  istihsan  technically  denotes  the  abandon- 
ment of  the  opinion  to  which  reasoning  by  analogy  (qiyas) 
would  lead,  in  favor  of  a  different  opinion  supported  by 
stronger  evidence.  Such  a  departure  from  qiyas,  may  be 
based  on  evidence  found  in  the  sunnah,  or  the  ijrna',  on 
necessity  (darurah) ,  or  on  what  the  upholders  of  qiyas  claim 
to  be  another  kind  of  qiyas  which,  though  it  does  not  so 
readily  occur  to  the  mind  as  the  first  qiyas,  in  reality  is 
stronger  than  it.2  Departure  f rdm  qiyas  in  the  three  former 

1  Pazdawi,  p.  1122  et  seq.;  Tawdih,  p.  493  et  seq. 

2  In  the  usage  of  writers  on  usul-al-fiqh,  istihsdn  generally  means  this 
last  kind   of  istihsdn,   namely,   the  istihsdn  based  on   another   qiyds, 
whereas  in  the  books  on  fiqh  it  denotes  the  former  three  kinds.    As  we 
are  concerned  with  questions  of  u^ul-al-fiqh,  istihsdn  shall  mean  the 
istihsdn  of  the  fourth  kind,  unless  otherwise  indicated. 

94  [404 


405]  OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  LEGISLATION  95 

cases  is  held  by  all  four  schools  to  be  legitimate.  For  ex- 
ample, salam  (sale  of  future  goods  for  present  cash)  and 
location  (ijarah),1  though  both  contrary  to  qiyds,  being 
sales  of  non-existing  goods,  have  been  justified  by  the 
sunnah;  or  istisnd'  (placing  an  order  with  an  artisan),  al- 
though contrary  to  qiyds  for  similar  reasons,  has  been  justi- 
fied by  ijma'. 

However,  departure  from  one  qiyas  in  favor  of  another 
qiyas,  that  is,  in  favor  of  istihsan,  has  been  a  subject  of 
hot  controversy  and  bitter  attack,  especially  on  the  part  of 
al-Shafi'i,  and  his  disciples.  This  attack  has  been  justified 
by  the  allegation  that  istihsan  is  no  more  nor  less  than  a 
setting  aside  of  the  revealed  sources  in  favor  of  the  personal 
opinion  of  the  canonist.  The  Hanifites  have  strongly 
denied  this  accusation.  Thus  the  author  of  the  Kashf  2  ex- 
presses himself  on  the  matter  as  follows: 

Some  of  the  false  accusers  among  the  Moslems  have  at- 
tacked Abu  Hanifah  and  his  disciples  because  they  aban- 
doned qiyds  for  istihsan,  and  said,  "  The  shari'ah  evidences 
are  the  Book,  the  sunnah,  the  ijma',  and  the  qiyds,  and  the 
istihsan  is  a  fifth  principle  recognized  by  Abu  Hanifah 
alone  "...  and  it  is  related  of  al-Shafi'i  that  he  exagger- 
ated in  denying  istihsan,  for  he  said,  "  Who  uses  istihsan 
places  himself  in  the  place  of  God  as  legislator,"  but  all  this 
is  attack  without  examination  .  .  .  and  learn  that  the  op- 
ponents have  not  blamed  Abu  Hanifah  for  the  istihsan 
based  on  evidence  in  the  sunnah,  or  the  ijma',  or  on  neces- 
sity, for  the  abandonment  of  qiyds  on  these  evidences  is 
granted  by  all  unanimously,  but  they  have  blamed  him 
only  for  the  istihsan  based  on  opinion,  [but  it  is  not  true 
that  this  latter  istihsan  is  based  on  opinion,  since]  according 

1  Location  is  considered  as  a  case  of  sale  of  non-existing  goods  be- 
cause the  benefits  from  the  use  of  the  object  leased  accrue  only  in  the 
future. 

3  P.  1123. 


96  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [406 

to  us  it  is  only  one  of  two  qiyases,  and  not  a  different  thing 
invented  by  way  of  passion  and  without  evidence.  Doubt- 
less when  two  qiyases  oppose  each  other  one  of  them  must 
be  preferred  [for  conduct  in  accordance  with  it]  when  a 
preference  is  possible,  and  [the  qiyas  preferred]  is  called 
istihsan,  in  order  to  indicate  that  it  is  the  better  fitted  of  the 
two  [for  conduct  in  accordance  with  it]  in  that  it  is  stronger 
than  the  other  qiyas. 

Another  doctor,  al-Pazdawi,  says  : * 

Inasmuch  as  according  to  our  school  the  cause  is  a  cause 
for  the  value,  we  have  named  that  which  is  weak,  qiyas, 
and  that  which  is  strong  istihsan,  meaning  by  it  that  it  is  a 
more  commendable  qiyas,  and  we  have  preferred  the  second, 
even  though  it  is  non-apparent,  to  the  former  which  is  ap- 
parent,2 for  importance  belongs  to  the  strength,  [of  causal 
"  effectiveness  "]  and  not  to  its  appearance.  Do  they  not 
see  that  this  world  is  apparent,  and  the  next  world  non- 
apparent,  and  yet  the  non-apparent  is  preferred  by  virtue 
of  the  strength  of  its  "  effectiveness,"  that  is,  its  perman- 
ence, eternity,  and  excellence,  and  the  apparent  [i.  e.,  the 
present  world]  is  abandoned  for  the  weakness  of  its  "  ef- 
fectiveness "  [athar]  ?  Likewise  the  qiyas  lapses  when  it 
is  in  conflict  with  the  istihsan? 

1  P.  1126. 

8  The  Hanifite  doctors,  who  claim  istihsdn  to  be  a  kind  of  qiyds,  in 
order  to  avoid  confusion  distinguish  it  from  the  qiyds,  whose  laws  we 
have  already  examined,  by  calling  the  former  apparent  (/a/t),  and  the 
istihsdn  non-apparent,  (khafi)  qiyds. 

8  The  Tawdih  (p.  493)  has  the  following  to  say  on  this  matter: 
"  Some  people  have  denied  the  validity  of  conduct  on  the  basis  of 
istihsdn,  because  of  ignorance  about  it;  for  if  they  oppose  the  name, 
there  can  be  no  discussion  on  terminology,  and  if  they  oppose  the  mean- 
ing of  it,  it  is  nonsense  similarly,  because  by  istihsdn  we  (i.  e.,  the 
Hanifites)  mean  an  evidence  of  the  number  of  evidences  unanimously 
accepted  (such  as  the  sunnah,  etc.)  which  occurs  in  opposition  to  the 
apparent  qiyds,  .  .  .  and  there  is  no  sense  in  denying  it ;  in  fact,  such 
opposing  evidence  may  be  either  a  swnnah,  ...  or  finally  a  non-appar- 
ent qiyds.  ..." 


407]  OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  LEGISLATION  97 

In  order  to  pass  judgment  on  the  merits  of  the  case  put 
forth  by  each  side,  we  must  examine  first  what  is  really 
meant  by  istihsan,  and  then  inquire  into  its  actual  working 
in  one  or  two  cases. 

The  Hanifites  are  profuse  in  saying  that,  what  they 
mean  by  istihsan,  is  that  one  of  two  qiyases  which,  al- 
though somewhat  more  obscure  than  the  other,  is  preferred 
because  it  is  stronger  in  its  causal  "  effectiveness."  They 
further  add  that  the  mere  fact  that  it  is  called  istihsan,  a 
contraction  of  the  expression  qiyas  mustahsan,  meaning 
"  the  qiyas  which  is  preferred,"  indicates  that  it  is  a  case 
of  choosing  between  two  qiyases  and  not  of  introducing  a 
new  principle,  as  the  Shafiites  claim. 

A  close  inquiry  into  the  treatises  on  usul-al-fiqh  will  dis- 
close that  the  word  istihsan  is  not  used  to  indicate  only  the 
qiyas  that  has  been  preferred  but  that,  on  the  contrary,  the 
name  applies  to  some  new  kind  of  a  principle — a  principle 
different  from  qiyas,  at  least  as  the  latter  has  been  under- 
stood by  the  doctors — which  is  called  istihsan,  whether  or 
not  it  is  preferred  to  qiyas.1  This  point  has  been  raised 
by  the  very  defenders  of  istihsan.2 

The  fact  is  that  istihsan,  as  originally  introduced  and 
used  by  Abu  Hanifah,  was  no  more  nor  less  than  a  resort 
to  personal  opinion  as  influenced  by  considerations  of  public 
welfare.  When  the  Shafiites  attacked  this  principle  on  the 
ground  that  it  meant  a  setting  aside  of  the  revealed  texts, 
the  disciples  of  Abu  Hanifah  felt  themselves  forced 

1  The  following  quotation  from  the  Tawfch  (p.  496)  fully  bears  this 
point  out :  "  By  an  intellectual  division,  each  [qiyds  and  istihsdn]  is 
divided  into  strong  and  weak  in  causal  "  effectiveness,"  and  in  case  of 
conflict,  istihsan  is  not  preferred  to  qiyas  except  in  one  single  case, 
namely,  when  the  qiyds  is  weak  in  its  causal  "  effectiveness."  and  the 
istihsdn  is  strong.  As  regards  the  other  three  cases,  the  qiyds  is  pre- 
ferred to  the  istihsdn. 

1  Kashf,  p.  1123. 


98  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [408 

to  show  that  such  was  not  the  case,  and  being  able  in 
scholastic  methods,  they  put  forward  the  contention  that 
istihsan  was  nothing  but  another  kind  of  qiyas,  which  was 
called  istihsan  because,  being  stronger,  it  was  preferred  to 
the  other.  But  at  the  next  moment,  they  are  forced  to  contra- 
dict themselves  by  saying  that  istihsan  is  not  always  pre- 
ferred to  qiyas.  This  is  nothing  less  than  an  admission  by 
implication  on  their  part,  that  istihsan  is  not  the  same  thing 
as  qiyas. 

That  Abu  Hanifah  and  his  earliest  disciples  did  not  con- 
sider istihsan  as  a  kind  of  qiyas,  and  that  the  above  con- 
tention is  really  an  afterthought,  is  borne  out  by  statements 
quoted  in  the  Hanifite  books  themselves.  Thus  al-Bukhari 
states  in  the  Kashf  *  that  the  Hanifites  disagreed  about  the 
meaning  of  the  istihsan  which  Abu  Hanifah  advocated. 
Some  said  that  it  is  a  departure  from  one  qiyas  to  another 
and  stronger  qiyas.2  Others  said  it  is  the  limitation  of 
qiyas  by  some  evidence  stronger  than  itself.  Abu  '1-Hasan 
al-Karkhi,  who  preceded  al-Pazdawi  by  over  a  century & 
is  quoted  as  having  said :  "  Istihsan  is  to  depart  from  judg- 
ing in  a  case  according  to  what  has  been  judged  in  analogous 
cases,  and  to  judge  to  the  contrary  on  account  of  a  stronger 
reason  (li  wajh  aqwa)  which  renders  necessary  the  de- 
parture from  the  former."  *  This  quotation  from  al- 
Karkhi  seems  to  express  the  real  situation  before  the  later 
writers  had  as  yet  woven  into  it  their  own  refinements. 
The  mere  fact  of  a  disagreement  about  the  meaning  in 
which  Abu  Hanifah  used  istihsan  is  very  significant.  It 
shows  that  Abu  Hanifah  did  not  use  the  word  in  any  techni- 

1  P.  1123. 

*  This  is  the  view  held  by  al-Pazdawi  and  the  later  doctors. 

3  Al-Karkhi  died  in  340  of  the  Hijrah,  while  al-Pazdawi  died  in  482. 

4  Kashf,  loc.  cit. 


409]  OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  LEGISLATION  99 

cal  sense.  Had  that  been  the  case,  like  so  many  of  his 
views  it  would  probably  have  been  placed  on  record.  The 
fact  is  that  he  used  the  word  istihsan  in  its  usual  meaning, 
namely  that  of  abandoning  qiyas  for  an  opinion  thought  more 
subservient  to  the  social  interests.  In  the  Kashf  there  is  a 
quotation  to  bear  this  out.  According  to  it,  Abu  Hanifah 
has  said  on  certain  occasions,  "  I  have  abandoned  istihsan 
for  qiyas"  He  evidently  meant  by  istihsan  something 
different  from  qiyas.  Similar  statements  are  found  in 
Abu  Yusuf's  Kitab-al-kharaj '-1  Finally,  al-Shafi'i  con- 
demning istihsan  says  2  "  If  one  were  allowed  to  ignore 
qiyas,  the  people  of  opinion  [ahl  al-'uqul]  who  are  not 
informed  on  'Urn  [namely,  the  knowledge  of  the  re- 
vealed texts]  would  then  have  been  allowed  to  express 
opinion  on  matters  in  regard  to  which  there  is  no  prescrip- 
tion in  the  revealed  texts,  according  to  what  seems  to  them 
proper  (istihsan)";  but  this  is  not  allowed.  Now  if  Abu 
Hanifah  meant  by  istihsan  a  kind  of  qiyas,  it  is  very  likely 
that  al-Shafi'i  would  have  referred  to  it.  We  may,  there- 
fore, be  certain  that  the  contention  made  in  regard  to 
istihsan  being  a  kind  of  qiyas,  is  only  a  fiction,  invented  by 
later  Hanifite  doctors.  Even  if  we  grant  this  fiction  to 
be  true,  istihsan  still  is  a  liberating  principle,  as  will  become 
clear  from  the  following : 

To  take  up  first  the  contention  that  istihsan  is  a  kind  of 
qiyas,  it  may  be  answered  that  it  is  true  that  in  the  last 
analysis  istihsan  is  a  sort  of  judgment  by  analogy,  but  one 
in  which  the  causal  attribute  (cillah),  is  not  determined  in 
quite  the  same  way  prescribed  in  the  treatises  on  usul-al-fiqh, 
but  is  somewhat  far  fetched.  The  very  name  of  khafi 
(concealed,  subtle)  given  to  this  kind  of  qiyas  by  the 

1  P.  109,  1.  i;  p.  112,  1.  — 5;  p.  117,  1.  — 5;  £f.  also  al-Jdmi'  al-Sagir, 
P-  17,  1.  —5 ;  P-  72,  1.  2. 
1  Risdlah,  p.  70,  1.  i. 


100  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [410 

doctors,  suggests  this.  But  in  applying  a  qiyas  the  most 
important  thing  is  the  basis  on  which  the  qiyas  will  be  made, 
namely,  the  fillah,  and  if  you  once  grant  the  right  of  depar- 
ture from  the  accepted  principles  in  determining  this  'illah, 
with  the  aid  of  a  little  scholastic  ability,  one  can  prove 
almost  anything  on  earth.  A  few  examples  will  illustrate 
the  point.1 

Judging  by  analogy  the  food  touched  (su'r)  by  wild  birds 
should  be  unclean  (najs),  because  the  food  touched  by 
wild  beasts  is  unclean,  and  wild  birds  are  like  wild  beasts, 
both  being  unclean  for  eating.  However,  judging  by 
istihsan,  the  food  touched  by  wild  birds  is  clean  (tahir). 
The  argument  is  as  follows.  The  quadrupeds,  when  they 
touch  food,  inevitably  leave  a  part  of  their  saliva  in  the 
remainder  and  pollute  it,  because  the  saliva  is  secreted  from 
the  flesh  and  is  unclean  like  it.  In  the  case  of  the  birds, 
however,  this  is  not  true,  because  they  take  the  food  by 
means  of  their  beak,  which  is  a  hollow  bone  and  has  no 
saliva  in  it.  So,  although  apparently,  the  food  touched  by 
the  latter  should  by  analogy  also  be  unclean,  a  closer  inquiry 
reveals  the  fact  that  it  is  not  polluted.  Indeed  the  animals 
are  not  unclean  as  such,  for  it  is  allowed  to  use  them  and 
sell  them,  and  if  they  were  unclean,  in  and  of  themselves, 
like  pigs,  their  use  and  sale  would  have  been  likewise  for- 
bidden. Moreover,  if  the  bones  of  dead  animals  are  con- 
sidered clean,  how  can  the  bones  of  living  animals  be  con- 
sidered unclean?  In  other  words,  the  uncleanness  resides 
in  the  flesh  alone,  and  the  food  they  have  touched  has  been 
considered  unclean  because  of  its  admixture  with  the  un- 
clean, but  this  does  not  happen  in  the  case  of  the  birds. 

How  many  nice  distinctions  must  be  made  in  order  to 
reach  the  above  conclusion  ?  It  must  first  be  proved  that  the 

1  Kashf,  p.  1126;  Taw&b,  p.  493- 


I 


41 1  ]  OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  LEGISLATION  IOi 

'illah  is  the  admixture  with  the  unclean.  Second,  that  it  is 
only  the  flesh  that  is  unclean,  not  the  beak,  horn,  etc.  Yet 
one  might  just  as  readily  argue  that  the  latter  are  more,  or 
just  as  much  unclean  as  the  flesh;  or,  assuming  for  the 
sake  of  argument,  that  contact  without  some  theoretical 
minimum  of  admixture  is  possible,  that  mere  contact  is  suf- 
ficient to  pollute. 

To  cite  another  example  of  istihsan,  if  two  parties  to  an 
act  of  salam,  (sale  of  future  goods  for  present  cash),  dis- 
agree in  regard  to  the  length  (dhira')  of  the  thing  sold 
(nwslam-flh) ,  according  to  qiyds,  each  party  may  require 
an  oath  from  the  other  (tahaluf),  because  they  have  dis 
agreed  about  something  claimed  by  virtue  of  an  act  of  salam. 
According  to  istihsan,  they  do  not  require  an  oath,  because 
they  have  not  disagreed  on  the  thing  sold,  but  on  its  quality, 
which  does  not  require  the  giving  of  an  oath  to  each  party. 
"  However,  if  we  examine  closely,  we  see  that  they  are  not 
disagreeing  on  the  very  thing  sold,  but  on  its  quality,  for 
they  have  disagreed  about  the  length.  But  the  length  is  a 
quality,  because  when  the  length  is  greater,  the  dress  made 
out  of  it  is  better,  unlike  the  case  of  measure  by  volume, 
(kayl)  or  by  weight.  Since  the  measure  by  length  is  a 
quality,  disagreement  on  the  length  does  not  necessitate 
tahaluf.  This  meaning,  namely,  that  the  length  is  a  quality, 
is  more  subtle,  than  the  other,  and  judgment  based  on  it  is 
called  istihsan,  as  distinguished  from  qiyas."  * 

The  argument  here  is  that  a  shortage  in  length  is  different 
from  one  in  weight  or  volume,  because  in  the  latter  two 
cases  the  buyer  may  make  up  the  shortage  by  buying  more 
of  it,  whereas  in  the  case  of  length,  although  he  may  still  buy 
more,  he  cannot  use  this  last  increment  as  profitably.  For 
instance,  assuming  the  object  bought  to  be  cloth,  a  shortage 

1  Taw&h,  idem. 


102  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [4I2 

in  the  length  would  affect  the  quality  of  the  dress  to  be  made 
out  of  it.  Now,  although  this  is  true  in  general,  it  is  based 
on  many  assumptions.  In  the  first  place  one  might  question 
whether  this  consideration  of  length  was  entirely  relevant 
to  the  point  at  issue,  namely,  the  taking  of  an  oath  by  both 
parties.  Again,  one  might  contend  that  there  are  cases 
where  it  is  not  possible  to  buy  the  part  wanting,  and  then 
volume  and  weight  would  be  like  length. 

These  two  concrete  cases  clearly  illustrate,  how  easily  the 
argument  may  be  twisted  to  arrive  at  conclusions  as  dif- 
ferent as  prohibition  and  permission.  This  is  not  saying, 
that  the  Hanifite  doctors  have  been  consciously  twisting 
their  arguments,  or  that  it  is  at  all  necessary  to  do  that,  in 
order  to  get  the  desired  result.  As  a  matter  of  fact,  what 
happens  is  that  one  starts  out  with  a  certain  predisposition 
inspired  by  existing  practices  and  social  needs  or  by  a  priori 
considerations,  and  the  rest  takes  care  of  itself  without  con- 
sciousness on  the  part  of  the  thinker. 

SECTION  II 

The  Other  Principles 

ISTISLAH.  We  have  already  referred  to  this  principle 
in  discussing  qiyas.  It  consists  in  prohibiting  or  permit- 
ting  a  thing  simply  because  it  serves  a  "  useful  purpose  " 

(maslahah),  although  there  is  no  express  evidence  in  the  re- 
vealed sources  to  support  such  action.  Istislah,  has  been 
called  by  some,  "  independent  deduction  "  (istidlal  mursal), 
or  simply  "deduction"  (istidlal).  Al-Gazali  defines 
istislah,  as  the  establishment  of  a  legal  principle  (hukm) 
for  which  there  is  no  evidence  in  the  sources,  but  which  is 
recommended  by  reason  as  advantageous.  According  to 
al-Khuwarizmi,  "  useful  purpose  "  (maslahah)  means  the 
protection  and  preservation  of  the  objects  of  the  sharfah, 


413]  OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  LEGISLATION  IC>3 

by  warding  off  mischief   from  humanity.     The  "  useful 
purpose  "  has  been  divided  into  three  kinds. 

( i  )The  "useful  purpose"  which  meets  an  absolute  neces- 
sity ( daruri) .  Such  is  supposed  to  be  the  case,  in  the  follow- 
ing five  instances  called  al-kulliyyat  al-khams:  (a)  preserva- 
tion of  life  (the  law  of  tallion)  ;  (b)  protection  of  property 
(prescriptions  like  the  cutting  off  of  one's  hand  for  theft)  ; 

(c)  preservation  of  the  offspring  (prohibition  of  adultery)  ; 

(d)  preservation  of   faith    (the  killing  of  the  apostates 
[murtadd]    and  holy  war) ;    (e)    finally,   preservation  of 
reason :  the  prohibition  of  alcoholic  drinks  is  based  on  this 
ground. 

(2)  The   "useful   purpose"   which   meets   no  absolute 
necessity  but  is  merely  expedient  (haji).    For  example,  the 
institution  of  location  (i jar  ah)  is  based  on  this. 

(3)  The  "  useful  purpose  "  which  serves  an  end  like  the 
promotion  of  good  morals  (tahsmi).1 

The  principle  of  istislah  is  used  by  the  Malikites,  the  other 
schools  having  prohibited  its  use.  However,  the  Malikites 
claim  that  all  the  schools  have  used  it.2  According  to  al- 
Juwayni,  Malik  carried  this  principle  too  far,  so  that  for 
purposes  useful  in  appearance  only,  he  made  legitimate  the 
taking  of  life,  and  the  confiscation  of  property,  although 
there  was  no  evidence  in  the  revealed  texts  to  confirm  such 
a  procedure. 

ISTISHAB.  This  principle  has  been  introduced  by  al- 
Shafi'i.  According  to  it,  when  the  existence  of  a  thing  has 
been  once  established  by  evidence,  even  though  later  some 
doubt  should  arise  as  to  its  continuance  in  existence,  it  is 
still  considered  to  exist.  It  is  called  istishab  al-hal,  if  the 
present  is  judged  according  to  the  past,  and  istishab  al- 

1  Shawkani,  p.  201. 

2  Majmu,  p.  67. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

modi,  if  the  converse  is  the  case.  This  principle  is  admitted 
by  Abu  Hanifah  also,  but  only  to  refute  an  assertion 
(dawa),  that  is,  as  an  instrument  of  defence,  (daf  dawa) 
and  not  to  establish  a  new  claim  (dawa).  According  to 
al-Shafi'i,  however,  it  may  be  used  for  both  purposes.  The 
Hanifites  hold  that  the  establishment  of  the  existence  of  a 
fact  is  no  evidence  of  its  continuance  in  existence  and 
therefore,  they  say,  the  continuance  of  the  Mohammedan 
shari'ah  after  the  death  of  Mohammed  does  not  rest  on  the 
principle  of  istishab,  as  the  Shafiites  claim,  but  on  the 
hadith  that  the  Mohammedan  shari'ah  will  never  be  abro- 
gated. 

The  principle  of  istishab  is  a  limited  principle.  It  only 
applies  to  cases  where  there  is  no  evidence  obtainable,  and 
at  best,  establishes  the  continuance  of  a  fact  in  existence, 
which  was  already  proved  to  have  existed.1  Nevertheless, 
in  the  extended  scope  given  to  it  by  al-Shafi'i,  it  acquires 
considerable  importance,  especially  in  questions  of  fiqh. 

THE  SUNNAH  OF  THE  COMPANIONS.  The  sunnah  of 
the  Companions  of  the  Prophet  has  been  a  source  of  great 
importance.  Theoretically  this  sunnah  is  not  binding  upon 
the  Mohammedans,  except  in  so  far  as  it  is  based  on  that 
of  the  Prophet.  When  the  conduct  of  the  Companions  is 
based  upon  their  personal  judgments,  it  is  considered  equi- 
valent to  qiyas,  and  the  canonist  is  free  to  accept  or  reject  it. 
However  this  theoretical  restriction  has  no  importance  in 
practice,  since  one  can  always  claim  that  the  sunnah  of  the 
Companions  was  based  on  that  of  the  Prophet.  This  is 
confirmed  by  the  divergence  of  view,  concerning  the  mean- 
ing of  the  word  sunnah  when  it  occurs  by  itself  (mutlaq), 
that  is,  when  there  is  no  indication  to  show  whether  it  is  the 
sunnah  of  the  Prophet  or  of  his  Companions  which  is  meant. 

1  Tawdlh,  p.  527. 


4!5]  OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  LEGISLATION  IO5 

We  have  seen  in  discussing  the  classification  of  the  sharl'ah 
values,  that  many  held  the  view  that  the  word  sunnah  may 
mean  both  the  sunnah  of  the  Prophet  and  that  of  his  Com- 
panions. It  would  seem  that  in  actual  practice  usually  no 
distinction  was  made  between  the  two  sunnahs,  and  that 
the  writers  on  usul-al-fiqh  attempted  to  draw  such  a  distinc- 
tion, only  because  they  were  driven  by  the  logical  necessi- 
ties of  the  case.  Hence  one  may  without  hesitation  say  that 
in  practice  the  sunnah  of  the  Companions  has  exercised 
great  influence  on  the  development  of  the  Mohammedan 
law.  One  may  easily  convince  himself  of  this  by  a  refer- 
ence to  the  fiqh  books  where  a  great  number  of  decisions 
have  been  based  on  the  sunnah  of  the  Companions.  This 
is  also  borne  out  by  the  great  number  of  traditions  found  in 
the  hadith  collections,  bearing  on  the  sunnah  of  the  Com- 
panions.1 

The   views   of   the    canonists   on   this   subject   may   be 
summarized  as  follows : 2 

(1)  The  sunnah  of  the  companions  is  by  unanimous 
opinion  (ijma()  binding  on  those  points  concerning  which, 
though  generally  known,  no  opposition  has  been  made  on 
the  part  of  the  Moslems. 

(2)  Their  sunnah  is  not  binding  on  the  points  on  which 
they  have  disagreed  among  themselves.     There  is  an  ijmd' 
on  this  opinion. 

(3)  There  is  disagreement  as  to  the  binding  force  of 
their  sunnah  on  the  points  on  which  it  is  not  known  whether 
they  have  agreed  or  disagreed :  according  to  al-Shafi'i  their 
sunnah  on  such  points  is  not  binding,  because  it  cannot  have 
been  based  on  direct  hearing  from  the  Prophet,  and  because 
the  Companions  in  their  ijtihad,  like  other  canonists,  are 

1  Cf.  Sprenge'r,  p.  2. 
8  Tawfch,  p.  384. 


I06  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

liable  to  error.  But  according  to  Sa'id  al-Barda'i,  their 
sunnah  is  binding,  because  the  Prophet  has  said :  "  My  Com- 
panions are  like  the  stars,  no  matter  whom  from  among 
them  you  follow,  you  will  be  going  the  right  way,"  and 
because  most  of  the  sayings  of  the  Companions  are  based  on 
what  the  latter  have  heard  from  the  Prophet.  Moreover, 
the  Companions  have  witnessed  the  circumstances  of  the 
revelations,  have  been  pioneers  in  the  religion,  and  have  had 
the  blessing  of  conversation  with  the  Prophet.  According 
to  al-Karkhi,  the  sunnah  of  the  Companions  is  binding  only 
as  regards  those  points  which  cannot  be  otherwise  cleared 
up  by  qiyas,  as  such  points  must  have  been  based  on  direct 
hearing  from  the  Prophet,  unless  they  be  lying,  which  is 
inconceivable.  But  their  sunnah  is  not  valid  as  regards 
points  which  may  be  established  by  qiyas,  since  the  Com- 
panions like  others  may  err  in  their  qiyases. 

As  regards  the  Followers  (tabi'iyyun,  or  tabi'un),  that  is, 
the  generation  following  the  Companions,  their  sayings  are 
like  those  of  the  Companions,  if  they  have  expressed  them 
during  the  time  of  the  latter,  for  by  the  tacit  confirmation 
of  the  Companions,  they  have  become  like  them.1 

CUSTOM.2  Custom  (curf}  (adah)  maybe  general  (famm) 
or  special  (khass).  Each  of  these  may  either  be  in  opposi- 
tion to  the  sources  (nass  shar'i)  or  to  the  statements  (nass) 
occurring  in  the  recognized  books  of  the  school  (zahir-al- 
riwayah)  ;  or  on  the  contrary,  it  may  be  in  accordance  with 
them.  If  the  latter  is  the  case,  there  is  no  room  for  dis- 
cussion ;  if  however  custom  is  in  opposition  to  them  the  fol- 
lowing cases  are  conceivable. 

(i)  Custom  is  in  opposition  to  the  revealed  texts, 
(nass  shar'i).  In  such  a  case,  if  the  opposition  is  absolute, 

1  Cf.  Pazdawi,  p.  944 ;  Taivfch,  p.  383. 

2  Ibn  'Abidin,  vol.  ii,  pp.  114  et  seq. 


4!7]  OTHER  PRINCIPLES  OF  LEGISLATION  JQ/ 

so  much  so  that  to  follow  the  custom  would  amount  to  an 
abandonment  of  the  text,  then  there  is  no  doubt  that  custom 
must  be  set  aside.  If  however  the  opposition  is  not  abso- 
lute, if  for  example  the  text  is  general  and  the  custom 
opposes  it  in  some  of  its  applications,  or  if  the  custom, 
instead  of  opposing  the  text  opposes  only  a  qiyas  based  on 
it,  preference  is  given  to  the  custom,  if  general,  as  was 
the  case  in  istisna'  or  in  entering  a  bath  without  specifying 
the  time  to  be  spent  therein.1  Custom  however  is  set  aside, 
if  not  general. 

(2)  Custom  is  in  opposition  to  the  text  of  the  books 
recognized  in  the  Hanifite  school  as  standard  (sahir-al- 
rksayah) .  The  texts  of  these  books  are  either  directly 
based  on  an  unequivocal  statement  (nass)  in  the  revealed 
sources,  and  then  it  is  the  same  as  in  the  preceding  case ;  or 
they  are  merely  the  opinions  of  the  doctors.  Inasmuch  as 
many  of  these  opinions  have  been  based  by  the  mujtahids 
on  the  customs  of  their  times,  it  is  permissible  to  depart  from 
them  if  the  customs  have  meanwhile  changed.  It  is  neces- 
sary, however,  in  doing  this  to  exercise  great  circumspection 
and  care.  In  this  last  case,  it  is  immaterial  whether  the 
custom  is  general  or  special,  because  both  of  them  take 
precedence  over  the  texts  of  the  books. 

PREVIOUS  DISPENSATIONS.2  According  to  some,  these 
continue  in  force  so  long  as  they  have  not  been  abro- 
gated. Others  hold  that  they  are  not  binding,  unless  there 
is  evidence  to  the  contrary.  Still  others  claim  that  these 

1  Both  in  istisna  and  in  entering  a  bath,  analogy  would  require  that 
the  acts  should  be  considered  imperfect  (fdsid)  :  in  the  case  of  sale, 
because  there  is  opposition  to  the  principle  that  the  thing  sold  must  be 
already  in  existence  at  the  time  of  sale;  in  the  case  of  location,  be- 
cause the  time  during  which  the  location  is  to  run  must  be  known. 
However,  in  both  cases  the  analogy  of  the  text  has  been  overruled  be- 
cause of  a  custom  to  the  contrary. 

1  Tawfch,  p.  383 ;  Pazdawi,  p.  932. 


I08  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [4Ig 

were  meant  for  the  people,  time  and  place  for  which  they 
were  revealed.  The  opinion  generally  accepted  by  the 
Hanifites  is  that  previous  dispensations,  in  view  of  their 
great  distortion  at  the  hands  of  their  votaries,  are  valid  for 
the  Moslems  only  in  so  far  as  they  have  been  confirmed  by 
the  Mohammedan  shari'ah. 


CHAPTER  VIII 
CLASSIFICATION  OF  THE  SHARI'AH  VALUES 

The  author  of  the  Tawdlh  l  reduces  the  various  kinds  of 
sharl'ah  values  (hukm)  to  the  following  classes : 

A  sharl'ah  value  may  or  may  not  consist  in  a  correlation 
(ta'alluq)  between  one  thing  and  another,  as  when  we  say 
that  A  is,  or  is  not,  the  cause  or  condition  of  B. 

When  the  value  does  consist  in  a  correlation  of  one  thing 
with  another,2 

(1)  if  that  which  is  so  correlated  is  contained  in  the 
thing  to  which  it  is  correlated,  it  is  called  its  rukn  (formal 
cause) ,  e.  g.,  the  offer  and  acceptance  of  the  two  parties  to  a 
sale  are  the  rukn  of  sale,  because  they  are  included  in  the 
act  of  sale ; 

(2)  if  the  thing  so  correlated  is  not  contained,  but  is  ex- 
ternal to  the  thing  to  which  it  is  correlated,  then, 

(a)  if  it  has  been  indicated  in  the  revealed  sources  as  the 
"  effective  "  cause  (mu'ath-thir  flh)  of  the  latter  thing,  it  is 
called  its  "  effective  "  cause  ('illah) ; 

(b)  if  it  is  not  so,  and, 

(1)  if  on  the  whole  it  leads  to  the  other  thing,  it  is 
called  its  sabab  (occasion,  cause), 

(2)  if  it  does  not  lead  to  it,  and, 

(a)  if  the  other  thing  is  dependent  upon  it,  it 
is  called  a  condition  (shart),  and 

(b)  if  the  other  thing  is  not  dependent  upon  it, 
it  is  called  a  sign  ('alamah)  of  the  other 
thing. 

1  Pp.  561  et  seq. ;  cf.  Talwih,  ibid. 

1  Tawdih,  p.  561. 

419]  109 


IIO  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [420 

When  the  value  does  not  consist  in  a  correlation  of  one 

thing  with  another,  it  is  either  a  quality  of  an  act  by  a  legally 
responsible  person  (mukallaf),  such  as  the  quality  of  an 
act  being  allowed  (ibahah)  or  prohibited  (hurmah)  in  the 
shan'ah;  or  it  is  the  effect  (athar)  of  such  an  act,  such  as 
ownership  and  indebtedness,  which  are  the  effects  of  the 
acts  of  purchase  and  borrowing  respectively. 

When  the  value  is  a  quality  of  an  act,  two  cases  are 
possible : 

1 I )  The  emphasis  is  either  laid  on  the  "  worldly  con- 
sideration," for  example,  when  we  speak  of  the  validity 
(sihhah)  of  an  act  of  worship,  we  are  primarily  thinking 
of  the  act  as  freeing  the  worshiper  from  the  obligation  of 
performing  that  particular  worship  again.     In  other  words, 
we  are  emphasizing  what  the  doctors  call  "  worldly  con- 
sideration," *  although  we  may  be  thinking,  in  a  secondary 
way,  also  of  the  "  religious  consideration,"   namely,  the 
acquisition  of  merit  (thawab)  which  the  act  results  in. 

(2)  Or  the  emphasis  is  laid  on  the  "religious  consider- 
ation," for  example,  when  we  speak  of  an  act  being  wajib 
(obligatory),  we  are  primarily  thinking  of  the  act  as  result- 
ing in  religious  merit  (thawab),  although  we  may  be  think- 
ing of  the  act,  in  a  secondary  way,  also  as  securing  freedom 
from  an  obligation  (tafrig  al-dhimmah) . 

From  the  standpoint  of  the  "worldly  consideration," 
the  value  of  an  act  is  said  to  have, 

(a)  validity  (sihhah),  if  the  act  results  in  the  realization 

1  By  "  worldly  consideration "  the  doctors  mean,  in  matters  of  wor- 
ship ('ibadat},  the  freeing  of  the  person  from  the  obligation  of  per- 
forming the  particular  act  of  worship,  say,  ablution,  and  in  temporal 
matters  (mu'dmaldt),  the  securing  of  the  various  intentions  and  objects 
which  pertain  to  those  temporal  matters,  such  as,  for  example,  the 
acquisition  of  property  or  its  alienation  pertaining  to  the  worldly  acts 
of  purchase  and  sale  respectively. 


42i]      CLASSIFICATION  OF  THE  SHARl'AH  VALUES      m 

of  the  "  worldly  consideration ;"  for  example,  a  sale  is  valid 
(sahth)  if  it  results  legally  in  the  transfer  of  ownership 
from  the  seller  to  the  buyer ; 

(b)  nullity   (butlan),  if  it  entirely  fails  to  secure  the 
realization  of  the  "  worldly  consideration ;"  such  an  act  is 
called  null  (batil) ; 

(c)  imperfection   (fasOd),  if  the  formal  cause   (rukn) 
and  the  conditions  (sharft'it)  of  the  act  are  conducive  to  the 
realization  of  the  "  worldly  consideration,"  but  its  outward 
qualities  (awsaf  kharijiyyah)  are  not  so  conducive;  the  act 
then  is  said  to  be  fasid.1 

From  the  standpoint  of  the  "  religious  2  consideration," 
values  are  either  'azimah  (ideal)  or  rukhsah  (actual). 
They  are  said  to  be  'azimah,  when  they  are  considered 
a  priori  and  in  their  original  rigor,  without  reference  to 
any  attenuating  circumstances  in  life,  which  may  soften 
their  rigor  or  even  entirely  suspend  them.  They  are  the 
law  as  intended  in  the  first  instance  by  the  lawgiver.  They 
are  said  to  be  rukhsah  (literally,  concession)  when  they  are 
considered  with  reference  to  the  attenuating  circumstances 
of  life. 

Human  acts,  according  to  the  'azimah  values  which 
attach  to  them,  are  grouped  in  the  following  categories 

1  From  the  standpoint  of  "  worldly  consideration  "  as  pertaining  to 
temporal  matters    (mu'dmaldf),  one  may  further  distinguish  between 
acts,  which  are  contracted  (mun'aqid)  or  uncontracted  (gayr-mun'aqid) , 
authorized    (ndfidh)    or  unauthorized    (mawquf),  binding    (Idzim)    or 
non-binding  (gayr-ldzim) . 

2  Some  doctors  have  claimed  that  the  several  sharl'ah  values  distin- 
guished from  the  standpoint  of  "  worldly  consideration  "  may  be  all 
reduced  to  some  one  of  the  values  distinguished  from  the  religious 
standpoint.     Thus,  they  said  that  when  a  sale  is  claimed  to  be  valid 
(saljih),  it  is  only  meant  that  the  purchaser  may  exercise  on  the  thing 
purchased  all  the  rights   of  ownership,   such  acts  on  his  part  being 
mubdh.    Others  contended  that  these  values,  properly  speaking,  are  not 
shari'ah  values  at  all.     (Talwih,  p.  563.) 


H2  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [422 

which  shade  off  into  one  another  from  the  "  imperative  " 
(fard)  to  the  "  indifferent  "  (mubah). 

(1)  The  fard  (imperative)  is  the  act  whose  value,  called 
faradiyyah,  has  been  established  by  a  shari'ah  evidence  about 
which  there  is  no  doubt.     The  legal  effect  (hukm)  of  the 
fard  is  that  it  must  be  given  absolute  faith  and  self-sur- 
render and  that  it  must  be  executed.      Failure  to  believe 
in  it  entails  unbelief,  and  failure  to  execute  it  causes  im- 
piety (fisq). 

Conversely,  the  commission  of  the  fard  results  in  the 
acquisition  of  religious  merit  (thawab).  Thawab  techni- 
cally means  title  to  "  divine  mercy  and  pardon,  and  to  the 
mediation  of  the  Prophet."  *  Examples  of  the  fard  are 
faith  (iman)y  performance  of  the  daily  prayers,  giving  of 
zakat,  pilgrimage  to  Mecca,  etc. 

The  fard,  and  for  that  matter,  the  wajib  also,  is  divided 
into  two  kinds:  (a)  The  fard  'ayn  (personal  fard)  ;  it  is 
the  act  which  every  one  must  personally  perform.  The 
performance  of  the  daily  prayers,  and  the  giving  of  zakat 
are  of  this  kind,  (b)  The  fard  kifayah  (social  fard)  ;  it  is 
the  act  which  every  person  is  under  obligation  to  perform, 
until  a  sufficient  number  of  persons  have  performed  it,  the 
rest  being  then  absolved  from  the  obligation  of  performance. 
The  reward  (ajr)  in  such  case,  belongs  to  those  who  per- 
formed the  act,  but  the  rest  are  not  punished  for  its  omis- 
sion. If  however  no  one  should  perform  the  act,  then  they 
are  all  punished.  An  example  of  this  is  the  obligation  of 
holy  war  (jihad).  Every  Moslem  is  under  obligation  to 
wage  it,  until  a  sufficient  number  of  Moslems  have  done  so. 

(2)  The  wajib    (obligatory)    is  the  act  whose  value, 
called  zvujftb,  has  been  established  by  a  sharfah  evidence 
concerning  which  there  is  doubt.     The  giving  of  alms  for 

1  Tech.  Diet.,  p.  171. 


423]      CLASSIFICATION  OF  THE  SHARP  AH  VALUES 

breaking  the  fast  is  of  this  kind.  The  value  (hukm)  of  the 
wajib  is  that  it  must  be  executed  like  the  fard,  although  it 
need  not  be  given  absolute  faith  as  the  latter.  Al-Shafi'i 
merged  the  fard  and  the  wajib  into  one  single  category,  call- 
ing it  by  either  one  of  the  two  names,  and  defining  it  as 
"  that  whose  commission  is  rewarded  and  omission  pun- 
ished." Both  the  fard  and  the  wajib  admit  of  divine 
pardon. 

(3)  The  acts  which  are  not  obligatory  to  the  degree  of 
being  fard  or  wajib,  and  whose  commission  is  still  re- 
warded and  is  preferable  to  their  omission,  though  the 
latter  does  not  entail  divine  punishment,  are  said  to  be 
(a)  sunnah,1  if  they  are  the  way  habitually  followed  in  the 
religion  (al-tanqah  al-maslukah  fi  'l-din},  namely,  if  they 
are  acts  that  were  performed  by  the  Prophet  habitually.2 
According  to  the  Hanifites,  sunnah,  unless  there  is  an  in- 
dication to  the  contrary  (al-sunnah  al-mutlaqah) ,  may  mean 
habitual  acts  performed  by  both  the  Prophet  and  the  Com- 
panions, but  al-Shafi'i  held  that  it  can  only  mean  acts  per- 
formed by  the  Prophet.3  The  sunnah  is  of  two  kinds: 
sunnat-al-huda,  also  called  al-sunnah  al-mu'akkadah,  such 
as  the  adhan  (calling  the  public  to  prayer)  and  jamd'ah 
(prayer  in  public  under  the  leadership  of  an  imam),  whose 
omission  is  evil  and  abominable  (makruh)  ;  and  sunnat-al- 
zawa'id,  such  as  the  personal  ways  of  the  Prophet  in  dress- 
ing, walking,  and  sitting,  whose  omission  is  not  abominable. 
According  to  the  Technical  Dictionary,*  Sadr-al-sharl'ah 
classed  as  sunnat-al-huda  the  Prophetic  acts  pertaining  to 

1  Sunnah  in  this  sense  must  not  be  confused  with  sunnah  in  the  sense 
of  one  of  the  four  bases  of  nqh.  Sunnah  in  the  latter  sense  may  and 
does  include  prescriptions  of  every  category. 

'  Cf.  Pazdawi,  p.  628. 

8  Tawfch,  p.  566;  Tech.  Diet.,  p.  704;  Pazdawi,  p.  630. 

4  P.  70S. 


II4  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [424 

worship  ('ibadah),  and  as  sunnat-al-zawa'id,  those  not  so 
pertaining  to  worship  (fadah) .  Sunnah,  as  will  be  observed 
from  the  above,  applies  primarily  to  acts  performed  in  the 
process  of  worship  ('ibadah).  This  explains  the  fact  that 
some  held  sunnah  to  mean  that  which  is  supererogatory  in 
worship.1 

(b)  They  are  said  to  be  nafl,  if  they  are  acts  that 
the  Prophet  performed  at  one  time  and  omitted  at 
another  time.  The  nafl  is  less  obligatory  than  the 
sunnat-al-zawaid,  and  like  sunnah,  nail,  too,  applies  pri- 
marily to  acts  of  worship,  that  are  supererogatory, 
namely,  acts  of  worship  that  are  neither  ford,  nor  wajib, 
nor  sunnah.  Nail  is  also  used  in  the  more  general  sense 
of  acts  of  worship  that  are  neither  fard,  nor  wajib, 
and  in  this  sense  it  includes  sunnah.  An  example  of  the 
nail  is  to  perform  more  prostrations  in  the  prayer,  or  to  give 
more  than  the  legal  rate  of  zakat.  The  omission  of  the 
nail  is  not  abominable.  The  nail  is  also  called  mandub, 
tatawwu'  and  mustahabb,  and  the  quality  of  an  act  being 
mandub  or  mustahabb  is  called  nadb,  or  istihbab,  re- 
spectively. 

(4)  The   mubah,   or  ja'iz,   or  halal    (the   indifferent) 
is  the  act  whose  commission  is  not  rewarded  but  whose  omis- 
sion is  not  punished. 

(5)  The  makruh  (abominable,  odious)  is  the  act  whose 
omission    is    preferable    to    its    commission.       It    is    of 
two  kinds:  (i)  The  makruh  karahat=al=tanzih  (that  which 
has  been  considered  abominable  for  purposes  of  keeping 
pure).     This  kind  is  nearer  to  the  mubah  than  to  the  next 
category,  that  is,  its  commission  is  not  punished  but  its 
omission  is  rewarded  though  by  a  lower  reward  than  that 
of  the  next  category.      (2)  The  makruh  karahat=al=tahrim 

1  Tech.  Diet.,  ibid. 


425]      CLASSIFICATION  OF  THE  SHARI'AH  VALUES      n5 

(abominable  to  the  degree  of  prohibition).  This  kind  is 
nearer  to  the  haram,  that  is,  its  commission  results  in  de- 
privation of  the  privilege  of  intercession  and  in  other 
disadvantages,  excepting  punishment  in  fire.  Muhammad 
Ibn  al-Hasan  considers  this  kind  as  identical  with  the 
following  one.  In  his  view,  an  act  is  haram,  whose  omis- 
sion is  based  on  evidence  of  which  there  is  no  doubt,  other- 
wise it  is  makruh  karahat-al-tahrim.1 

(6)  The  haram,  (prohibited)  or  mahziir,  is  the  act  whose 
commission  is  punished  and  omission  rewarded. 

The  rigor  of  the  above  prescriptions  is  subject,  as  already 
hinted,  to  the  softening  influence  of  the  rukhsah,  which 
according  to  Ibn  'Abbas,  is  an  alms  of  God  which  one  must 
not  refuse.2  For  instance,  if  a  Mohammedan  is  compelled 
to  deny  his  faith,  he  is  permitted  to  do  so,  although  the 
'azimah  would  be  for  him  to  persist  in  his  faith  until  death. 
The  excuse  in  this  case  is  the  right  of  a  person  to 
live.  In  certain  cases,  it  is  even  obligatory  to  make  use  of 
the  benefit  of  rukhsah,  while  in  others  it  is  only  commend- 
able (mandub)  or  indifferent  (mubah).  An  example  of 
the  first  case  would  be  to  eat  a  dead  corpse,  when  on  the 
point  of  starvation.  An  example  of  the  second,  would  be 
to  reduce  the  length  of  prayer  during  a  journey,  and  of  the 
third,  to  break  fast  while  journeying. 

With  reference  to  the  performance  of  the  preceding  vari- 
ous categories  of  prescriptions,  the  following  distinctions 
have  made  made  : 

(1)  Ada'  is  the  performance  of  the  obligation  per  se 
((ayn),  whether  or  not  a  time  has  been  specified  in  the  re- 
vealed sources  for  its  performance. 

(2)  Qada*  is  the  performance  of  a  similar  (mithl)  obli- 


p.  566. 
1  Goldziher,  d.  Zahiriten,  pp.  68-9. 


ZI6  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [426 

gation,  instead  of  the  identical  obligation,  as  in  the  first 
case.  The  above  is  according  to  the  Hanifites.  The 
Shafiites  use  these  terms  only  in  regard  to  the  performance 
of  prescriptions  for  whose  obligation  a  time  limit  has  been 
specified.  They  mean  by  ada'  the  performance  of  the  obli- 
gation at  the  time  set  for  it,  qada'  being  its  performance 
after  such  time.  Moreover,  they  distinguish  a  third  kind, 
i'adah  (repetition),  which  means  a  second  performance  of 
the  obligation  at  its  set  time,  the  first  performance  having 
been  non-valid  for  some  reason  or  other. 


CHAPTER  IX 

IjTIHAD  OR  THE  EXERCISE  OF  INDEPENDENT  THOUGHT  a 

THE  word  ijtihad  means  literally  the  exertion  of  great  ef- 
forts in  order  to  do  a  thing.  Technically  it  is  defined  as  "the 
putting  forth  of  every  effort  in  order  to  determine  with  a 
degree  of  probability  a  question  of  shari'ah."  It  follows 
from  the  definition  that  a  person  would  not  be  exercising 
ijtihad  if  he  arrived  at  an  opinion  while  he  felt  that  he  could 
exert  himself  still  more  in  the  investigation  he  is  carrying 
out.  This  restriction,  if  conformed  to,  would  mean  the 
realization  of  the  utmost  degree  of  thoroughness.  By  ex- 
tension, ijtihad  also  means  the  opinion  rendered.  The  per- 
son exercising  ijtihad  is  called  mujtahid,  and  the  question 
he  is  considering  is  called  mujtahad-flh. 

It  becomes  clear  from  the  definition,  that  the  mujtahad- 
fih  must  be  a  question  of  shari'ah.  In  other  words,  intel- 
lectual problems,  such  as  the  createdness  (hudiith)  of  the 
universe,  the  existence  of  a  Creator,  the  sending  of  pro- 
phets, etc.,  cannot  properly  constitute  a  subject  of  ijtihad, 
because  in  these  there  is  only  one  correct  view,  and  all  hold- 
ing a  different  view  are  wrong.  Furthermore,  the  subject 
of  ijtihad  must  not  be  one  on  which  there  is  positive 
evidence  (dalil  qat'i).  Consequently,  one  may  not  exer- 
cise ijtihad  on  matters  such  as  the  wujub  (obligation)  of 
the  "  pillars  of  faith  "  (e.  g.,  the  performance  of  the  five 
prayers  or  the  giving  of  sakat),  or  such  as  the  prohibition 
of  adultery,  murder,  wine-drinking,  usury,  theft.  These  are 
evident  truths  of  the  shari'ah,  based  on  explicit  statements 

1  Kashf,  p.  1134;  Tawfcb,  p.  554;  Taqrir,  vol.  Hi,  p.  291. 
427]  117 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [428 

(nass),  and  concerning  them  the  whole  Moslem  community 
is  of  one  opinion  (ijma().  A  wrong  ijtihad  concerning 
such  questions  would  be  outright  sin,  "  and  we  are  con- 
cerned here  with  the  kind  of  ijtihad  where  wrong  opinion 
does  not  entail  sin."  In  other  words,  the  person  who  is 
qualified  to  be  a  mujtahid  may  exercise  ijtihad  only  in  re- 
gard to  questions  on  which  there  is  no  positive  evidence.  In 
such  cases  he  may  be  right  or  wrong,  but,  should  he  be 
wrong,  he  is  not  considered  a  sinner.  On  the  contrary, 
"  he  is  excused  and  rewarded,  since  his  obligation  is  only 
to  exert  himself,  and  this  he  has  already  done,  but  he 
could  not  reach  the  truth  on  account  of  the  obscurity  of  its 
evidences."  2  If  the  mujtahid  is  wrong  notwithstanding 
the  fact  that  the  evidence  is  clear  he  is  not  excused,  for 
obviously  he  is  wrong  "  by  reason  of  a  fault  of  his,  and  be- 
cause he  did  not  do  his  best  in  exerting  himself,  and  there- 
fore he  is  punished."  !  As  regards  the  mujtahid  who  is 
wrong  in  the  fundamentals  of  religion,  his  failure  may  be  a 
case  of  simple  error  (dalal)  or  of  unbelief  (kufr).  Some 
claim  that  error  in  the  fundamentals  of  religion  does  not 
entail  sin. 

According  to  al-Mawardi,  the  scope  of  ijtihad  after  the 
Prophet's  death  includes  eight  separate  heads.  Seven  of 
these  consist  in  the  interpretation  of  the  revealed  texts,  by 
some  method  such  as  analogy,  and  the  eighth  is  the  deriva- 
tion of  a  meaning  from  other  than  the  revealed  texts,  e.  g., 
by  reasoning.  A  few  of  the  rules  concerning  ijtihad  are 
as  follows: 

The  mujtahid  is  under  a  "  personal  obligation  "  (fard 
fayn)  to  exercise  ijtihad  in  regard  to  matters  concerning 

1  Gazali,  vol.  ii,  p.  354. 

1  Talwih,  p.  560. 

8  Ibid.,  cf.  also,  Gazali,  vol.  ii,  p.  357  ',  Tawdlh,  p.  559. 


429]          EXERCISE  OF  INDEPENDENT  THOUGHT 

himself,  for  in  such  matters  he  is  not  allowed  to  follow 
(taqlid)  the  opinion  of  others. 

A  mujtahid  is  likewise  under  a  "  personal  obligation  "  to 
exercise  ijtihad  for  others  when  the  matter  does  not  admit 
of  delay. 

When  a  person  asks  for  the  opinion  of  a  mujtahid  in 
order  to  meet  a  situation,  the  exercise  of  ijtihad  concerning 
that  situation  becomes  a  fard  kifayah  obligation  upon  all  the 
mujtahids,  and  especially  the  mujtahid  whose  opinion  was 
requested.  When  any  one  of  these  mujtahids  renders  an 
opinion  upon  the  matter,  the  rest  are  absolved  from  the 
obligation,  but  if,  notwithstanding  the  clearness  of  the 
question,  they  all  refrain  from  rendering  an  opinion,  they 
all  become  sinners.  They  are,  however,  excused  if  the 
question  is  ambiguous,  but  in  such  cases  they  must  continue 
their  investigation  until  they  solve  it. 

When  the  mujtahid  is  asked  to  give  his  opinion  on  a  case 
that  has  not  as  yet  occurred,  or  when  he  considers  such  a 
case  of  his  own  accord,  the  obligation  to  render  the  opinion 
is  not  of  the  fard  but  only  of  the  mandub  category. 

The  mujtahid  is  not  allowed  to  change  his  opinion  con- 
cerning the  same  case,  although  he  may  render  a  new  and 
different  opinion  in  the  future  concerning  an  identical  case. 

The  conditions  pertaining  to  the  mujtahid  are  the  fol- 
lowing: The  mujtahid  must  know  many  sciences  and  have 
many  attainments.  He  must  know  the  sciences  of  Koran, 
its  legal  and  literal  meanings,  its  divisions,  and,  some  say, 
he  must  remember  even  the  textual  words,  though  others 
claim  that  the  ability  to  trace  them  is  sufficient.  He  must 
know  the  science  of  the  sunnah,  the  ways  of  its  transmis- 
sion,1 the  texts  and  meanings  (if  transmitted  in  meaning), 

1  Al-Taftazani  says  that  owing  to  the  great  distance  of  time  it  is  now 
impossible  to  know  all  about  the  transmitters  and  that  therefore  it  is 
enough  to  rely  on  /ia</i//i-collections  like  that  of  al-Bukhari  (Talwih, 
P.  555). 


I2Q  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [430 

the  logical  values  of  the  terms,  whether  they  are  universals 
or  particulars,  etc.  Finally  he  must  know  the  laws  of  qiyas 
and  ijma',  etc.  Yet  all  this  is  not  enough.  The  mujtahid 
must  possess  a  perfect  character.  He  must  be  "  just,"  a 
man  of  good  faith  and  right  intentions,  and  truthful.  These 
virtues  are  not  presumed  to  exist  in  a  person  who  merely 
believes  in  the  religious  truths ;  he  must  practise  them.  He 
is  assumed  to  practise  them  when  he  does  not  commit  capital 
sins  (kabirah),  when  he  fulfils  his  religious  duties,  and 
when  he  does  not  persist  in  the  commission  of  venial  sins 
(sagirah).  Therefore  the  person  who  does  not  practise  his 
religious  duties,  although  he  may  believe  in  them  (fasiq), 
may  not  be  a  mujtahid.  The  man  whose  thoughts  are 
tainted  by  heresy  (bid'ah)  is  also  excluded,  for  heresy 
would  warrant  a  presumption  of  injustice.  In  short,  only 
the  person  who  is  learned,  pious  and  orthodox,  may  be  a 
mujtahid.1  A  detailed  statement  of  all  these  requirements 
given  by  al-Gazali  constitutes  a  formidable  array  of  sciences 
and  practices,  but  dogmatic  theology  is  not  included  in  them. 
It  must  be  kept  in  mind  that  a  combination  of  all  these 
virtues  is  necessary  only  for  the  person  who  intends  to  be  a 
full  mujtahid  (mujtahid  mutlaq,  or  mujtahid  fi  'l-sharlfah) 
i.  e.,  a  mujtahid  who  may  express  an  opinion  on  every 
question  of  the  shari'ah.  Hence,  one  is  allowed  to  enter 
the  rank  of  mujtahids  (mansab  al-ijtihad),  although  one  has 
mastered  only  a  part  of  the  required  sciences,  provided  that 
one  exercises  ijtihad  only  on  questions  falling  within  that 
part.  For  instance,  if  one  knows  only  the  laws  of  qiyas, 
though  he  may  not  know  the  science  of  the  sunnah,  or  if  he 
knows  only  the  subject  of  inheritance,  he  may  form  an 
opinion  on  points  included  in  the  field  known  to  him,  since 
it  is  not  necessary  for  the  jurisconsult  (mufti)  to  be  able 

1  Cf.  Ostrorog,  p.  48. 


43 1  ]          EXERCISE  OF  INDEPENDENT  THOUGHT  I2i 

to  answer  every  question.  Thus  it  is  related  of  Malik  that 
he  was  asked  forty  questions  concerning  thirty-six  of  which 
he  answered :  "I  do  not  know."  Similarly,  the  Com- 
panions and  all  the  great  mujtahids  have  not  answered 
every  question  that  was  put  to  them.  However,  some  doc- 
tors have  questioned  the  legitimacy  of  the  "  splitting " 
(tajazzi)  of  ijtihad,  that  is  whether  a  person  should  be  al- 
lowed to  reach  independent  opinions  within  the  branch  of 
fiqh  which  he  has  mastered,  if  he  is  not  acquainted  with  the 
entire  subject  of  fiqh.1 

The  majority  hold  that  the  limited  mujtahid  is  not  en- 
titled to  independence  of  opinion  outside  of  his  specialty 
and  like  the  muqallids  must  apply  to  a  mujtahid  for  an 
opinion  on  such  matters.  This  applies  only  in  case  the 
"  splitting  "  of  ijtihad  is  granted  to  be  legitimate ;  in  the 
contrary  case,  the  limited  mujtahid  must  rely  on  the  opinion 
of  the  full  mujtahid  even  on  points  falling  within  his  own 
specialty.2 

The  legal  effect  (hukm)  of  ijtihad  is  that  the  opinion 
rendered  is  probably  right,  though  there  is  the  possibility 
of  error.  Therefore,  ijtihad  in  the  fundamentals  of  reli- 
gion has  been  forbidden.  One  sect,  the  Mu'tazilites,  hold 
that  ijtihad  is  always  right. 

According  to  the  degree  of  independence  and  scope  of 
research  which  the  mujtahids  have  shown,  they  have  been 
classified  by  later  Hanifite 3  doctors  in  the  following 
groups : 

(i)  The  full  mujtahid  (mujtahid  fi  'l-shar').  The 
mujtahids  of  this  type  have  established  a  legal  system 

1  It  will  be  noted  that  this  dispute  is  another  form  of  the  time-hon- 
ored   argument   over   the    relative    values   of    general    education   and 
specialization. 

2  Taqrir,  vol.  iii,  p.  344- 

*  Ibn  'Abidin,  pp.  1 1  et  seq. 


122  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [432 

(madh-hab)  of  their  own  and  are  called  founders  of  schools 
(sahib  madh-hab).  Abu  Hanifah,  al-Shafi'i,  Malik,  and 
Ahmad  Ibn  Hanbal  belong  in  this  group.  Each  of  these 
has  originated  a  different  system  of  usul-al-fiqh. 

(2)  The  mujtahids  "within  the  school"   (mujtahid  fi 
'l-madh-hab).     These  are  the  disciples  of  the  former,  like 
Abu  Yusuf,  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  Zufar,  etc.      They 
have  determined  the  law  in  the  particular  cases   (furuf), 
applying  the  principles  (usul)  established  by  their  master, 
and  have  at  times  disagreed  with  him  in  the  particular  ap- 
plications of  the  law  but  never  in  the  principles. 

(3)  The  "  mujtahids  on  particular  questions  "  (mujtahid 
fi  'l-masa'il),  like  al-Khassaf,  Abu  Ja'far  al-Tahawi,  Abu 
'1-Hasan  al-Karkhi,  Shams-al-a'immah  al-Halwani,  Shams- 
al-a'immah  al-Sarakhsi,  Fakhr-al-islam  al-Pazdawi,  Fakhr- 
al-din  Qadikhan.     These  have  not  opposed  the  founder  of 
the  school,  either  in  the  principles  or  in  the  particular  appli- 
cations (furu')  of  the  principles,  but  have  contented  them- 
selves with  determining  the  law  in  regard  to  particular  cases 
which  the  former  had  left  undetermined,  using,  however, 
the  principles  established  by  the  former.     All  the  preceding 
three  classes  have  been  called  mujtahids,  but  the  following 
four  are  usually  denominated  as  muqallids,  muqallid  being 
the  opposite  of  mujtahid. 

(4)  The  so  called  "ashab  al  takhrij,"  like  al-Razi,  etc. 
These  are  not  able  to  form  ijtihad,  but,  being  well-con- 
versant with  the  principles  and  the  particular  applications 
decided  by  the  former,  indicate  which  view  is  correct  in 
cases  of  ambiguity  or  contradiction. 

(5)  The  so-called  "ashab  al-tarjih,"  like  Abu  '1-Hasan 
al-Quduri  and  the  author  of  the  Hidayah.     These,  when 
there  are  several  views  on  the  same  point,  indicate  which  is 
the  correct  view,  by  means  of  the  use  of  some  such  expres- 
sion as  "this  is  correct"   (sahlh),  or  "the  fatwa  is  ren- 
dered according  to  this  view  "  (falayhi  al-fatwa). 


EXERCISE  OF  INDEPENDENT  THOUGHT  123 

(6)  The  doctors  who  can  distinguish  between  the  weak 
and  the  strong,  the  reliable  (zahir-al-riwayah)  and  the  un- 
reliable, etc.     They  are  the  authors  of  "  the  esteemed  texts  " 
(al-mutiin  al-mu'tabarah),  like  the  Kanz,  the  Mukhtar,  the 
Wiqayah,  and  the  Majma'.     They  include  in  their  books 
only  the  views  that  have  been  considered  reliable. 

(7)  the  class  of  the  muqallids  who  lack  the  powers  of 
the  preceding  and  "  do  not  distinguish  between  the  lean  and 
the  fat,  right  and  left,  but  on  the  contrary  get  together 
whatever  they  find." 

It  must  be  remarked  here  that  this  classification  appar- 
ently is  not  intended  by  the  doctors  to  indicate  merely  that 
tlu-  mujtahids  have  been  classed  in  this  or  that  group  be- 
cause they  have  shown  only  that  much  independence  of 
thought,  for  it  implies  a  gratuitous  assumption  that  the 
later  mujtahids  could  not  show  greater  independence  of 
thought.  This  is  another  symptom  of  that  peculiar  habit 
of  mind  which  resulted  in  the  fiction  which  has  been  termed 
by  the  Moslem  doctors  "  the  closing  of  the  door  of  ijtihad  " 
(insidad  bab  al-ijtihad).  This  fiction  consists  in  the  belief 
that  after  the  era  of  the  full  mujtahids  (mujtahid  mutlaq) 
who  founded  the  schools,  no  more  mujtahids  of  that  calibre 
appeared,  and  according  to  some  there  is  not  even  the  pos- 
sibility that  such  might  appear.1 

This  belief,  which  is  a  later  development,  is  partly  due 
to  the  fact  that  the  founders  of  the  schools  were  men  of 
great  ability  and  thoroughness  who  had  practically  ex- 
hausted the  various  logical  alternatives  which  offered  them- 
selves for  speculation  within  the  limitations  set  by  the 
revealed  texts.  The  later  doctors  had  many  views  to 
choose  from,  but  there  was  little  to  add.  They,  therefore, 
seized  upon  the  existing  material  and  elaborated  it,  filling 

1  Juynboll,  p.  34,  fn. ;  cf.  Taqrir,  vol.  iii,  pp.  339-4O. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [434 

in  the  gaps  left  by  the  masters.  By  far  the  most  important 
factor,  however,  in  bringing  about  this  acquiescence  with 
what  was  said  and  done  by  the  previous  generations,  and  in 
bringing  about  this  voluntary  surrender  of  independence 
of  thought,  must  have  been  the  fact  that,  after  the  crystal- 
lization of  the  various  conflicting  views  into  distinct  systems 
and  schools  and  the  acceptance  of  the  same  by  the  majority 
of  society,  the  future  trend  of  thought  was  then  and  there 
determined  along  existing  lines.  As  time  went  on,  people 
as  a  matter  of  course  ranged  themselves  under  the  banner 
of  the  school  that  was  predominant  in  their  district.  This 
was  especially  true  as,  owing  to  the  doctrine  of  ijmaf,  once 
an  agreement  was  reached  on  a  certain  point,  further  dis- 
cussion of  that  point  was  automatically  barred. 

But,  while  there  is  a  historical  basis  for  this  fiction,  there 
is  no  justification  for  it  in  theory.  Even  those  who  accept 
this  fiction,  will  be  careful  to  indicate  by  their  wording  that 
this  closing  of  ijtihad  is  not  necessitated  by  theory,  but 
merely  is  a  result  of  the  absence  of  full  mujtahids.  Thus 
Haydar  Effendi,  a  modern  Turkish  authority  on  Fiqh,  in 
his  Durar  al-Hukkam?  says  that  the  door  of  ijtihad  was 
not  closed  (sadd)  by  an  external  cause  but  that  it  closed  of 
itself  (insidad)  through  mere  absence  of  mujtahids.  Ac- 
cording to  theory,  the  mujtahid  is  not  only  free  in  his  think- 
ing but  is  bound  to  be  so,  and  there  is  no  a  priori  reason 
why  a  person  today  might  not  be  able  to  combine  in  him- 
self the  necessary  qualities  required  by  the  Mohammedan 
doctors  themselves. 

It  is  not  therefore  a  matter  of  surprise  to  find  among 
earlier  doctors  strong  statements  condemning  this  belief 
and  refuting  it  by  theoretical  arguments.2  For  example, 

1  Vol.  iv,  p.  671. 

2  Shawkani,  p.  235. 


435]          EXERCISE  OF  INDEPENDENT  THOUGHT  ^5 

al-Zarkashi  [tenth  century  of  the  Hijrah],  expressing  great 
astonishment  that  such  a  belief  should  have  arisen  at  all, 
says: 

If  they  [i.  e.,  the  people  entertaining  this  belief]  are  think- 
ing of  their  contemporaries,  it  is  a  fact  that  they  have  had 
contemporaries  like  al-Qaffal,  al-Gazali,  al-Razi,  al-Rafi'i, 
and  others,  all  of  whom  have  been  full  mujtahids}  and  if 
they  mean  by  it  that  their  contemporaries  are  not  endowed 
and  blessed  by  God  with  the  same  perfection,  intellectual 
ability  and  power,  or  understanding,  it  is  absurd  and  a  sign 
of  crass  ignorance;  finally,  if  they  mean  that  the  previous 
writers  had  more  facilities,  while  the  later  writers  had  more 
difficulties,  in  their  way,  it  is  again  nonsense,  for  it  does  not 
require  much  understanding  to  see  that  ijtihad  for  the  later 
doctors  (muta'akhiriln)  is  easier  than  for  the  earlier  doctors. 
Indeed  the  commentaries  on  the  Koran  and  the  sunnah  have 
been  compiled  and  multiplied  to  such  an  extent  that  the 
mujtahid  of  today  has  more  material  for  interpretation  than 
he  needs. 

Similar  views  have  been  expressed  by  al-Shafi'i  and  others.1 
The  writings  of  the  mujtahids,  like  the  mujtahids  them- 
selves, have  been  grouped  by  later  Hanifite  doctors  in  three 
main  classes.2 

(i)  The  so-called  Usul  (bases)  or  Zahir-al-riwayah  (of 
reliable  transmission)  or  Zahir-al-madh-hab  (the  estab- 
lished doctrines  of  the  school).  These  are  the  views  and 
opinions,  of  Abu  Hamfah  and  his  disciples  Abu  Yusuf, 
Muhammad  ibn  al-Hasan,  also  Zufar  and  Hasan  Ibn  Ziyad, 
which  have  been  recorded  in  the  books  called  by  the  same 
name,  i.  e.,  Kutub  Zahir-al-riwayah.  These  books  are  the 
Mabsfit,  the  al-Jamic  al-Kabir,  the  al-Jami{  al-Sagir,  and  the 
al-Siyar  al-Kabir,  all  of  them  written  by  Muhammad  Ibn 
al-Hasan,  Abu  Hanifah's  disciple. 

1  Cf.  also  Ibn  Hazm,  p.  212. 
1  Qadlzadah,  p.  14. 


126  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE  [436 

(2)  The  so-called  al-Nawadir.     These  are  the  views  and 
opinions  of  the  above  doctors  recorded  in  other  than  the 
above   mentioned   books,    such    as    the   al-Klsdniyydt,   al- 
Haruniyyat,  al-Jurjaniyydt,  and  al-Raqqiyyat,  of  the  same 
Muhammad,  the  Amdli  of  Abu  Yusuf ,  the  books  written  by 
Hasan  Ibn  Ziyad,  Zufar,  etc. 

(3)  Finally,   the   Waqi'at,   namely  the   views   of   later 
mujtahids,    like    'Isam-al-din    Ibn    Yusuf,    Ibn    Rustam, 
Muhammad  Ibn  Sama'ah,  Abu  Sulayman  al-Jurjani,  Abu 
Hafs  al-Bukhari,  etc.     The  first  book  of  this  kind  was  the 
Nawazil  of  Abu  '1-Layth  al-Samarqandi.     It  was  followed 
by   al-Natifi's   Kitab   Majmu'   al-Nawazil   wa   'l-Waqi'at. 
Later  writers  compiled  works  in  which  they  put  together 
the  views  contained  in  these  earlier  books.     Qadikhan  is 
one  of  these  writers.    The  best  compendiums  of  the  opinions 
of  the  first  class  (usul)  are  the  Kofi,  and  the  Muntaqa.     A 
commentary  on  the  Kdfi  has  been  written  by  al-Sarakhsi,  in 
a  work  entitled  al-Mabsut.     It  is  a  large  book  in  thirty  parts 
and  has  been  very  extensively  used  in  Part  II.  of  this  study. 

The  opposite  of  mujtahid  is  muqallid  and  of  ijtihad  is 
taqlid.  Taqlid  is  defined  as  the  servile  acceptance  of  an- 
other's opinion  without  evidence.  According  to  this  defini- 
tion everybody  who  is  not  a  mujtahid  would  be  a  muqallid. 
Some  have  held  that  the  name  of  muqallid  applies  only  to  a 
mujtahid  who  follows  the  opinion  of  another  mujtahid,  or 
to  a  layman  who  follows  the  opinion  of  another  layman, 
but  not  to  a  layman  who  follows  the  opinion  of  a  mujtahid, 
because,  these  people  argue,  the  mere  fact  that  the  person 
from  whom  an  opinion  is  requested  is  a  mujtahid  is  con- 
clusive evidence  for  the  layman  who  applies  to  him.  Like- 
wise, they  say,  it  would  not  be  a  case  of  taqlid  to  follow  the 
views  of  the  Prophet.  Shawkani  establishes  a  more  rele- 
vant distinction  when  he  says  that  taqlid  applies  only  in 
case  one  follows  the  opinion  of  another  person,  but  that  it 


437]          EXERCISE  OF  INDEPENDENT  THOUGHT  127 

is  not  a  case  of  taqlid  when  one  applies  to  another  person 
to  determine  a  point  of  fact.  Therefore  it  is  not  taqlid 
if  a  layman  applies  to  a  mujtahid  in  order  to  find  what  the 
law  is  on  a  certain  point. 

The  lowest  scale  in  the  hierarchy  of  intellectual  freedom 
is  occupied  by  the  so-called  'ammis  or  illiterate.  These 
naturally  possess  even  fewer  rights  than  the  muqallids,  for 
while  the  muqallids  can  refer  to  the  law-books  and  ascertain 
the  views  of  the  doctors,  the  'ammis  do  not  even  possess  the 
minimum  of  knowledge  required  for  that,  and  must  apply 
to  the  mujtahids  or  the  muqallids,  if  they  are  in  doubt  con- 
cerning a  point. 

The  process  by  which  the  mass  of  the  illiterate  are  in- 
structed in  law  is  ifta,  which  means  the  act  of  answering  a 
question  concerning  a  point  of  law.  The  act  of  asking  for 
such  an  answer  is  called  istifta  and  the  answer  so  given  is 
called  fatwa  (plural,  fatdwi) .  The  person  giving  the  fatwa 
is  called  mufti  and  the  person  asking  for  it  is  called  mustafti. 

There  has  been  considerable  divergence  of  opinion  as  to 
the  amount  of  learning  a  person  must  possess  in  order  to 
qualify  to  give  fatwas,  but  the  generally  accepted  opinion 
is  that  a  mufti  must  be  a  mujtahid.  A  person  however 
is  allowed  to  give  fatwas  by  quoting  1  the  opinions  of 
others,  provided  he  conforms  to  the  rules  concerning  trans- 
mitters (rawi).2  Such  a  person,  according  to  the  Path, 
when  asked  about  a  point,  must  not  give  his  answer  as  final ; 

1  The  expressions  used  in  the  law-books  to  indicate  that  a  certain 
opinion  is  recommended  by  the  author  of  the  book  for  being  quoted  as 
fatwa  are  the  following:  'alayhi  al- fatwa  (according  to  this  is  the  opin- 
ion rendered)  wa  bihi  yufta  (according  to  this  the  fatwa  is  rendered) ; 
wa  'alayhi  al-'amal  al-yawm  (according  to  this  is  conduct  at  present) 
wa  huwa  al-sahih  or  asahh  (this  is  the  correct  view),  etc. 

1  Path,  vol.  vi,  p.  360 ;  for  full  details  concerning  the  muftis  consult 
'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  iii,  pp.  380  et  seq.\  Bahr,  vol.  vi,  pp.  292  et  seq.-, 
Majnia',  vol,  ii.  p.  120;  Durar,  p.  717;  Durr,  p.  8;  Qadizadah,  p.  16. 


I2g  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE          [438 

for  example,  he  must  not  say,  "  The  answer  of  your  ques- 
tion is  this,"  but  on  the  contrary,  he  must  relate  the  various 
opinions  on  the  point,  as  for  example,  "Abu  Hanifah  said  on 
this  point  so  and  so,"  and  leave  it  to  the  mustafti  to  follow 
the  opinion  that  appeals  to  his  intuition  as  the  correct  one. 
The  author  of  the  Path  here  interjects  the  opinion  that,  al- 
though it  is  advisable  for  the  person  giving  the  fatwa  to 
quote  all  the  opinions  on  the  point,  it  is  not  necessary  to 
do  so,  it  being  permissible  to  mention  only  one  of  them. 
The  same  author  goes  on  to  say  that,  inasmuch  as  the  person 
giving  the  fatwa  is  not  a  mujtahid  but  simply  a  transmitter 
and  narrator,  he  must  see  to  it  that  he  is  quoting  correctly. 
This  last  point  is  considered  to  have  been  insured  if  the 
narrator  knows  the  complete  chain  of  transmitters  from 
himself  back  to  the  original  mufti,  or  quotes  the  fatwa  from 
a  well-known  book  that  is  circulating  in  the  hands  of  the 
public,  such  as  the  books  of  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan. 
According  to  al-Razi,  such  books  are  equivalent  to  a  report 
of  the  mutawatir  or  mash-hur  type.  If,  however,  at  the 
present  time  there  should  be  only  a  few  copies  of  a  rare 
manuscript  in  existence,  it  would  not  be  lawful  to  give  a 
fatwa  on  the  basis  of  an  opinion  recorded  in  them,  ascrib- 
ing it  for  example  to  Abu  Yusuf  or  Muhammad  Ibn  al- 
Hasan,  because  these  copies  have  not  attained  wide  circula- 
tion and  reputation  (lam  tashtahir)  in  our  time  and  place. 
It  is  all  right,  however,  if  these  opinions  have  been  quoted 
in  a  well-known  book  like  the  Hidayah  or  the  Mabsut,  since 
it  would  then  be  a  case  of  relying  on  these  latter  books. 

While  the  muftis  who  are  not  mujtahids  have  no  liberty 
of  thought  and  must  simply  quote  others,  the  muftis  who 
are  mujtahids  1  are  conceded  by  the  jurists  the  right  to 
depart  from  the  opinion  of  the  founder  of  the  school,  and, 

1  Strictly  speaking,  the  name  mufti  applies  only  to  the  mujtahids. 


EXERCISE  OF  INDEPENDENT  THOUGHT 

in  general,  to  exercise  independence  of  judgment  as  far  as 
their  learning  will  allow.1  But  almost  as  early  as  the  time 
of  the  disciples  of  Abu  Hanifah,  one  can  detect  the  origin 
of  that  peculiar  state  of  mind  which  gratuitously  assumes 
that  jurists  of  great  calibre  of  mind  are  no  longer  to  be  met 
and  so  it  has  been  the  current  view  for  a  long  time  to 
consider  the  muftis  and  the  judges  as  mere  muqallids  or 
mujtahids  of  the  most  limited  scope  of  research.  Conse- 
quently special  rules  have  been  elaborated  as  to  the  preced- 
ence of  doctors'  opinions  in  giving  a  fatwa  or  rendering  a 
judgment.2 

Special  rules  have  been  established  also  concerning  taqlid 
and  the  duties  of  the  'ammis  (ignorant)  who  have  to  apply 
to  the  muftis  in  order  to  find  out  what  the  law  is.  Refer- 
ence will  here  be  made  only  to  a  few  of  them.  According 
to  Abu  '1-Khattab,  the  duty  of  an  'ammi  *  is  to  apply  to  the 
mujtahid  for  the  solution  of  his  difficulties,  but  he  must  see 
to  it  that  he  applies  to  a  person  whom  he  knows  to  possess 
the  ability  for  that  work,  either  because  the  latter  has  repu- 
tation for  science  or  piety,  or  because  he  has  been  recom- 
mended to  him.  Consequently  he  must  not  apply  to  a  person 
whose  condition  is  unknown  to  him,  although  some  claim 
that  he  may.  Some  hold  that  the  educated  person  is 
obliged  to  follow  the  opinion  of  a  mujtahid  only  when 
he  feels  convinced  about  the  soundness  of  the  latter's  argu- 
ments. It  has  been  a  matter  of  dispute  as  to  whether  in 
intellectual  matters,  that  is  matters  which  are  outside  of  the 
shari'ah  sciences,  taqlid  is  legitimate  or  obligatory.  When 

1  It  will  be  remembered  that  a  mujtahid  need  not  be  of  the  full  rank 
and  that  he  is  bound  to  know  only  as  much  as  he  needs  for  the  deter- 
mining of  the  particular  question  he  is  interested  in. 

•  For  full  details  see  'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  iii,  pp.  383-387;  cf.  al-Fatdwa 
al-Kubra,  vol.  ii,  p.  212. 

8  Majntu',  p.  140. 


I30  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

there  are  two  muftis,  the  'ammi  must  apply  to  the  more 
learned  of  the  two,  although  some  say  that  he  may  apply  to 
either.  When  a  person  asks  for  a  fatwa  from  two  muftis 
he  follows  the  one  whose  opinion  appeals  to  his  intuition  as 
the  more  correct,  although  according  to  the  Path  *  he  may 
also  follow  the  one  whose  opinion  does  not  so  appeal  to 
his  intuition.  For,  he  says,  the  intuition  (may I)  of  the 
ignorant  is  of  no  account.  When  an  'ammi  has  followed 
the  opinion  of  a  mujtahid  on  a  point,  by  unanimous  opinion, 
he  may  not  any  longer  follow  the  opinion  of  another 
mujtahid  on  the  same  point,  though  he  may  do  so  in  a  new 
case. 

There  has  been  discussion  as  to  whether  an  'ammi  should 
follow  a  definite  school 2  in  all  particulars,  some  saying  yes, 
others  saying  no.  The  argument  of  the  latter  is  that  the 
Companions  of  the  Prophet  did  not  blame  people  for  fol- 
lowing opinions  other  than  their  own.  The  first  side  argues 
that  after  the  establishment  of  the  four  schools,  affiliation 
with  one  of  them  is  necessary. 

May  one  in  certain  particulars  depart  from  the  doctrines 
of  the  school  to  which  he  has  pledged  allegiance?  3  Some 
say  he  may,  others  say  he  may  not,  and  still  others  say 
he  may  not  if  he  has  already  acted  according  to  his  own 
school.  Finally,  others  say,  if  the  case  has  already  occurred, 
he  may  not  change,  otherwise,  he  may.  This  last  view  has 
been  followed  by  Imam-al-haramayn.  According  to  al- 

1  Vol.  vi,  p.  360. 
1  Shawkani,  p.  253. 

*  In  the  Taqrlr  (vol.  iii,  p.  351)  it  is  said  that  the  opinion  of  later 
generations  is  that  the  'ammi  cannot  properly  claim  affiliation  with  a 
school  and  say,  "  I  am  a  Hanifite  or  a  Shafiite,"  because  following  a 
certain  school  implies  a  minimum  of  discriminating  intelligence  and 
acquaintance  with  the  literature  of  that  school,  and  the  illiterate  does 
not  possess  even  that  knowledge. 


EXERCISE  OF  INDEPENDENT  THOUGHT  I3i 

Quduri,  he  may  change  his  school  if  he  is  convinced  that  the 
school  he  wants  to  follow  is  stronger  than  his  own  school 
in  regard  to  that  particular  case,  otherwise  he  may  not.  But 
others  say  he  may  change  if  the  new  school  is  not  less 
rigorous  than  his  own  school;  and,  according  to  others,  he 
may  change  if  the  new  school  pleases  him  better,  and  he 
does  not  do  it  merely  for  fun,  provided,  however,  that  by 
so  changing  he  is  not  setting  at  nought  what  he  has  already 
done  in  accordance  with  his  school.  However,  in  the 
opinion  of  some,  one  becomes  impious  (fasiq)  by  picking 
out  from  each  school  what  is  most  agreeable  to  him,  for 
example,  the  drinking  of  nabidh  (a  kind  of  wine)  from  the 
school  of  'Iraq,  temporary  marriage  (mut'ah)  from  that 
of  Mecca,  etc.  The  author  of  the  Taqrir  sees  no  objection 
to  this  practice. 

It  will  readily  be  seen  that  notwithstanding  the  minute 
dispositions  that  we  have  been  briefly  examining,  there 
are  often  cases  where  the  believer  may  be  at  a  loss 
as  to  what  is  the  right  thing  for  him  to  do.  For  example, 
when  a  person  has  asked  for  a  fatwa  from  two  muftis,  how 
is  he  to  tell  which  one  of  the  two  he  must  follow?  Or, 
supposing  that  he  is  in  the  wilderness  and  wants  to  pray, 
but  does  not  know  in  which  direction  Mecca  lies  (qiblah), 
how  can  he  satisfy  his  conscience  that  he  has  performed  his 
religious  duties  completely?  These  difficulties  are  removed 
by  the  process  of  taharri.1 

Taharri 2  technically  means  the  determination  of  a  fact, 
which  it  is  impossible  to  ascertain,  by  means  of  intuitive 
conviction.  A  person  is  said  to  resort  to  taharri  when  he 
turns  to  his  heart,  that  is,  to  his  intuitive  faculty  in  order 

1 ' Alatnkiriyyah,  vol.  v,  p.  569;  Mabsuf,  vol.  x,  p.  185;  Ja'mi',  p.  133. 

1  Some  jurists  restrict  the  use  of  the  word  taharri  to  questions  of  re- 
ligious ritual  ('ibdddt)  and  use  the  word  tawakh-khi  concerning  civil 
transactions  (mu'dntaldt). 


I32  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

to  find  the  truth.  Resort  to  this  method  is  allowed  when 
the  thing  desired  to  be  known  is  involved  in  doubt  (shakk)? 
and  other  evidence  is  not  available,  since  in  such  a  case  it  is 
the  only  means  of  getting  at  the  truth.  The  legal  effect 
(hukm)  of  taharri  is  that  action  based  upon  it  is  valid 
(sawab)  in  the  eyes  of  the  shari'ah.  The  application  of  the 
principle  of  taharri  concerning  the  payment  of  zakat  will 
be  seen  in  Part  II. 

1  The  jurists  define  doubt  (shakk)  as  the  state  of  mind  in  which 
knowledge  and  ignorance  just  balance  each  other,  and,  on  the  other 
hand,  they  mean  by  gann  (presumption)  the  case  in  which  the  side  of 
knowledge  overbalances  ignorance,  though  without  any  evidence  in 
its  support. 


CHAPTER  X 
THE  FIQH  SCHOOLS  AND  THEIR  FOUNDERS 

THE  violent  discussions  which  raged  in  the  early  period  of 
Islam  in  regard  to  religious  and  legal  questions  such  as  the 
use  of  qiyas,  or  political  issues  like  the  calif  ate,  resulted  in 
groupings  along  certain  lines.  The  groupings  along  the 
line  of  fiqh,  have  been  the  ones  which  have  received  most 
recognition  and  adherence.  Consequently  they  have  been 
practically  the  only  groupings  to  spread  and  survive  to  our 
own  day,  and  are  known  as  the  fiqh  madh-habs  or  schools. 
The  differences  between  these  schools,  although  they  pri- 
marily relate  to  matters  of  law,  are  by  no  means  confined 
to  them,  since  they  bear  on  subjects  as  far  apart  as  meta- 
physics and  politics.  In  fact,  they  relate  to  all  the  various 
subjects  on  which  the  shari'ah  has  had  something  to  say, 
namely  to  every  matter  which  in  those  times  excited  hu- 
man interest. 

The  most  important  of  the  fiqh  schools  have  been  the  ones 
founded  by  Abu  Hanifah,  Malik,  al-Shafi'i,  Ahmad  Ibn 
Hanbal,  Dawiid  Ibn  'AH,  al-Awza'i,  Sufyan  al-Thawri,  and 
Abu  Thawr.  Each  one  of  these  is  considered  a  full  mujta- 
hid,  and  is  supposed  to  have  had  his  own  system  of 
theory  and  applications  of  fiqh.  They  have  all  been  reck- 
oned as  orthodox  and  they  have  considered  one  another  as 
such.  They  are  to  be  distinguished  from  the  so-called 
Shiites  and  Kharijites,  etc.,  who  are  looked  down  upon  by 
the  former  as  heretical. 

133 


I34  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

According  to  al-Bagdadi,1  the  origin  of  this  distinction 
between  orthodoxy  and  heresy  is  based  among  other  things 
on  the  following  statement  of  the  Prophet : 

"  Verily,  it  shall  happen  to  my  community  (ummah)  what 
happened  to  the  sons  of  Israel.  The  sons  of  Israel  split 
up  into  72  sects,  and  my  community  shall  split  up  into  73 
sects,  namely,  one  more  than  their  sects;  all  of  these  sects 
shall  go  into  the  Fire  excepting  one  single  sect."  They  said : 
"  Oh  Prophet  of  God,  which  is  the  one  sect  that  will  stay 
away  from  the  Fire  ?"  He  replied :  "The  sect  in  which  I  and 
my  Companions  have  belonged." 

The  test  of  orthodoxy  then  is  to  hold  the  same  views  as  the 
Companions.  Using  this  test,  al-Bagdadi  says  2  that  in  his 
days  only  the  faqihs  and  theologians  who  belonged  in  the 
so-called  orthodox  body  (ahl  al-sunnah  wa  'l-jam&eah) 
could  be  considered  as  living  in  accordance  with  the  Com- 
panions, and  that  the  remaining  such  as  the  Rafidites, 
Qadarites,  and  Kharijites,  were  heretical. 

The  content  of  orthodoxy,  as  explained  by  the  same 
author  in  a  long  chapter,3  consists  in  agreement  on  1 5  heads 
or  "  pillars,"  as  he  terms  them.  Each  of  these  "  pillars  " 
must  be  understood  by  every  adult  person  of  mature  under- 
standing. These  "  pillars "  include  fundamental  (ustil) 
and  secondary  (furuf)  questions.  On  the  fundamental 
questions,  he  says,  all  the  orthodox  Moslems  have  been  at 
one,  though  they  have  differed  on  the  secondary;  but,  he 
adds,  their  differences  have  not  been  in  the  nature  of 
error  (dalal)  or  impiety  (fisq). 

These  fifteen  pillars  embrace  a  wide  range  of  subjects: 
among  others,  questions  of  metaphysics,  such  as  matter, 

1  PP.  4-5. 

8  P.  304. 

9  Pp.  309  et  seq. 


THE  FIQH  SCHOOLS  AND  THEIR  FOUNDERS 

accidents  and  essences ;  dogmatic  theology,  such  as  the  exist- 
ence, unity,  attributes  and  names  of  God,  the  createdness  of 
the  universe,  the  prophets,  and  their  miracles ;  worship,  such 
as  the  observation  of  the  five  "  pillars  "  of  Islam;  fiqh; 
public  law,  such  as  the  question  of  the  calif  ate,  etc.  Those 
who  do  not  believe  in  the  above  al-Bagdadi  would  consider 
as  outside  of  the  orthodox  body,  though  they  may  still  be 
Moslems. 

Who  is  called  a  Moslem?  According  to  al-Bagdadi  * 
this  question  has  been  variously  answered.  Some  said, 
every  person  who  believes  in  Mohammed  as  a  prophet  be- 
longs in  the  Moslem  community  (millat  al-islam).  The 
Karamites  said, — every  person  who  says,  "  There  is  no  God 
but  God,  and  Mohammed  is  the  prophet  of  God  "  is  a 
Moslem.  Still  others  said, — every  person  is  a  Moslem,  who 
believes  in  the  five  prayers  and  in  their  being  said  with 
the  face  turned  toward  Mecca.  Al-Bagdadi,  however, 
would  call  a  person  Moslem,  only  if  he  believed  in  the 
createdness  of  the  universe,  the  unity,  eternity,  justice  and 
wisdom  of  its  Creator,  and  would  not  liken  others  to  God, 
nor  deny  any  of  His  attributes;  believed  in  the  prophecy 
and  mission  of  all  the  prophets,  and  in  the  truth  of  the 
prophecy  of  Mohammed,  as  well  as  in  his  mission  to  all 
nations;  believed  in  his  teachings  and  the  Koran  as  the 
source  of  divine  revelation;  finally,  if  he  believed  in  the 
obligation  of  the  five  prayers,  the  giving  of  zakat,  the  fast 
of  Ramadan,  and  the  pilgrimage  to  Mecca.  The  person 
who  observes  all  the  above  is  a  Moslem;  if  he  furthermore 
abstains  from  any  heresy  (bid'ah)  that  involves  unbelief, 
he  is  a  Sunnite  (orthodox)  Moslem.  If  on  the  contrary, 
he  commits  a  heresy,  one  of  these  two  cases  is  possible: 
( i )  The  heresy  is  of  the  nature  committed  by  the  Batinites, 

1  Pp.  220223. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Bayanites,    Mugirites,    Mansurites,    Janahites,    Sabbabites, 
or   Khattabites    (subdivisions   of   the   Rafidites) ;   or   the 
Hululites;  or  those  who  believe  in  the  transmigration  of 
souls;  or  the  Maymunites  or  Yazidites  (both  subdivisions  of 
the  Kharijites)  ;  or  the  Haitites  or  Himarites  (subdivisions 
of  the  Qadarites)  ;  or  it  consists  in  the  prohibition  of  what 
the  Koran  permitted  by  name,  and  vice  versa.      In  such 
cases  he  does  not  belong  in  the  Moslem  community  (millat 
al-islam).     (2)  His  heresy  is  of  the  nature  committed  by 
the  Zaydites  and  Imamites  (subdivisions  of  the  Rafidites)  ; 
or  most  of  the  Kharijites;  or  the  Mu'tazilites,  Najjarites, 
Jahmites,  Dirarites,  and  Mujassimites.     In  this  case  he  is 
considered  a  Moslem  in  certain  respects,  but  is  considered 
to  be  outside  of  the  Moslem  community  in  other  respects. 
For  example,  like  other  Moslems,  he  is  buried  in  the  Moslem 
cemetery,  he  receives  a  share  in  the  spoils  of  war,  and  he 
may  enter  a  Moslem  mosque  to  pray  in  it.     However,  it  is 
not  allowed  to  a  Sunnite  Moslem  to  pray  over  his  dead  body, 
nor  to  pray  under  his  leadership  (al-saldt  khalfahu),  nor 
to  eat  his  sacrifice;  neither  may  a  Sunnite  marry  women 
of  his  sect,  or  offer  him  a  Sunnite  woman  in  marriage.     In 
brief,  al-Bagdadi,  distinguishes  three  classes  of  Moslems, 
the   Moslems  who  are   Sunnites,   those  who  are  merely 
Moslems,  and  finally  those  who  are  Moslems  only  in  name, 
but  not  in  reality,  such  as  the  Maymunites  and  Hululites. 
Al-Bagdadi  includes  the  former  two  classes  in  the  list  which 
he  made  out  to  bring  the  number  of  sects  in  the  Moham- 
medan community  up  to  73,  but  he  excludes  from  the  list 
the  third  class  of  nominal  Moslems. 

According  to  the  Technical  Dictionary*  the  Prophet  de- 
fined Islam  as  consisting  in  the  observance  of  "  the  five 
pillars,"  namely,  the  testimony  that  there  is  no  God  but 

*P.  696. 


THE  FIQH  SCHOOLS  AND  THEIR  FOUNDERS 

God  and  that  Mohammed  is  his  Prophet,  the  five  prayers, 
the  zakat,  the  fasting  during  the  month  of  Ramadan,  and 
the  pilgrimage  to  Mecca.  In  other  words,  Islam  is  the 
external  submission,  and  differs  from  iman  (faith)  which 
means  the  internal  submission.  This  distinction  is  also 
acknowledged  by  al-Bukhari,  though  there  are  those  who 
have  considered  the  two  terms  synonymous.  The  opposite 
of  iman  is  kufr,  meaning  unbelief.  According  to  the  view 
that  Iman  means  internal  submission  only,  kufr,  or  unbe- 
lief, would  not  exclude  a  person  from  Islam.  The  ma- 
jority of  faqlhs  and  theologians  are  agreed  that  Moslems 
do  not  become  unbelievers  (kafir)  by  erring  in  the  funda- 
mentals of  religion  (usul  al-dln),  that  is,  in  dogma. 
When  a  Moslem  errs  in  other  than  dogma,  if  he  can  justify 
his  opinion  by  some  evidence  (burhan),  he  is  saved  (naji)  ; 
and  even  if  he  bases  his  opinion  on  the  erroneous  view  of 
another  person  (taqlld)  he  is  still  saved,  according  to  the 
majority  view.  According  to  one  opinion,  Moslems  are  al- 
lowed to  call  other  Moslems  kafirs  by  way  of  retaliation  for 
the  same  insult. 

The  reason  why  certain  groups  of  Moslems  have  been 
considered  as  heretical  is  not  because  they  differed  in  the  ap- 
plication or  even  the  theory  of  fiqh,  since  the  orthodox  sects 
will  be  found  to  differ  among  themselves  almost  as  much. 
It  is  mainly  because  of  differences  on  theological  and  poli- 
tical issues,  for  these  were  the  principal  issues  which  led 
to  their  secession  from  the  main  body  of  Moslems.1  It 
goes  without  saying  that  the  heretical  Moslems  have  their 
own  legal  systems,2  but  they  do  not  interest  us  here  because 
we  shall  be  concerned  only  with  the  orthodox  doctrines. 

The  differences  between  the  various  orthodox  schools, 

1  Goldziher,  Vorlesungen,  pp.  237-239. 
1  Cf.  Juynboll,  pp.  31-32. 


!38  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

as  already  anticipated  in  the  chapters  on  Ijma'  and  Ijtihad, 
relate  chiefly  to  the  applications  of  fiqh,  for  we  have  seen 
that  in  the  theory  of  fiqh  (usul-al-fiqh)  they  practically  all 
follow  the  same  principles.  Al-Sha'rani  has  likened  the 
several  orthodox  schools  to  so  many  roads,  all  leading  to 
the  same  goal.  Thus  they  have  never  called  one  another 
heretical  (kafir),  and  they  usually  allow  a  shifting  of  alle- 
giance from  one  orthodox  school  to  another.  Of  the  many 
schools,  which  existed,  only  six,  all  of  them  orthodox,  have 
been  able  to  obtain  a  following.  They  are  known  as  the 
six  "  followed  "  (matbufah)  schools,  and  are  the  Hanifite, 
Malikite,  Shafiite,  Hanbalite,  and  those  of  al-Thawri  and 
Dawud.  The  first  four  are  the  ones  which  have  had  the 
largest  following  and  have  survived  to  our  own  day;  the 
last  two  could  not  survive  beyond  the  seventh  century  of 
the  Hijrah.  The  rest  of  the  orthodox  schools  have  had 
little  or  no  following.  Here  are  the  most  important  of 
the  orthodox  schools. 

The  Hanifites.  The  founder  of  this  school  is  Abu 
Han  if  ah  Na'man  Ibn  Thabit  (80/699-1  so/767).1  His  grand- 
father was  brought  from  Persia  to  Kufah  as  a  slave  and 
later  obtained  his  freedom.  According  to  the  historian 
Ibn  Khallikan,1  Abu  Hanifah  was  born  early  enough  to 
have  met  with  four  of  the  Companions,  namely,  Anas  Ibn 
Malik,  'Abdallah  Ibn  Aw  fa  who  resided  at  Kufah,  and  two 
others,  but  that  he  never  saw  them  nor  obtained  from  any  of 
them  traditions  respecting  the  Prophet.  His  disciples  have 
claimed  the  contrary.  According  to  the  same  author,  Ja'far 
Ibn  Rabi'ah  said  that  he  had  attended  the  lessons  of  Abu 
Hanifah  during  five  years  and  never  met  a  man  who  would 
remain  silent  as  long  as  he ;  but  that  when  he  was  questioned 

1  This  notation  signifies  the  dates  80-150  Hijrah  and  690-767  A.  D. 
8  Vol.  iii,  p.  556. 


THE  FIQH  SCHOOLS  AND  THEIR  FOUNDERS       139 

on  [a  point  of]  jurisprudence  he  would  launch  out  into  a  flux 
of  words,  copious  as  a  torrent.  Also  that  in  the  art  of  draw- 
ing conclusions  from  analogies  (qiyas)  he  was  a  master 
of  the  highest  rank.1  Abu  Hanifah  was  a  man  of  inde- 
pendent means  and  perfect  character.  He  devoted  his  life 
to  the  study  of  religion  and  law,  delivering  lectures  in  Kufah 
to  his  private  circle  of  students.  His  opinion  on  legal  mat- 
ters was  universally  sought  after.  He  left  no  works  ex- 
cept a  small  book  on  dogmatics  and  belief  called  al-Fiqh 
al-Akbar.  His  so-called  Musnad  has  been  compiled  by  one 
of  his  students  and  contains  the  hadiths  used  by  the  master. 
It  was  Abu  Hanifah  who  occasioned  the  famous  con- 
troversy  regarding  the  use  of  opinion  (ra'y)  in  legislation, 
and  this  activity  on  his  part  brought  upon  him  bitter  at- 
tacks. The  charge  made  by  his  enemies  was  that  he  em- 
phasized the  speculative  elements  at  the  cost  of  the  hadiths, 
whereas  his  disciples  rightly  maintained  that  he  used  qiyds 
only  when  he  could  not  find  a  provision  in  the  hadiths.  The 
truth  is  that  "Abu  Hanifah  did  not  constitute  an  exception 
in  the  use  of  qiyas  but  that  they  all  acted  alike."  x  We 
have  already  seen  in  the  chapter  on  Qiyas  how  much  truth 
there  was  in  the  allegation  that  qiyas  meant  the  introduction 
of  the  use  of  ra'y,  on  the  contrary,  qiyas  curbed  the  inor- 
dinate and  lawless  use  of  ra'y,  as  it  was  then  practised  on  all 
sides.  It  is  true  that  Abu  Hanifah  also  introduced  the 
principle  of  istihsan  which  was  really  a  case  of  using  ra'y, 
but  all  the  schools  were  guilty  of  that  practice.  The  only 
difference  between  Abu  Hanifah  and  the  rest  was  that  Abu 
Hanifah  was  conscious  of  what  he  was  doing  and  was 
not  afraid  of  openly  admitting  it,  while  the  others  did  the 
same  thing  in  a  more  or  less  concealed  way.  The  work 

1  Ibid.,  vol.  iii,  p.  559. 

'  Luknawi,  Introduction,  p.  27 ;  Mizdn,  p.  54,  1.  10. 


I40  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

of  Hanifah  can  hardly  be  over-estimated,  for  he  made  the 
first  attempt  to  codify  the  Mohammedan  law,  using  qiyas 
as  one  of  his  bases.  In  doing  this  Abu  Hanifah  incidentally 
evolved  a  theory  of  law  (usul-al-fiqh)  for  the  first  time. 
Abu  Hanifah's  work  was  supplemented  and  completed  by 
his  intimate  circle  of  disciples  especially  Abu  Yusuf,  and 
Muhammad  Ibn-al-Hasan. 

Abu  Yusuf,  Ya'qub  Ibn  Ibrahim,  ( 1 13/731-182/799),  was 
by  far  the  most  important  disciple  of  Abu  Hanifah.  He 
was  the  one  who  wrote  out  the  principles  laid  down  by 
the  master  x  and  occupied  in  relation  to  him  a  position  very 
similar  to  that  which  Plato  did  in  relation  to  Socrates.  Abu 
Yusuf  held  office  as  Chief  Justice  in  Bagdad  under  the  well- 
known  calif  Harun-al-rashid,  who  sought  his  advice  on  the 
most  important  affairs  of  state.  In  answer  to  certain  ques- 
tions of  the  Calif  concerning  taxation,  and  other  matters 
of  public  law,  Abu  Yusuf  wrote  his  famous  Kitab  al-Kharaj, 
a  valuable  essay  on  those  subjects. 

Imam  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  al-Shaybani  (135/752- 
189/804-5)  was  the  younger  of  the  two  disciples  but  by  far 
the  keener.  Ibn  Khallikan  *  says  the  following : 

When  the  imam  as-Shafi  went  to  Bagdad,  Muhammad  Ibn 
al-Hasan  was  there,  and  they  both  met  frequently  and  dis- 
cussed points  of  law  in  the  presence  of  Harun-ar-Rashid. 
Al-Shafi'i  was  (afterwards)  heard  to  say :  "  I  never  saw  a 
person  who,  when  questioned  on  a  point  which  required  re- 
flection, did  not  betray  some  uneasiness  by  his  countenance ; 
but  I  must  except  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan."  He  said 
again :  "  The  information  which  I  learned  by  heart  from 
Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  would  suffice  to  load  a  camel." 

1  It  is  stated  in  the  Mizdn  (p.  48)  that  when  Abu  Hanifah  decided  a 
point  of  law  and  all  the  doctors  of  his  city  were  agreed  upon  it,  he 
said  to  Abu  Yusuf,  "  Write  it  down  ". 

1  Vol.  ii,  p.  590. 


THE  FIQH  SCHOOLS  AND  THEIR  FOUNDERS       i4I 

Muhammad  compiled  the  applications  of  the  principles  laid 
down  by  the  master  into  a  corpus  juris,  which  served  as  a 
basis  for  many  future  books  on  the  applications  of  fiqh,  and 
the  commentaries,  and  constitutes  the  most  authoritative 
source-book  for  the  Hanifite  doctrines. 

The  Hanifite  school  is  one  of  the  most,  if  not  the  most, 
important  of  the  four  orthodox  schools,  and  counts  many 
adherents.  It  owes  its  reputation  mainly  to  the  Ottoman 
Turks,  who  have  officially  adopted  it.  It  has  followers  also 
in  other  lands  where  Turkish  influence  prevails.  Further- 
more it  has  spread  in  Central  Asia,  Turkestan,  Bukhara, 
Samarqand,  and  Hindustan.  The  Hanifite  principles  are, 
by  far  the  most  humanitarian  of  all,  concerning  the  treat- 
ment of  non-Moslems,  war  captives,  slaves,  the  law  of 
retaliation,  etc. 

The  Malikites.  This  is  the  school  founded  by  Malik 
Ibn  Anas  (95/713-4-179/795)  of  Medina.  Malik  was  con- 
sidered as  a  representative  of  the  hadith-tolk,  notwithstand- 
ing the  fact  that  he,  too,  used  qiyas,  although  perhaps  to  a 
less  extent  than  Abu  Hanifah.  This  is  borne  out  by  an 
examination  of  his  collection  of  hadiths,  called  al-MuwattS,' ', 
the  first  orderly  collection  of  law,  where  Malik  based  his 
legal  decisions  partly  on  his  personal  opinion.  Notice  this 
statement  by  'Abdallah  Ibn  Qa'nab.1 

I  went  to  Malik  Ibn  Anas,  in  his  last  illness  and  saluted 
him ;  I  then  sat  down  and,  perceiving  that  he  wept,  I  said : 
"O  Abu  'Abdallah;  what  maketh  thee  weep?"  and  he 
answered,  "  O  Ibn  Qa'nab,  why  should  I  not  weep  ?  By 
Allah!  I  wish  I  had  been  flogged  and  reflogged  for  every 
question  of  law  on  which  I  pronounced  an  opinion  founded 
on  my  own  private  judgment." 

Having  lived  and  acted  in  the  city  of  Medina,  the  home  of 

1  Ibn  Khallikan,  vol.  ii,  p.  548. 


I42  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  hadith-lore,  Malik  occupies  a  conspicuous  place  in  the 
teaching  of  hadiths.  Thus  it  is  stated  in  the  Tah-dhib  1 
that  according  to  al-Bukhari,  the  most  reliable  chain  of 
transmission  is,  'Malik,  from  Nafi',  from  Ibn  'Omar/  but 
according  to  Abu  Mansur  al-Tamimi  it  is  '  al-Shafi'i,  from 
Malik,  from  Nafi',  from  Ibn  'Omar,  from  the  Prophet/ 
Malik's  teachers  were  Nafi',  a  client  of  Ibn  'Omar,  Muham- 
mad Ibn  al-Munkadir,  Abu  '1-Zubayr,  al-Zuhri,  'Abdallah 
Ibn  Dinar,  Abu  Hazim.  Malik  had  many  disciples  who 
taught  hadiths  on  his  authority,  among  others,  al-Awza'i, 
Al-Thawri,  Ibn  'Uyaynah,  Al-Layth  Ibn  Sa'd,  Ibn  al- 
Mubarak  and  al-Shafi'i.  Malik  was  well-versed  in  the  study 
of  the  Koran  and  the  sunnah,  and  served  as  official  juris- 
consult (mufti).  This  last  circumstance  may  explain  the  fact 
that  Malik  was  the  first  one  to  break  away  from  the  purely 
casuistic  practices  of  his  predecessors  and  to  attempt  to  for- 
mulate the  principles  underlying  the  hadiths  and  the  customs 
of  Medina,  and  to  arrange  them  topically.  The  very  name 
of  Muwatta',  which  he  gave  to  his  book,  suggests  the  nature 
of  the  work  done.  The  word  means  that  which  has  been 
made  smooth,  even. 

The  school  of  Malik  naturally  found  much  favor  in  his 
native  city  of  Medina  and  in  the  western  part  of  the 
Mohammedan  world,  namely,  in  Morocco,  Algeria,  and 
Tunis,  as  well  as  in  the  so-called  Magrib  (meaning  West), 
which  included  Spain,  when  that  country  was  under  Mo- 
hammedan rule;  also  in  the  other  parts  of  Africa  where 
Islam  had  already  been  accepted,  and  in  upper  Egypt,  where 
at  present  it  has  many  followers. 

The  Shafiites.  This  school  was  founded  by  al-Shafi'i, 
Muhammad  Ibn  Idris  (150/767-204/820).  He  was  born 
in  Gaza  and  he  died  in  Old  Cairo.  He  taught  in  Bagdad  for 

1  P.  53i. 


THE  FIQH  SCHOOLS  AND  THEIR  FOUNDERS       143 

time  and  later  in  Egypt.  The  Mohammedans  consider 
al-Shafi'i,  as  the  vindicator  par  excellence  of  the  hadiths, 
although  to  the  impartial  critic  this  view  does  not  seem  quite 
well  founded,  if  it  is  to  mean  that  he  did  not  use  ra'y  at 
all.  In  fact  the  difference  between  Abu  Hanifah  and  al- 
Shafi'i  was  more  in  appearance  than  in  reality.  Al-Shafi'i 
freely  admitted  the  lawfulness  of  the  use  of  qiyas  and,  as 
we  have  already  seen,  his  method  of  determining  the  "  ef- 
fective "  cause  for  purposes  of  qiyas  was  looser  than  that 
of  Abu  Hanifah.  It  is  true  that  al-Shafi'i  objected  to  the 
principle  of  istihsan  introduced  by  Abu  Hanifah,  but  he  him- 
self introduced  the  principle  of  istishdb  which,  supplemented 
by  the  greater  liberty  of  action  afforded  by  his  looser 
method  in  qiyas,  would  be  as  effective  a  means  of  introduc- 
ing personal  opinion  as  the  istihsan  of  Abu  Hanifah.  But 
this  is  true  only  as  a  theoretical  statement,  because  it  may  be 
fairly  said  that  in  practice  al-Shafi'i  preserved  more  faith- 
fully the  spirit  of  the  hadiths  and  used  them  more  exten- 
sively. It  is  easy  to  understand  why  it  should  be  so,  if  it  is 
remembered  that  al-Shafi'i  was  of  pure  Arab  origin  and 
studied  fiqh  in  Mecca,  and  in  Medina  under  Malik,  the  cham- 
pion of  the  hadlth-lore.  The  following  quotation  from  the 
Risalah  *  will  well  illustrate  his  tendency  to  hark  back : 

God  has  not  given  it  to  any  one  after  the  death  of  the  Pro- 
phet to  express  opinion  except  on  the  authority  of  the  knowl- 
edge ((ilm)  that  came  before  him,  and  such  knowledge  con- 
sists in  the  Book,  the  sunnah,  the  ijmdf ,  and  the  sayings  and 
doings  (athar)  of  the  Companions,  and  then,  as  I  have  ex- 
plained, in  qiyas  upon  the  basis  of  the  preceding,  and  it  is 
not  allowed  to  any  one  to  use  qiyas  until  he  has  learned  what 
has  occurred  before  him  in  the  way  of  practices  (sunan) 
and  sayings  of  the  predecessors,  and  the  ijma's  and  differ- 
ences of  the  people,  as  well  as  the  Arabic  language. 

1  P.  70. 


I44  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Al-Shafi'i  was  very  brilliant,  and,  according  to  Ibn  Khal- 
likan,1  he 

stood  unrivalled  by  his  abundant  merits  and  illustrious  quali- 
ties ;  to  the  knowledge  of  all  the  sciences  connected  with  the 
book  of  God,  the  Sunnah,  the  sayings  of  the  Companions, 
their  history,  the  conflicting  opinions  of  the  learned,  etc., 
he  united  a  deep  acquaintance  with  the  language  of  the  Arabs 
of  the  Desert,  philology,  grammar,  and  poetry ;  .  .  . 

Ahmad  Ibn  Hanbal,  one  of  al-ShafiTs  disciples,  is  quoted 
as  saying,  "  al-Shafi'i  was  to  mankind,  what  the  sun  is  to 
the  world,  and  health  to  the  body;  what  can  replace  them?" 

In  contrast  to  Abu  Hanifah  who  was  of  a  scholastic  type 
of  mind  and  liked  hypothetical  speculation,  al-Shafi'i  was 
rather  averse  to,  and  probably  not  so  skilful  in  subtle  dis- 
tinctions, and  therefore  relied  on  the  revealed  sources  when- 
ever he  could  find  in  them  the  desired  provisions.  The 
following  verses  composed  by  al-Shafi'i  bear  this  out :  "  The 
more  experience  instructs  me,  the  more  I  see  the  weakness 
of  my  reason;  and  the  more  I  increase  my  knowledge, 
the  more  I  learn  the  extent  of  my  ignorance."  2 

In  short,  al-Shafi'i  was  an  eclectic, 

who  came  when  the  law  books  were  already  completed  into 
elaborate  systems,  and  the  laws  sifted  and  laid  down  in  a 
hard  and  fast  way.  He  studied  the  schools  of  the  fore- 
runners and  learned  from  the  most  prominent  doctors;  he 
disputed  with  the  ablest  and  profoundest  and  examined 
their  teachings,  and  later  on  worked  out  from  them  a  method 
which  combined  the  Book,  the  sunnah,  the  ijrna',  and  the 
qiyas,  and  so  he  did  not  confine  himself  to  one  or  the  other 
of  these  sources,  as  was  the  case  with  others.3 

1  Vol.  ii,  p.  569. 

1  Ibid.,  vol.  ii,  p.  572. 
•  Tah-dhlb,  p.  62. 


THE  FIQH  SCHOOLS  AND  THEIR  FOUNDERS 


145 


The  above  quotation  from  a  disciple  of  al-Shafi'i,  al- 
Nawawi,  although  somewhat  exaggerated,  gives  a  good  idea 
of  the  work  done  by  al-Shafi'i. 

The  avowed  object  of  al-Shafi'i  was  to  reconcile  fiqh 
and  tradition,  and  to  those  concerned  he  seemed  to  have  suc- 
ceeded in  doing  this  (jama'ahu  bayn  al-fiqh  wa  'l-sunnah). 
This  explains  the  circumstance  that  when  al-Shafi'i  appeared 
in  Bagdad,  there  followed  a  rapid  conversion  to  his  school. 
The  most  prominent  disciples  and  followers  of  al-Shafi'i 
were  Ahmad  Ibn  Hanbal,  Abu  '1-Thawr,  al-Za'farani,  al- 
Tabari,  al-Mawardi,  Imam-al-haramayn,  and  others. 

According  to  the  Tah-dhib  l  al-Shafi'i  wrote  113  works 
bearing  on  interpretation  (tafslr),  fiqh,  literature,  etc.  The 
works  relating  to  fiqh  are,  the  Risalah,  the  Kitab  al-Umm, 
the  two  /ami's  and  Mukhtasars  of  Muzani,  the  Mukhtasar 
of  Rabi',  etc.  The  most  renowned  commentaries  upon  al- 
Shafi'i's  writings  are  the  Ta'liqs  of  Abu  Hamid  al-Isfara'ini, 
al-Tabari,  and  al-Mawardi. 

At  present,  the  followers  of  this  school  are  found  in  the 
Strait  settlements,  the  Malayan  districts  of  Siam,  the  coast 
of  Hindustan,  (Malabar  and  Coromandel),  in  Southern 
Arabia,  especially  in  Hadramut,  in  Bahrayn,  on  the  Persian 
Gulf,  in  certain  Central  Asian  districts,  in  Dagistan,  and  in 
the  German  East-African  colonies.  Finally,  some  Moham- 
medans in  Syria  follow  the  Shafiite  doctrines  in  the  field  of 
private  life  only.  This  is  also  true  of  those  found  in  Arabia 
and  Egypt. 

The  Hanbalites.  This  is  the  school  founded  by  Ahmad 
Ibn  Hanbal  (164/780241/855).  Ahmad  was  a  disciple 
of  al-Shafi'i  and,  next  to  Dawud  al-Zahiri,  he  was  the 
staunchest  opponent  of  the  ra'y-iolk.  He  makes  use  of 
qiyas  very  little,  and  bases  his  system  mainly  on  the  sacred 

1  P.  67. 


I46  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

texts.  He  is  uncritical  in  the  selection  of  his  hadiths,  of 
which  he  compiled  about  28,000  in  his  Musnad.  He  was 
a  very  conservative  theologian,  and  got  into  trouble  on 
that  account.  His  followers  are  found  now  in  Central 
Arabia,  the  inland  districts  of  'Oman,  and  on  the  Persian 
Gulf.  The  others  are  few  in  number  and  are  scattered  in 
out-of-the-way  localities,  in  a  number  of  Central-Asian 
cities,  and  in  the  country  populations  of  some  isolated  Syrian 
villages.1 

The  Z ah i rites.  This  is  the  school  founded  by  Dawud 
Ibn  'AH  (1270/883-4),  who  threw  qiyas  overboard  and 
adhered  to  the  letter  (al-zahir)  of  the  Koran  and  the 
hadiths,  hence  his  name  al-zahiri.  His  school  at  one  time 
spread  westward  as  far  as  Spain,  when  that  country  was 
under  the  Mohammedans,  but  at  present  it  boasts  no 
adherents.2 

AI-Awza'i,  'Abd-al-rahman  Ibn  'Amr  Abu  'Amr,  born  in 
Baalbek,  (88/757-157/774)  was  another  founder  of  a 
school.  He  was  reputed  for  his  ascetic  tendencies  and  good 
character,  and  was  called  the  Imam  of  Syria.  He  had  fol- 
lowers even  in  Magrib,  before  it  went  over  to  the  school  of 
Malik.  Among  his  contemporaries  were  Sufyan,  Malik, 
Ibn  al-Mubarak,  and  others.  According  to  Hiql,  who  was 
the  most  reliable  of  the  persons  who  quoted  al-Awza'i,  the 
latter  decided  10,000  and  according  to  another  version,  80,- 
ooo  legal  questions."  'Abd-al-rahman  Ibn  Mahdi  said :  "The 
imams  of  hadlth  are  four,  al-Awza'i,  Malik,  Sufyan  al- 
Thawri,  and  Hammad  Ibn  Zayd." 

AI-Thawri,  Abu  'Abdallah  Sufyan  Ibn  Sa'id  of  Kufah 
was  another  full  mujtahid.  Among  those  who  quoted  him 

1  Juynboll,  p.  29 ;  Kremer,  p.  499. 

'Juynboll,  p.  25;  Goldziher,  d.  Zahiriten,  p.  27;  Kremer,  p.  500. 

»  Tah-dhlb,  p.  384- 


THE  F1QH  SCHOOLS  AND  THEIR  FOUNDERS 

were,  Malik,  al-Awza'i,  and  others.  He  was  well-known 
for  his  piety,  and  his  thorough  knowledge  of  the  hadiths. 
Thus  Abu  'Asim  said:  "Al-Thawri  is  the  Commander  of 
the  Believers  in  the  matter  of  hadiths."  * 

1  Tah-dhib,  pp.  286-8. 


CHAPTER  XI 
CONCLUDING  REMARKS 

IN  Part  I.  we  have  attempted  to  give  a  comprehensive  view 
of  Mohammedan  law,  as  a  background  for  the  understand- 
ing of  Part  II.,  as  well  as  for  an  intelligent  determination 
of  the  extent  to  which  non-revealed  or  external  elements 
have  gone  into  the  making  of  fiqh  or  Mohammedan  law. 
Thus  in  a  preliminary  chapter  we  saw  that  the  word 
sharfah  was  the  generic  name  given  to  the  ensemble  of 
religious  truths  taught  by  Mohammed;  that  fiqh  was  the 
body  of  legal  prescriptions  concerning  human  conduct  which 
was  derived  from  the  sharl'ah ;  and  finally,  that  usul-al-fiqh 
was  the  connecting  link  between  fiqh  and  sharifah,  since  it 
denoted  the  discipline  which  derived  the  former  from  the 
latter.  In  the  following  chapters  we  examined  the  four 
sources  or  bases  from  which  fiqh  was  derived  by  usul-al-fiqh, 
and  which  were  accepted  by  the  four  most  important  fiqh 
schools.  These  four  sources,  the  reader  will  readily  remem- 
ber, were  the  Koran,  the  sunnah,  the  ijma'  and  the  qiyas.  In 
the  course  of  these  chapters  special  emphasis  was  laid  on  the 
discussion  of  the  rules  concerning  the  transmission  of  the 
sunnah,  and  of  the  principles  regarding  the  investigation  of 
the  reasons  for  the  divine  prescriptions  for  purposes  of 
reasoning  by  analogy.  In  the  next  chapter  we  took  up  the 
question  of  the  relative  importance  of  these  four  sources 
and  the  degree  to  which  they  overruled  one  another.  We 
then  examined  the  principles  of  legislation  accepted  by  only 
one  or  more  schools,  and  we  treated  the  principle  of  istihsan 
or  personal  opinion,  owing  to  its  importance,  in  a  separate 
148 


CONCLUDING  REMARKS 


149 


section.  A  special  chapter  was  devoted  to  a  brief,  though 
comprehensive,  exposition  of  the  various  classes  of  sharl'ah 
values.  We  next  inquired  into  the  principles  governing  the 
exercise  of  independent  thought  (ijtihad)  as  well  as  the 
transmission  of  others'  opinions  and  the  duties  of  the  illiter- 
ate ((ammi)  when  they  want  to  determine  the  law  on  con- 
crete cases.  To  complete  the  discussion,  in  the  last  chapter, 
information  was  given  concerning  the  most  important 
orthodox  schools  of  fiqh  and  the  origin  and  content  of 
orthodoxy. 

A  close  examination  of  the  Mohammedan  legal  system, 
even  if  one  should  confine  himself  to  what  little  of  it  may 
be  learned  from  the  preceding  chapters,  will  at  once  reveal  its 
highly  mechanical  nature.  Like  all  systems  which  lack  the 
evolutionary  outlook  on  life,  it  works  under  the  assumption 
that  social  phenomena,  complex  as  they  are,  may  be  reduced 
to  hard-and-fast  rules  to  which  the  intricate  and  nondescript 
situations  of  real  life  must  fit  themselves  as  best  they  can. 
Under  the  plea  that  reality  (batin)  cannot  be  known  but  to 
God  alone,1  and  that  for  the  purposes  of  law,  the  outward 
signs  (sahir)  of  reality  may  be  treated  as  reality  itself, 
the  latter  is  entirely  lost  sight  of,  and  so  the  whole  discus- 
sion is  carried  on  in  terms  of  the  signs  of  reality  instead  of 
of  reality  itself.  Of  course,  the  signs  correspond  to  reality 
only  in  what  the  statisticians  would  call  the  mode  of  the 
cases,  and  the  chances  of  this  correspondence  become  fewer 
and  fewer  as  one  gets  further  and  further  away  from  the 
initial  premises. 

To  cite  one  instance,  we  saw  that  a  matter  so  subtle  as  the 
exercise  of  independent  thought  (ijtihad)  has  been  reduced 
to  mechanical  laws.  For  example,  the  doctors  have  ruled 
that  one  may  not  exercise  independence  of  thought  until  he 

1  Cf.  Risdlah,  p.  69,  1.  I. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

has  met  certain  requirements.  Of  course  such  a  rule  is  all 
right  in  so  far  as  it  encourages  thoroughness,  but  it  is  fatal 
in  at  least  two  ways:  (i)  it  shuts  off  contributions  likely 
to  come  from  persons  who  have  not  as  yet  met  all  the  re- 
quirements, and  (2)  it  excludes  those  that  might  come  from 
outsiders  who,  being  engaged  in  other  studies,  have  likewise 
failed  to  fulfill  the  requirements.  It  is  the  familiar  case  of 
the  conservative  theologian  who  cries  halt  to  the  scientist 
when  the  latter  "  steps  over  the  line." 

The  most  fatal  consequence  of  a  mechanical  system, 
however,  is  the  excessive  feeling  of  confidence  and  certainty 
into  which  it  lulls  its  adepts.  When  to  all  appearances  the 
complex  and  organic  relationships  of  social  life  have  been 
reduced  to  law  and  order,  one  cannot  help  getting  into  a 
false  sense  of  security  and  optimism.  Such  a  state  of  mind, 
acts  like  a  selective  screen  that  shuts  off  those  stimuli,  which 
if  let  through  might  expose  the  deceptiveness  of  the  appear- 
ances. The  Mohammedan  legal  system  offers  a  good  ex- 
ample of  optimism  carried  too  far.  It  inspires  its  adepts 
with  the  feeling,  that  at  no  point  in  the  process,  from  the 
divine  inception  of  the  law  down  to  the  detailed  legal  pro- 
visions in  the  fiqh-books,  or  to  the  carrying-out  of  these 
provisions  by  the  believers,  is  there  any  weakness  where 
doubt  might  enter.  Thus  to  the  Mohammedans  it  is  a 
matter  of  certainty  that  the  Koran  and  the  sunnah  are 
genuine  expressions  of  the  divine  will.  Of  course  there  is 
a  possibility  that  their  meanings  may  have  been  misunder- 
stood, but  the  believer  need  have  no  misgivings  on  this  point. 
For  if  a  passage  concerning  the  meaning  of  which  there  is 
doubt  is  one  on  which  an  ijmaf  has  been  reached,  certainty 
is  assured  by  that  fact ;  and  if  no  ijma'  has  been  reached,  his 
conscience  may  still  be  set  at  ease  by  resort  to  intuition 
(taharri),  since  the  fact  that  one  of  the  constructions  appeals 
to  the  intuition  is  sufficient  guarantee  of  its  truth.  Finally, 


CONCLUDING  REMARKS  i$i 

if  the  question  were  raised  that  the  law,  although  well  under- 
stood, is  misapplied,  resort  to  intuition  would  again  remove 
all  doubts. 

In  the  light  of  the  above  it  is  easy  to  understand  why  the 
Mohammedan  doctors  claim  with  great  optimism  that  the 
various  bases  used  in  deriving  the  law  from  the  shari'ah, 
may  all  be  reduced  to  the  four  bases  of  fiqh  l  previously 
mentioned,  and  that  the  latter  in  turn  are  based  on  and  jus- 
tified by  the  Koran  and  the  sunnah,  the  two  primary  and 
genuine  sources.  Let  us  now  critically  inquire  how  true 
this  assertion  is  and  how  far  the  primary  sources  are  re- 
vealed, namely,  how  far  they  represent  genuine  records  of 
the  Prophetic  utterances  and  conduct,  and  how  far  the  other 
sources  would  in  theory  exclude  external  and,  especially, 
intellectual  influences.  In  taking  as  our  basis  of  compari- 
son the  revealed  sources  we  must  consider  them  in  their  en- 
tirety, although  it  is  a  fact  that  they  have  gone  through  an 
evolution  considering  that  they  have  reached  their  comple- 
tion only  at  the  death  of  the  Prophet,  that  is,  in  the  course 
of  nearly  a  quarter  of  a  century.  Doubtless  during  this 
long  period  external,  that  is,  non-Arabian  influences,  have 
made  themselves  felt,  but  their  effect  on  the  revealed  sources 
in  the  life-time  of  the  Prophet  has  indeed  been  very  insigni- 
ficant, compared  to  what  it  has  been  on  the  Mohammedan 
law  since  the  Prophet's  death.2  Then  too,  there  is  an  added 
reason  for  taking  as  our  basis  the  revealed  sources  in  their 
entirety,  because  if  we  should  pass  the  natural  limit  afforded 
by  the  death  of  the  Prophet,  we  would  not  know  where  to 
stop,  and  our  inquiry  would  have  to  be  pushed  far  back 
into  preislamic  history.  Viewed  from  this  standpoint,  the 
various  bases  of  fiqh  are  as  follows : 

1  C'f.  Taqrir,  vol.  ii,  p.  212. 

a  In  Part  III.  we  shall  see  to  what  influences  the  revealed  sources  have 
been  subject  as  regards  finance. 


I52  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

The  Koran.  There  is  little  doubt  that  the  Koran  is  on 
the  whole  a  faithful  record  of  the  statements  of  the  Prophet, 
modern  scholars  being  agreed  on  this  point. 

The  Sunnah.  Unfortunately  we  cannot  say  the  same 
thing  concerning  the  sunnah,  not  only  because  it  is  a  mat- 
ter of  historical  record  that  falsification  and  invention  of 
hadiths  were  extensively  practised,  but  also  because,  as  we 
have  seen,  the  rules  concerning  the  transmission  of  the 
sunnah  are  by  no  means  a  sufficient  guarantee  of  its  truth. 
Moreover,  we  know  that  one  did  not  need  to  resort  to  falsi- 
fication to  support  his  claims  when  there  could  be  found 
a  justification  for  them  in  the  sunnah  of  the  Companions, 
since  the  sunnah  of  the  latter  was  almost  as  binding  as 
that  of  the  Prophet.1  It  would  not  therefore  be  too  rash  to 
assume  that  certain  new  elements  have  found  their  way  into 
fiqh  in  the  garb  of  sunnah.  In  this  respect  the  sunnah  of 
the  Companions  acquires  especial  importance  when  we  re- 
call that  the  spread  of  Islam  throughout  Syria,  Mesopo- 
tamia, 'Iraq  and  Egypt  was  completed  in  a  very  short  time 
even  before  many  of  the  Companions  had  died,  for  it  means 
that  most  of  the  new  situations  which  Islam  faced  in  its  ex- 
pansion, received  their  solution  at  the  hands  of  the  Com- 
panions themselves.  Of  course  this  solution,  as  we  shall 
see  later  in  Part  III.,  was  almost  always  in  the  way  of 
sanctioning  the  existing  practices  and  institutions.  In  other 
words,  by  the  time  the  sunnah  reached  its  final  and  settled 
form  in  the  famous  collections  of  al-Bukhari,  Muslim,  and 
others,  many  a  foreign  institution  and  idea  had  already 
found  its  way  into  Mohammedan  law,  either  through  sanc- 
tion by  the  Companions  or  even  through  falsification  of 
the  sunnah. 

The  process  of  absorption  from  outside  and  adaptation 

1  Cf.  supra,  Classification  of  the  Sharl'ah  Values. 


CONCLUDING  REMARKS  153 

to  changing  conditions  inside  by  no  means  stopped  after  the 
crystallization  of  the  sunnah  into  the  famous  hadith-col- 
lections,  as  has  just  been  indicated,  but  went  on  as  before, 
though  this  time  through  the  medium  of  the  remaining 
sources  of  legislation,  such  as  ijma'  and  qiyas. 

The  Ijma'  may  serve  to  introduce  into  the  law  new  ele- 
ments in  two  ways :  ( I )  In  so  far  as  its  constituent  opinions 
consist  in  qiyases,  ijma'  would  naturally  be  as  good  as  qiyas. 
In  fact  it  would  be  somewhat  more  effective  than  qiyas, 
since  the  evidential  force  of  ijma'  is  based  mainly  on  the 
fact  of  the  consensus  rather  than  on  the  merits  of  the  in- 
dividual qiyases.  (2)  Ijma  in  many  cases  would  be  an- 
other form  of  sanctioning  custom.  For  example,  if  one 
doctor  should  express  an  opinion  in  approval  of  a  recent 
custom,  and  the  others  should  keep  silent,  we  would  have 
an  ijma.  Thus  we  know  that  the  legal  institution  of 
istisna'  was  introduced  into  the  law  by  way  of  ijmae. 

Qiyas.  It  is  evident  that  in  matters  of  analogy  the  ques- 
tion whether  or  not  you  are  departing  from  your  proto- 
type, depends  on  whether  or  not  the  basis  of  analogy, 
namely,  the  causal  attribute  (( illah)  is  in  accordance  with 
the  spirit  of  the  prototype.  Even  if  we  should  disregard 
the  extreme  views  relative  to  the  determination  of  this 
'illah  and  confine  ourselves  to  the  orthodox  views,  we  would 
still  find  it  to  be  true  that  they  offered  no  adequate  guaran- 
tee that  in  applying  qiyas  the  revealed  texts  were  not  de- 
parted from.  Take  for  instance  the  prohibition  of  wine- 
drinking.  In  order  to  make  a  qiyas  on  its  basis,  in  the  first 
place,  the  cause  of  the  prohibition  must  be  determined. 
Right  here  there  would  be  an  opportunity  for  displaying  a 
great  deal  of  scholastic  subtlety  whereby  to  determine  as 
cause  exactly  that  attribute  of  wine-drinking  which  would 
best  serve  the  end  in  view.  For  instance,  supposing  that 
there  is  in  the  sources  no  prohibition  against  gambling 


154 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


and  that  we  want  to  bring  this  under  the  prohibition, 
it  would  be  easy  to  do  it  by  considering  as  the  cause  of  pro- 
hibition in  the  case  of  wine-drinking  a  quality  of  the  latter 
which  is  also  common  to  gambling,  for  example,  excite- 
ment. But  there  is  no  need  to  go  to  even  that  much  trouble, 
for  it  is  not  necessary  that  gambling  should  have  precisely 
the  quality  which  was  the  cause  of  prohibition  in  the  case 
of  wine-drinking.  It  is  sufficient  if  gambling  has  a  quality 
which,  while  not  the  very  same  quality,  is  of  the  genus  of 
the  quality  which  was  the  cause  of  prohibiting  wine-drink- 
ing. For  instance,  one  might  say  that  wine-drinking  had 
the  quality  of  causing  drunkenness,  and  gambling,  excite- 
ment, and  that  both  of  them  were  of  the  genus  of  evil,  and 
that  consequently  gambling  came  by  analogy  under  the 
prohibition.  It  is  true  that  the  genus  must  be  a  proximate 
genus,  but  this  does  not  materially  affect  the  situation,  for 
one  might  say  that  the  cause  was  a  genus  of  intellectual  evil, 
in  that  they  both  disturbed  the  mental  processes  temporarily, 
or  that  it  was  a  genus  of  financial  evil,  etc.  Even  this  does 
not  exhaust  the  possibilities,  for  just  as  in  the  case  of  the 
causal  quality  one  may  take  the  proximate  genus  instead 
of  the  very  same  quality,  so  also  in  the  case  of  the  value 
sought  to  be  applied  to  the  new  case,  one  may  apply  a  value 
of  the  same  genus  instead  of  the  identical  value.  Thus 
arguing  that  prohibition  is  a  genus  of  restriction  one  might 
only  restrict  gambling  instead  of  entirely  prohibiting  it, 
as  was  the  case  with  wine-drinking.  It  must  be  admitted 
here  that  the  above  examples  represent  somewhat  strong 
cases,  yet  they  are  by  no  means  exaggerated.  In  general 
one  would  not  have  to  stretch  things  so  far,  for  the  purpose 
in  hand  would  be  much  better  served  by  using  a  more  liberal 
principle  like  istihsdn. 

Istihsan,  taking  it  in  the  sense  used  by  the  Hanifites,  doubt- 
less is  a  more  effective  means  than  qiyds  for  introducing  new 


CONCLUDING  REMARKS  155 

elements,  since  in  its  case  the  rules  for  determining  the 
cause  are  even  subtler  than  in  the  case  of  qiyds,  and  conse- 
quently afford  greater  possibilities.  All  that  is  needed  is  to 
discern  in  the  new  element  whose  introduction  is  desired 
some  quality  that  is  shared  by  a  matter  already  approved  or 
prohibited  by  the  sources  and  the  object  is  achieved. 

The  principle  of  istislah,  made  use  of  by  the  Malikites,  is 
probably  the  most  effective  of  all,  since  it  dispenses  with  the 
necessity  of  rinding  for  its  use  a  justification  in  the  sources. 

Custom,  as  will  be  recalled,  is  another  important  source 
of  legislation,  since  in  matters  which  are  not  mentioned, 
in  the  sources,  according  to  the  Hanifites,  it  is  a  direct 
source  of  law.  To  a  certain  extent  custom  is  a  source 
of  law  even  in  matters  which  are  mentioned  in  the  sources ; 
moreover,  custom  supersedes  the  doctors'  opinions  when 
these  have  been  based  on  custom  and  it  has  meanwhile 
changed.  The  significance  of  this  last  point  will  be  fully 
grasped  when  it  is  remembered  that  the  doctor's  opinions 
are  largely  based  on  custom. 

Space  will  not  be  taken  to  discuss  the  principles  concern- 
ing the  interpretation  of  texts  (tafsir  wa  ta'wll),  since  they 
are  of  slight  importance  in  relation  to  the  question  of  the 
extent  to  which  foreign  influences  may  have  been  allowed 
to  influence  Mohammedan  Law.  Suffice  it  to  say  that  some 
doctors  who  did  not  acknowledge  qiyas  achieved  practically 
the  same  result  through  a  process  which  they  called  inter- 
pretative. 

Without  further  illustrations,  the  preceding  discussion 
proves  beyond  doubt,  that  so  far  as  theory  is  concerned, 
there  was  practically  no  check  to  the  introduction  into  fiqh 
of  foreign  institutions  and  ideas.1  Indeed,  in  Part  III.  we 
shall  find  this  to  have  actually  been  the  case  as  regards 

1  Cf.  Kremer,  pp.  53^-547- 


I56  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

finance  which,  as  we  have  seen  in  Chapter  L,  is  an  integral 
part  of  fiqh.  If,  therefore,  fiqh  has  been  on  the  whole  an 
independent  development,  especially  in  its  later  stages  of 
growth,  it  is  not  because  there  was  a  theoretical  obstacle 
to  non-revealed  external  influences,  but  simply  because  there 
were  not  enough  of  the  latter. 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


THE  following  bibliography  is  intended  for  use  in  the  study  of 
Mohammedan  law  directly  from  the  Arabic  sources,  and,  therefore, 
works  on  the  subject  written  in  European  languages,  as  a  rule,  are  not 
indicated,  since  a  very  good  account  of  them  may  be  obtained  from 
the  works  of  Juynboll  and,  especially,  of  MacDonald.  The  chief  aim 
in  writing  this  bibliography  is  to  give  a  ^>ue  d'ensemble  of  the  litera- 
ture and  to  furnish  prospective  students  with  the  necessary  bearings 
in  approaching  the  vast  subject  of  Mohammedan  law.  To  this  end,  the 
chief  works  written  on  the  different  disciplines  that  make  up,  or  are 
preliminary  to  the  study  of,  Mohammedan  law  have  been  explained; 
works  generally  referred  to  and  quoted  in  the  sources  have  been  indi- 
cated, and,  so  far  as  possible,  the  sources  have  been  presented  in  a 
chronological  order  and  their  nature  briefly  explained.  Although  many 
books  which  are  not  extant  in  printed  or  manuscript  form  have  been  in- 
cluded, the  list  is  by  no  means  exhaustive,  as  the  object  has  been  selec- 
tion rather  than  collection. 

The  Arabic  sources  fall  into  three  fairly  distinguishable  classes:  (a) 
The  so-called  texts  (ma/n)  or  compendiums  (mukhtasar)  ;  (b)  the 
commentaries  (shark)  and  glosses  (hdshiyah,  taqrlr,  ta'liq) ;  (c)  the 
collections  of  legal  opinions  (fatwa).  The  compendiums  give  in  a 
more  or  less  general  way  the  principles  of  law  respecting  concrete 
cases  and  are  intended  to  serve  as  a  basis  of  instruction  and  as  a 
mnemonic  help.  As  a  rule  they  do  not  mention  the  arguments,  and  do 
not  indicate  the  views  of  other  schools.  As  they  are  intended  to  be 
learnt  by  heart  by  the  students,  the  ideal  that  the  writers  of  such  com- 
pendiums set  before  themselves  is  to  make  them  as  brief,  but  also  as 
comprehensive,  as  possible.  Probably  the  Mukhtafar  of  Khalll  has  ap- 
proached this  ideal  more  than  any  other.  Various  devices  are  used  to 
hint,  without  using  more  words,  whether  a  certain  view  was  held  by 
the  founder  of  the  school  (wow)  and  whether  it  is  an  independent 
view  (qawl)  or  merely  an  application  by  analogy  (wajh,  qawl  muk- 
harraj)  of  an  existing  view.  The  persons  responsible  for  a  given  view 
and  the  view  to  be  preferred  out  of  the  many  given  views  are  also 
hinted.  The  Hanifite  usage  in  this  last  respect  is  to  cite  first  the  view 
favored  by  the  writer  of  the  text,  unless  the  text  gives  the  arguments 
also.  In  such  case,  first  the  views  and  then  the  respective  arguments 

157 


I5g  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

are  presented, — the  view  and  argument  favored,  last.  While  on  the 
whole  no  established  usage  has  prevailed  in  this  connection,  in  some  in- 
stances a  fairly  common  understanding  seems  to  have  been  reached. 
A  thorough  study  of  this  subject  would  be  most  helpful  for  the  proper 
understanding  of  the  sources.  Probably  the  chief  distinction  between 
a  commentary  and  a  gloss  is  that  a  gloss  is  more  sketchy  and  goes  into 
questions  of  grammar  and  syntax  more  often  and  more  at  length. 
The  distinction  between  so-called  fatwa  collections  and  works  on  law 
proper  {fiqh),  as  the  words  are  used  by  the  doctors,  is  often  shadowy. 
Thus  the  name  fatwa  collection  is  given  to  works,  such  as  the  'Alam- 
kiriyyah,  which  by  no  means  answer  questions  on  concrete  actual 
cases  but  simply  give  the  legal  principles  on  particular  points  as  deter- 
mined in  the  first  instance  by  early  doctors  or  as  involved  in  existing 
fatwas  on  actual  cases.  These  principles,  however,  are  still  too  general 
to  be  applied  to  actual  cases  without  further  interpretation.  As  it 
is,  the  difference  of  a  work  on  fatwas  from  a  work  on  fiqh  proper 
reduces  itself  to  the  fact  that  the  latter,  besides  being  somewhat  less 
full  as  to  details,  also  gives  the  motives  and  grounds  and  is  meant  to 
furnish  a  more  or  less  scientific  training  whereby  one  might  apply  the 
law  to  new  cases. 

The  statements  occurring  in  the  fiqh  books  of  one  school  concerning 
views  held  in  another  school  are  not  always  accurate  and  must  be  re- 
ceived with  caution.  As  a  rule,  greater  caution  is  needed  in  regard  to 
books  that  may  not  strictly  speaking  be  called  fiqh  books,  such  as  the 
work  of  al-Mawardi,  than  would  be  necessary  for  a  work  on  fiqh 
proper,  such  as  the  Hiddyah  or  the  Minhdj.  Works  of  the  latter  type 
being  an  object  of  constant  study  and  comment  as  well  as  of  actual 
application  have  remained,  relatively  speaking,  immune  from  text  cor- 
ruption. Besides,  it  is  easy  to  correct  any  corruptions  that  may  have 
crept  into  the  text  by  reference  to  the  source  books  of  the  school  on 
which  they  are  invariably  based.  Works  of  the  former  type,  however, 
have  not  had  the  benefit  of  these  corrective  agncies  to  the  same  extent. 

Abbreviations  and  Signs. — Words  printed  in  black-face  type  indicate 
the  titles  under  which  works  have  been  referred  to  in  this  dissertation. 
Words  underlined  indicate  the  shorter  names  by  which  persons  and 
books  are  commonly  referred  to  by  the  doctors.  Dates  in  parentheses 
after  titles  of  books  and  names  of  persons  indicate  years  of  writing 
and  death,  respectively.  Devotional  phrases  such  as  "  May  He  be 
exalted "  or  "  May  God  have  mercy  on  him,"  invariably  used  by  doc- 
tors after  the  mention  of  God,  and  persons  of  note,  have  been  omitted. 
Where  the  volume  has  not  been  indicated,  the  first  volume  is  meant, 
unless  another  volume  has  been  expressly  indicated.  A.  =  Ahmad; 
Ism.  =  Isma'il;  Ibr.  —  Ibrahim;  'Al.  =  'Abdallah;  'Ar.  =  'Abd-al- 
rahman;  'Aq.  =:  'Abd-al-qadir ;  H.  =  Hasan;  Hu.  =  Husayn;  Su.  = 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  159 

Sulayman;  M.  =  Muhammad;  Yu.  =  Yusuf ;  a.  =  Abu  (father  of) ; 
b.  =  Ibn  (son  of)  ;  K.  =  Kitdb.    The  remaining  are  self-explanatory. 

BIOGRAPHICAL 

COMPANIONS  AND  FOLLOWERS :  (1)  Tabaqdt  al-Sahdbah  wa 
'l-Tdbi'in  or  simply  Tabaqdt  b.  Sa'd  by  a.  'AI.  M.  tx  Sa'd  al-Zuhri 
al-Ba§ri  (230).  "The  earliest  and  most  comprehensive"  (Rieu).  (2) 
Al-Ifdbah  A  Tomyiz  al-Sabdbah,  by  Shihab-al-din  a,  '1-Fatfl  A.  b.  'Ali 
b.  Hajar  al-'Asqalani  (852),  the  Shafiite.  Cairo,  1323.  Contains  the 
Istidb  al-Sahdbah  fi  Ma'rifat  al-Afhdb  by  a.  'Amr  Yu.  b.  'Al.  b.  'Abd- 
al-barr  (463),  the  Malikite,  and  the  Usd  al-Gdbah  fi  Ma'rifat  al- 
Sabdbah,  by  'Izz-al-din  a.  '1-H.  'Ali. b.  al-Athlr  (-al-din)  al-Jazari  (630), 
and  more,  in  all  12,279  lives,  omitting  all  but  the  Companions.  Abridged 
by  Jalal-al-din  'Ar.  al-Suyuti  (9")  in  the  'Ayn  al-lsdbah. 

TRUSTWORTHY  REPORTERS  (al-thiqdt)  :  K.  al-Thiqdt —  }yy 
al-Hafiz  a.  Khatim  M.  b.  Hibb&n  al-Busti  (354). 

UNTRUSTWORTHY  REPORTERS  (ruwdt)  :  (1)  Al-Kdmil  fi 
Ma'rifat  al-Du'afd1  wa  'l-Matrukin  min  al-Ruwdt—by  a.  'AL  A.  b.  M. 
b.  'Adi  (365).  Considered  as  standard  by  the  doctors.  Al-Daraqutni 
asked  to  compose  a  work  on  untrustworthy  (du'afa)  reporters,  an- 
swered: "  Do  you  not  have  the  book  of  b.  'Adi?"  "There  is  sufficient 
in  it;  it  cannot  be  augmented."  (H.  Khal.)  The  work  contains  the 
name  of  every  reporter  whose  trustworthiness  was  questioned  even  if 
he  has  already  been  classed  as  reliable  (thiqah).  (2)  Mlzdn  al-I'tiddl 
fi  Naqd  al-Rijal—by  Shams-al-din  a.  'AI.  M.  b.  A.  al-Dhahabi  (748). 
According  to  b.  Hajar,  the  most  comprehensive,  except  that  the  author 
in  order  to  avoid  criticism  omitted  the  names  of  Companions  and  foun- 
ders of  schools  who  obtained  a  following  (H.  Khal.).  Arrangement 
alphabetical.  The  Sahihs,  where  the  hadlths  reported  by  these  untrust- 
worthy reporters  are  cited,  are  hinted. 

REPORTERS  IN  GENERAL:  (1)  The  Tdrikh  —  by  M.  b.  Ism. 
al-Bukhari  (256).  Reporters  grouped  in  classes.  (2)  Al-Kamdl  /» 
Ma'rifat  (or  Asma}  al-Rijdl—by  a.  M.  'Abd-al-gam  b.  Abd-al-wahid 
al-Muqaddasi  (600).  Alphabetical  list  of  the  reporters  mentioned  in 
the  six  Sahihs  with  biographical  notices.  The  Tah-dhib  al-Katndl,  etc., 
is  an  enlargement  by  Jamal-al-din  Yu.  b.  al-Zaki  al-Mizzi  (742).  "This 
is  a  large  work,  to  compose  the  like  of  which  is  believed  impossible"  (H. 
Khal.).  The  work  also  remarks  about  the  reliability  of  the  reporters. 
A  further  abridgment  is  the  Tah-dhib  al-Tah-dhlb  by  b.  Hajar  (852). 
A  still  further  abridgment  by  b.  Hajar  is  the  Taqrib  al-Tahdhib,  with 
additions.  Lith.  Dihli,  1320.  Gives  full  names,  places,  dates  of  death 
and  degrees  of  reliability. 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 

TRADITIONISTS  (Huffdg}  :  Tadhkirat  al-Huffdg—by  Shams-al-din 
M.  b.  A.  al-Dhahabi  (748).  'Haydarabad.  It  gives  lives  of  students 
of  hadlth  whose  function  is  to  decide  whether  a  certain  reporter  is 
reliable,  etc. 

GENERAL— (1)  Tarlkh  'Ulama  al-Andalus,  by  a.  al-Walid  'Al.  b. 
M.  al-Azdi  b.  al-Fara^i  (403).  Ed.  Fr.  Codera,  Bibl.  ar.  hisp.,  vols.  vii- 
viii,  Matriti,  1890.  Gives  briefly  in  alphabetical  order  lives  of  1,642 
doctors,  jurists,  etc.  of  Spain.  Indexes  on  persons,  books  and  places 
appended.  Scanty  in  bibliographical  information.  A  continuation  of 
this  work  is  the  Al-Silah  fi  Akhbdr  A'immat  al-Andalus  (534),  by  a. 
al-Qasim  Khalaf  b.  'Abd-al-malik  b.  Bashkwal  al-Qurtubi  (578).  Ed. 
Fr.  Codera,  Bibl.  ar.  hisp.,  vols.  i-ii,  Matriti,  1883.  (2)  Tdrikh  Bagdad— 
by  a.  Bakr  A.  b.  'AH  al-Khatib  al-Bagdadi  (463).  A  celebrated  exten- 
sive history,  particularly  of  the  learned  men,  of  Bagdad.  (3)  Tabaqdt 
al-Fuqahd\  by  a.  Ishaq  Ibr.  b.  'AH  al-Shirazi  (476),  the  Shafiite.  It 
gives  the  lives  of  the  jurists  among  the  Companions  and  Followers  and 
those  of  the  founders  of  schools  and  their  disciples.  (4)  Bugyat  al- 
Multamis  fi  Tdrikh  A  hi  Rijdl  al-Andalus  (592),  by  a.  Ja'far  A.  b. 
Yahya  al-Dabbi  al-Qurtubi.  A  completion  and  continuation  of  the 
Jadhwat  al-Muqtabis,  etc.  by  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  a.  Na§r  al-Humaydi  (488). 

(5)  Irshad  al-Arlb  ila  Ma'rifat  al-Adlb,  known  as  Mu'jam  al-Udabd' 
or  Tabaqdt  al-Udabd',  by  Yaqut_b.  'Al.  al-IRumi  (626).    E.  J.  W.  Gibb 
Memorial  Series.    Leyden,  1907.    Gives  lives  of  literary  persons,  such 
as  grammarians,  lexicographers,  genealogists,  Koran  readers,  chronicle 
writers,  historians,  copyists,  and  famous  scribes.    Gives  lives  of  jurists 
in  so  far  as  they  have  been  literary  writers,  such  as,  e.  g.,  al-Shafi'i. 

(6)  K.  Wafaydt  al-A'ydn  wa  Anbd'  Abnd'  al-Zamdn — by  Shams-al-din 
A.  b.  M.  b.  Khallikan    (672),  the  Shafiite.     Cairo,   1892,  2  vols.    (b. 
Khali.)   (with  the  Shaqd'iq  on  the  margin).    English  translation  by  M. 
G.  de  Slane  (Ibn  Khallikan)  in  4  vols.    Paris-London,  1843-7.    A  cele- 
brated work  giving  lives  of  persons  of  note  in  every  line.    Omits  Com- 
panions and  early  califs  as  too  well-known.    Alphabetical  with  respect 
to  real  names.    Many  supplements  have  been  written,  among  others  the 
Fawdt  al-Wafaydt  by  M.  b.  Shakir  al-Kutubi    (764),  who  claims  to 
have  also  supplied  omissions  mentioned.     (7)  Tah-dhib  al-Asmd'  wa' 
l-Lugdt — by  a.  Zakariya'  Yahya  b.  Sharaf  al-Nawawi  (676),  the  Shafiite. 
Ed.,  F.  Wustenfeld,  Gottingen,  1849   (first  part  only).     A  very  fre- 
quently  quoted,   useful   work.     First   part    (qism)    gives   the   proper 
names,  and  the  second  part  the  common  names  and  technical  terms 
occurring  in  the  Shafiite  fiqh  books,  Mukhtasar  al-Musani,  Muhadh- 
dhab,  Tanbih,  Wasit,  Wajis,  and  Rawdah.    Alphabetical  with  respect 
to  real  names,  surnames,  etc.,  grouped  in  separate  sections.    The  lives 
given  are  mostly  of  Companions  and  Followers,  with  a  few  of  the 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  l^l 

leading  jurists  of  different  schools,  chiefly  the  Shafnte.  (8)  Al-Nujum 
al-Zdhirah  fi  Muluk  Mi$r  wa  'l-Qdhirah  —  by  Abu  '1-Mahasin  Jamal- 
al-din  Yu.'b.  Tagribirdi  (874).  Ed.  F.  G.  Juynboll,  Lugd.  Batav.,  1855- 
61  (as  far  as  year  365).  Gives  useful  information  in  connection 
with  necrologies.  (9)  Husn  al-Muhadarah  fi  Akhbdr  Mi$r  wa  'l-Qdhi- 
rah— by  Jalal-al-din  al-Suyu|i  (911).  Cairo,  1299.  A  many-sided  his- 
tory of  Egypt,  giving  short  notices  on  the  inujtahids  (pp.  161-88)  and 
jurists  (pp.  224-74)  who  lived  in  Egypt,  with  their  works  mentioned. 
(10)  Nafb  al-Tib  tnin  Gu$n  al-Andalus  al-Ratib  wa  Dhikr  Waslr-ha 
Lisdn-al-din  b.  al-Khafib — by  a.  al-' Abbas  A.  b.  M.  al-Maqqari  al-Tilim- 
sani  (1041),  the  Malikite.  Ed.  R.  Dozy,  etc.,  Leyden,  1855-61.  A  large 
work  giving,  among  other  matter,  lives  of  Spanish  doctors  who  trav- 
eled eastward  and  doctors  who  traveled  to  Spain,  and  mentioning 
names  of  many  books,  with  some  bibliographical  information.  The 
arrangement  of  the  book  follows  no  order.  The  indexes  at  the  end 
unsatisfactory. 

.HANIFITE— (1)  Al-Jawdhir  al-Mutfah,  by  Muhyi-al-din  'Aq.  b.  a. 
al-Wafa'  al-Qurashi  al-Mi§ri  (775).  Contains  many  mistakes  because 
it  is  the  first  work  of  its  kind ;  "  therefore  the  man  should  be  ex- 
cused"  (H.  Khal.).  Supplement:  Al-Guraf  al-Aliyyah  A  Tardjim 
Muta'cikhiri  al-Hanafiyyah,  by  Shams-al-din  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  'AH  b.  Tulun 
(955)-  Contains  about  1,200  lives,  mostly  of  eighth,  ninth  and  tenth 
centuries  (Rieu).  Condensation  by  Ibr.  b.  M.  al-Halabi  (956),  the 
Hanifite,  including  only  jurists  who  left  works  and  whose  names  are 
mentioned  in  the  books.  (2)  Tdj  al-Tardjitn_  £  Tabaqdt  al-Hanafiyyah — 
by  a.  al-Fadl  Zayn-al-millah  wa'l-din  alUQasim  b.  'Al.  b.  Qutlubuga 
(879).  The  work  deals  only  with  jurists  who  left  writings — in  all,  330 
persons.  (8)  Al-Shaqd'iq  al-Nu'mdniyyah  fi  Ulamd'  al-Dawlah  al-'Uth- 
indiiiyyah  —  by  Mawla  A.  b.  Mustafa  Tashkeuprizadeh  (968).  Con- 
stantinople, 1851-2,  with  additions  and  supplements  by  Majdi  and  'Ata'i 
(Fliigel).  Also  printed  on  margin  of  Wafaydt  by  b.  Khallikan.  The 
work  contains  about  600  lives.  It  was  written  in  order  to  save  from 
oblivion  the  doctors  ('ulatnd")  who  lived  and  flourished  in  the  Otto- 
man Empire.  Many  supplements  were  written.  H.  Khal.  speaks  in  the 
highest  terms  of  a  supplement  in  7  vols.  by  Ata'-allah  New'izadeh. 
(4)  Tabaqdt  al-Ulamd'  al-Hanafiyyah,  by  'Ali  Tchelebi  b.  Imru'-allah 
Hzadeh  (979).  Gives  in  brief  lives  of  231  persons,  in  21  classes. 
(•">)  Kataib  A'ldm-al-Akhydr  tnin  Fuqahd'  Madh-hab  Nu'mdn  al-Mukh- 
tdr.  also  called  al-Kataib  al-Kaffawiyyah,  by  Mahmud  b.  Su.jil-Kaffawi 
(ooo).  It  treats  of  the" Hanifite  doctors  "from  the  Prophet  down"  to 
his  own  time,  giving  lists  of  their  teachers  and  students  ('an'andt), 
peculiar  legal  opinions  as  found  in  famous  fatwa  collections,  their 
works,  and  other  relevant  information.  An  esteemed  work.  An  abridg- 


162  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

ment  of  it  is  the  Al-Fawd'id  al-Bahiyyah  ft  Tardjim  al-Hanafiyyah  ma' 
al-Ta'liqdt  al-Saniyyah  'ala  'l-Fawd'id  al~Bahiyyah,  by  a.  al-Hasanat  M. 
'Abd-al-hayy  al-Luknawi  (1304).  Kazan,  1321;  Cairo,  1324.  (6)  Al- 
Tabaqdt  al-Saniyyah  fi  Tardjim  al-Hanafiyyaht  by  Taqi-al-dm  b.  'Aq. 
al-Tamimi  al-Gazzi  (1005-10),  with  an  introduction.  Alphabetically  ar- 
ranged with  respect  to  real  names  (asmd1).  Separate  sections  for 
ethnic  (ansdb}  and  honorary  names  (alqdb).  "This  is  the  most  ex- 
cellent of  the  works  composed  on  the  lives  of  Hanifites  (ahl  al-ra'y)  : 
It  contains  the  lives  of  the  Shaqd'iq  and  later  works  until  his  time, 
namely  993,  the  year  of  its  completion"  (H.  Khal.).  (7)  Fliigel,  G., 
"Die  Classen  der  hanefitischen  Rechtsgelehrten,"  Abhandl.  der  philol. 
hist.  Classe  der  kdnigl.  sdchs.  Ges.  der  Wiss.,  vol.  iii. 

SHAFIITE— (1)  Tabaqdt  al-Shdffiyyah,  by  Taj-al-din  'Abd-al-wah- 
hab  b.  A.  (b.)  al-Subki  (771).  Cairo,  1324.  Overflowing  with  informa- 
tion (H.  Khal.).  Intended  by  the  author  to  include  the  name  of  every 
jurist  named  in  the  current  books  of  his  time.  Often  quotes  long  passages 
from  their  works  and  relates  at  length  debates,  etc.  Alphabetical  (not 
strictly)  with  respect  to  real  names  (asmd3)  within  each  group,  except 
that  jurists  whose  name  is  Ahmad,  then  those  whose  name  is  Muham- 
mad, are  treated  first.  First  group  gives  Al-Shafi'i's  personal  disciples; 
the  other  groups  consist  of  jurists  who  died  within  same  century. 
There  is  an  abridgment  of  it  by  himself.  (2)  Qald'id  al-Fud,ala  wa 
'Uqud  al-fumdn  (769) — by  Jamal-al-din  a.  M.  'Abd-ar-rahim  b.  al-H. 
al-Isnawi  (772).  Alphabetical  with  respect  to  names  or  surnames  by 
which  jurists  are  commonly  known.  Based  on  the  work  of  b.  al-'Salah 
and  others.  (3)  Tabaqdt  al-Shdffiyyah — by  Taqi-al-dm  a.  Bakr  b.  A. 
b.  (Qadi)  Shuhbah,  al-Dimashqi  (851).  It  gives  lives  of  those  "whose 
names  are  widespread  and  about  whom  the  student  needs  to  know," 
as  the  author  claims.  Treats  in  29  classes  of  20  years  each ;  alphabetical 
within  each  class.  (4)  Wiistenfeld,  H.  F.,  "Der  Imam  el-SchafVi,  seine 
Schiiler  und  Anhanger."  Konigl.  Gesel.  d.  Wiss.  zu  Gottingen,  Abdanl.t 
vols.  36-37.  Based  on  the  works  of  al-Nawawi,  Al-Subki,  al-Isnawi,  b. 
Shuhbah,  b.  Khallikan,  al-Maqrlzi,  al-Suyuti,  etc. 

MALIKITE— (1)  Tartib  al-Maddrik  wa  Taqrib  al-Masdlik  li  Ma'ri- 
fdt  A'ldm  Madh-hab  Mdlik—by  al-Qadi  'lyad  b.  Musa  al-Yahsabi  (544). 
An  esteemed  work  that  is  much  quoted.  (2)  Al-Dlbdj  al-Mudhahhab 
fi  Ma'rifat  A'ydn  Ulamd'  al-Madh-hab,  also  Tabaqdt  al-Mdlikiyyah — by 
Burhan-al-din  Ibr.  b.  'Ali  b.  Farhun  (799).  Fez,  1802.  An  elegant 
work  (H.  Khal.).  Supplements:  (a)  Tawshlh  al-Dibdj  wa  Hilyat 
al-Ibtihdj—by  Badr-al-din  M.  b.  Yahya  ^1-Qarafi  (975  or  1008).  (b) 
Kifdyat  al-Mukhtdj  ila  Ma'rifat  man  Laysa  fi  'l-Dibdj  —  by  A.  Baba 
b.  A.  al-Tunbukti  al-Sanhaji  (1032).  Author  claims  to  have  also  sup- 
plied omissions  of  the  Dibdj.  (Cf.  "Les  Tabakat  Malekites"  by  E.  Fag- 
nan  in  Homenaje  o  D.  F.  Codera,  Zaragoza,  1904.) 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  163 

\NBALITE— (1)  Tabaqdt  al-Hanboliyyah  (513),  by  al-Qadi  a. 
'1-Hu.  M.  b.  M.  al-Farra'  al-Bagdadi  (526).  Supplemented  first  down 
to  750  by  Zayn-al-din  a.  al-Faraj  'Ar.  b.  A.  b.  Rajab  (795)  down  to 
750,  then  by  Yu.  b.  H.  al-Muqaddasi,  down  to  871.  (2)  Al-Manhaj 
al- Ahmad  fi  Tardjim  Asbdb  al-Imdm  Ahmad — by  'Ar.  b.  M.  al-'Umari 

laymi  (927),  the  Hanbalite.  Detailed  work  on  famous  Hanbalites 
down  to  his  time,  supplying  many  omissions  of  the  former. 

SHI'ITE— Majdlis  al-Mu'minin  (996),  by  Nur-allah  b.  Sharif  al- 
Husayni  al-Shushtari.  A  frequently  quoted  work. 

BIBLIOGRAPHICAL 

(1)  K.  al-Fihrist,  or  Fihris  al-Ulum  (377),  by  a.  '1-Faraj  M.  b.  Ishaq 
al-Warraq  al-Bagdadi.  Ed.  G.  Flugel,  Leipzig,  1871.  A  list  of  the  Arabic 
books  written  up  to  377  topically  arranged  with  occasional  bibliographical 
details.  Good  for  earliest  writers.  (2)  Fihrist  Kutub  al-Shfoh,  by  JL 
Ja'far  M.  b.  al-H.  al-Tusi  (459),  the  Imamite.  Ed.  A.  Sprenger.  Bibl. 
Ind.,  nos.  60,  71,  91,  107.  Calcutta,  1853-5.  Gives  list  of  Shi'ite  works. 
According  to  the  Iktifd',  it  includes  the  Nadad  at-Itfdb  of  'Alam  al-Huda 
on  famous  Shi'ites.  (8)  Fihrist  ma  Rawdhu  'an  Shuyukhihi  min  al- 
Dawdwin  al-Musannafah  fi  Durub  al-'Ilm  wa  Anwd'  al-Ma'drif,  by  a. 
Bakr  M.  b.  Khayr  al-Ishbili  (575).  Ed.  Fr.  Codera  and  J.  R.  Tarrago, 
Bibl.  ar.  hisp.,  vols.  ix-x,  Caesaraugustae,  1894-5.  A  list  of  more  than 
1,400  book-titles  topically  arranged  with  full  lists  of  their  transmitters 
but  scant  bibliographical  information.  There  is  a  chapter  on  the  many 
Fihrists  transmitted  down  by  the  author.  (4)  K.  al-'Ibar  wa  Dlwdn 
al-Mubtadd1  wa  'l-Khabar  fi  Ayydm  al-'Arab  wa  'I- A  jam  wa  'l-Barbar, 
etc.,  by  a.  Zayd  'Ar.  b.  M.  b.  Khaldun  al-Magribi  (808),  the  Malikite; 
ihcMuqqaddantah,  vol.  i,  pp.  363-77  (Ibn  Khaldun).  Bulaq,  1284.  Con- 
tains a  valuable  bibliographical  and  critical  review  of  the  literature  of 
the  religious  and  other  sciences.  (5)  Miftdb  al-Sa'ddah  wa  Mifbdb 
al-Siyddah,  by  a.  '1-Khayr  A.  b.  Mu§lih-al-din  Mustafa  Tashkeuprizadeh 
(968),  the  Hanifite.  It  describes  the  subject-matters  of  150  disciplines 
indicating  the  well-known  books  pertaining  to  each.  Drawn  upon  by 
H.  Khal.  (6)  Risdlah  fi  Tabaqdt  al-Masd'il,  by  'AH  Tchelebi  Qinali- 
zadeh  (979)  (also  b.  al-Hinnali).  It  explains  main  types  of  Hanifite 
legal  literature.  Probably  does  not  contain  very  much  more  than  Ibn 
'Abidin  and  H.  Khal.  Cf.  Ahlwardt,  no.  4868.  (7)  Kashf  al-Zunun 
'an  Asdmi  al-Kutub  wa  'l-Funiin  (H.  Khal.),  by  Mustafa  b.  'Al.  Katib 
Tchelebi  Haji  Khali f ah  (1068).  Ed.  with  Latin  translation  by  G. 
Flugel,  Leipzig,  1835-58.  Excepting  Malikite  works,  it  gives  a  nearly 
exhaustive  list  of  Arabic  (also  Turkish  and  Persian)  books  alphabeti- 
cally arranged  according  to  titles,  with  a  long  introduction  on  science, 
its  definition,  purpose,  division,  etc.,  and  with  learned  reviews  of  the 


164 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


different  sciences  and  their  literatures  in  their  proper  places.  (For  inst., 
'Urn  fiqh  under  fiqh,  'Urn  usul-al-fiqh  under  usul-al-fiqh,  etc.)  Profuse 
in  giving  dates  of  death  and  bibliographical  information.  In  connec- 
tion with  basic  works  are  -given  the  commentaries,  abridgments,  versifi- 
cations, etc.  (8)  D'Ohsson,  M.  de  M.,  Tableau  general  de  I'empire 
ottoman,  Paris,  1787.  Pp.  17,  290  give  a  short  list  of  fatwa  collections 
and  a  description  of  the  seminaries  (madrasah)  in  Turkey  and  the 
text-books  used,  respectively.  (9)  Shark  al-Manziimah  al-Musammdt 
bi  'Uqud  Rasm  al-Mufti,  by  M.  Amln  Efendi,  known  as  Ibn  'Abidin 
(1250),  the  Hanifite.  Printed  in  a  collection  of  his  essays  entitled 
Majmuah  Rasd'il  Ibn  'Abidin.  Constantinople,  1325.  Pp.  10-52.  Gives 
valuable  information  about  the  original  'Hanifite  sources  and  the  mean- 
ings of  the  terms  used  by  Hanifite  doctors  in  connection  with  the  trans- 
mission of  early  opinions.  (10)  Vincent,  M.  B.,  Etudes  sur  la  loi  mu- 
sulmane.  Legislation  criminelle.  Paris,  1842.  Gives  historical,  bib- 
liographical information  on  early  important  Malikite  works  of  law 
(pp.  31-62).  (11)  Harington,  J.  H.,  Esq.  (1828),  "Remarks  upon  the 
Authorities  of  Mosulman  Law,"  in  his  An  Elementary  Analysis  of  the 
Laws  and  Regulations  (of  Bengal),  etc.,  vol.  i,  Calcutta,  1805-17. 
Bibliography  of  Hanifite  works  with  especial  reference  to  India.  (12) 
Morley,  W.  H.  (1860),  An  Analytical  Digest  (of  cases  decided  in  the 
Supreme  Courts  of  India).  New  series,  vol.  i,  introd.  London,  1852. 
(13)  Sircar,  -Shama  Qi.,  The  Muhammadan  Law,  Tagore  Law  Lec- 
tures, 1873  and  1874.  Calcutta,  1873  and  1875.  Bibliogr.  of  Hanifite  (pp. 
18-63)  and  of  Shi'ite  works  (pp.  167-74).  (14)  Kremer,  A.  von,  Cultur- 
geschichte  des  Orients  unter  den  Chalifen.  Vienna,  1875-7.  Chapters  on 
law,  pp.  470-547,  and  science  and  literature,  vol.  ii,  396-484.  Also  goes 
into  origin  of  fiqh.  (15)  Chauvin,  Victor,  Bibliographic  des  outrages 
arabes  ou  relatifs  aux  Arabes  publics  dans  I' Europe  chretienne  de  1810- 
8$.  Vols.  i,  ii,  iii.  Liege,  1892, 1897, 1898.  Topical  treatment.  Very  schol- 
arly. Quotes  tables  of  contents.  (16)  Ahlwardt,  W.,  Verzeichniss  der 
arab.  Hss.  der  kdnigl.  Bibliothek  zu  Berlin.  Berlin,  1887.  Topical  treat- 
ment. Gives  list  of  the  works  or  commentaries  bearing  on  a  subject. 
Valuable  work.  (17)  Hurgronje,  C.  Snouck,  Mekka,  Haag,  1889.  Vol. 
ii,  pp.  249  et  seq.  On  methods  of  instruction  in  seminaries  in  Mecca  and 
a  few  of  the  works  used,  with  a  critical  evaluation  of  same.  (18)  Gold- 
ziher,  I.,  Muham.  (M.)  Studien.  Halle,  1889-90.  Contains  a  chapter 
(vol.  ii)  on  hadith  literature.  The  book  is  a  masterly  study  of  the 
entire  subject  of  hadtth.  (19)  Rieu,  Ch.,  Supplement  to  the  Cat.  of  the 
Arab.  Mss.  in  the  Br.  Museum.  London,  1894.  Topical  treatment. 
Rich  in  bibliographical  information.  (20)  Hughes,  T.  B.,  A  Dictionary 
of  Islam,  2d  ed.,  London,  1896.  Gives  bibliography  of  Hanifite  and 
Shi'ite  works  under  Law  and  Tradition.  (21)  K.  Iktifa'  al-Qunii  bima 
Huwa  Matbu  min  A  jail  al-Ta'dllf  al-Arabiyyah  fi  'l-Matdbi'  al-Shar- 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  ^5 

qiyyah  wa  'l-Garbiyyah,  by  Edward  Findik,  Cairo,  1896.  A  list  of  the 
important  Arabic  works  published  in  Europe  and  the  Orient.  Its 
bibliographical  notices  often  based  on  Haji  Khali f ah.  They  are  at 
times  original.  (22)  Sawas,  Pacha,  Etude  sur  la  theorie  du  droit 
H'.usuhnan.  2nd  ed.,  Paris,  1902.  Pp.  150-60.  Bibliography  of  Hani- 
iite  works,  with  special  reference  to  those  used  in  instruction  in  semi- 
naries in  Turkey.  (28)  Sachau,  Ed.,  Muham.  Recht  nach  Shafit. 
l.chrc  (S.),  Stuttgart  and  Berlin,  1897.  Vol.  xvii  of  Lehrbiicher  des 
San.  fiir  orient.  Sprachen  zu  Berlin.  A  bibliography  of  Shafiite  books. 
For  a  long,  constructive  criticism  of  same  by  C.  Snouck  Hurgronje  (H. 
on  S.),  see  Zeitschrift  der  deutschen  morgenldndischen  Gesellschaft 
/).  M.  G.),  Leipzig,  vol.  53,  esp.  pp.  143-150.  (24)  Brockelmann, 
Carl,  (icschichte  der  arab.  Litteratur.  Weimar,  1898-1002.  A  list  of 
extant  Arabic  works  with  accounts  of  existing  Mss.,  years  of  publica- 
tion, short  biographical  notices,  dates  of  birth  and  death,  and  occa- 
sional bibliographical  information.  Commentaries,  abridgments,  etc., 
are  given  in  connection  with  the  basic  works  to  which  they  relate. 
Arrangement  chronological  within  general  topics.  An  indispensable 
manual.  (2.">)  MacDonald,  D.  B.,  Development  of  Muslim  Theology, 
Jurisprudence  and  Constit.  Theory.  New  York,  1903.  Contains  a  good 
annotated  bibliography  on  works  (esp.  European)  on  Islam  in  general. 
(2(>)  Institutes  of  Mussulman  Law,  by  A.  F.  M.  Abdur  Rahman.  Cal- 
cutta, 1907.  Annotated  bibliography  on  Hanifite  works  (pp.  Iv-lxi), 
chiefly  based  on  Harington  and  Morley.  (27)  Heidborn,  A.,  Manuel 
de  droit  public  et  admin,  de  I' empire  ottoman.  Vienna,  Leipzig,  1908. 
Pp.  275  et  seq.  A  complete  list  of  books  used  at  present  in  seminaries 
in  Turkey.  (28)  Nores,  Ed.,  Essai  de  codification  du  droit  musulman 
algcrien  (statut  personel).  Algiers,  1009.  Bibliography  on  Malikite  law 
works.  Pp.  ix-xxv.  (29)  Juynboll,  Th.  W.,  Handbuch  des  islam.  Ge- 
sctzcs  nach  der  Lehre  der  schafiit.  Schule  nebst  einer  allgem.  Einleitung. 
Leiden-Leipzig,  1910.  A  compact  and  useful  work  with  many  refer- 
ences on  each  topic.  Also  contains  a  list  of  the  chief  European  and 
orthodox  Arabic  works  on  Moh.  law.  (30)  The  Encyclopedia  of  Islam. 
Ed.  by  M.  Th.  Houtsma,  etc.  Leyden,  1913.  Covers  geography,  eth- 
nography and  biography  of  Mohammedan  peoples.  Published  as  far  as 
the  letter  H.  (81)  Carusi,  Prof.  Ev.,  Sui  rapporti  fra  diritto  romano 
c  diritto  musulmano.  Rome,  1913.  Extract  from  Atti  d.  Soc.  Ital.  per 
il  Progresso  d.  Science,  VII,  Riunione-Siena,  settembre,  1913.  Makes 
critical  remarks  on  European  works  on  Muh.  law. 

LEXICOLOGICAL 

NAMES  OF  PERSONS— (1)  Al-Mushtabih  fi  Asmd'  al-Rijdl—by 
Shams-al-din  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  A.  al-Dhahabi  (748),  the  Shafiite.  Gives  spell- 
ing of  ambiguous  real  names,  ethnic  names,  surnames  (kunyah)  and 


166  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

honorary  names  (laqab).  (2)  Lubb  al-Lubdb  ft  Tahrir  al-Ansdb,  by 
Jalal-al-din  'Ar.  b.  a.  Bakr  al-Suyu|i  (911),  the  Shafiite.  Leyden,  1851. 
Gives  spelling  of  nisbahs,  i.  e.  names  of  tribal,  family,  or  local  relation. 
Condensed  from  the  Lubdb  of  b.  al-Athlr.,  with  additions. 

NAMES  OF  PLACES— (1)  K.  Mu'jam  Ma  Ustu'jimo,  by  a.  'Ubayd 
'Al.  b.  'Abd-al-'aziz  al-Bakri  (487).  Ed.  F.  Wiistenfeld,  Gottingen, 
1876.  According  to  R.  Dozy,  as  quoted  by  Wiistenfeld,  it  is  unique  in 
completeness  and  accuracy  and  beyond  comparison.  The  work  gives  the 
spelling  of  names  of  towns,  villages,  countries,  stations,  mountains, 
rivers,  wells,  etc.,  occurring  in  hadlths,  histories,  and  poems,  with  situa- 
tions indicated.  Quotes  respective  verses.  (2)  Mu'jam  Mard_sid_  al- 
Ittild'  'a/a  Asina  al-Amkinah  wa  'l-Biqdf,  by  Yaqut  b.  'AL  al-Rumi 
(626).  Ed.  T.  G.  J.  Juynboll,  Leyden,  1850-64.  Condensed  from  the 
Mu'jam  al-Bulddn  of  the  same  author.  (3)  General  dictionaries  such 
as  the  al-Qdmus  al-Muhit  of  M.  b.  Ya'qub  al-Firuzabadi  (817),  the 
Shafiite,  and  esp.  its  commentary,  the  Tdj  al-'Arus,  by  al-Sayyid  M. 
Murtada  al-Zabidi  (1206),  the  Hanifite.  Both  are  alphabetical  with  re- 
spect to  3d,  then  ist  and  2d  letters  of  the  root.  (4)  Bibl.  Geograph- 
orum  Arabicorum.  Ed.  M.  J.  De  Goeje,  Lugduni  Batavorum,  1870-94. 
Contains  indexes  of  places  and  peoples.  (5)  The  Onomasticon  Ara- 
bicum  to  be  shortly  brought  out  in  connection  with  the  Annali  dell' 
Islam  by  L.  Caetani.  It  is  to  contain  over  200,000  items,  and  may  f  airlv 
be  expected  to  dispense  with  all  other  works  of  its  kind. 

COMMON  NAMES— (I)  Koran:  Mufraddt  Alfd?  al-QurjOn,  by  a. 
'1-Qasim  al-<Hu.  b.  M.  al-Ragib  al-Isfahani  (502).  Cairo.  Alphabeti- 
cally arranged  and  very  serviceable.  Quotes  verses  and  traditions. 

(II)  Tradition:    Al-Nihdygh    fi    Garib    al-Hadith    wa    'l-Athar,    by 
Majd-al-dln  a.  '1-Sa'adat  al-Mubarak  b.  M.  al-Jazari  ibn  al-Athir  (606). 
Cairo,  1311.     Two  vols.     Based  on  the  standard  works  of  a.  'Ubayd 
al-Qasim  al-Harawi  (223),  'Al.  b.  Muslim  b.  Qutaybah  (276),  a.  Ubayd 
A.  b.  M.  al-Harawi  (401)  on  both  the  Koran  and  the  hadith,  and  M.  b. 
a.  Bakr  al-Isfahani  (581),  with  additions.    Alphabetical  with  respect  to 
roots.    Quotes  the  entire  hadith  where  the  word  is  found.    Very  easy 
of  reference  and  full  of  valuable  information.     A  condensation  with 
additions  is  the  Al-Durr  al-Nathtr,  by  Jalal-al-din   al-Suyuti    (911). 
Printed  on  the  margin  of  the  Nihdyah. 

(III)  Law— (1)  Garib  al-Fiqh,  by  a.  Man§ur  M.  b.  A.  al-Azhari  (370). 
Explains  words  used  by  Shafiite  jurists.    It  is  "a  standard"  ('umdah} 
in  this  respect.    (H.  Khal.)     (2)  Mafatih  al-'Ulum,  by  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  A. 
al-Khuwarizmi  al-Katib  (ca.  365-87).    Ed.  G.  van  Vlotten,  Leyden,  1895. 
Gives  in  brief  explanations  of  technical  terms  used  in  sciences  and  arts 
(such  as  fiqh,  dogmatics,  syntax,  tax  and  other  administration   [kitd- 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 

bah],  music,  and  chemistry)  in  separate  chapters  analytically  arranged. 
Very  valuable.  (8)  ^/-Mugrib  fi  Tartlb  ol-Mu'rib,  by  a.  '1-Fath  Na§ir 
b.  'Abd-al-sayyid  al-Mutarrizi  (610),  the  Hanifite.  Haydarabad,  1328. 
A  condensed  alphabetical  arrangement  of  his  own  al-Mu'rib.  Explains 
words  and  locutions  used  in  Hanifite  works  on  fiqh,  such  as  the  Muntaqa 
of  al^Hakim  al-Shahid,  the  Tafsir  of  al-Quduri,  the  Mukhtas.ar  of 
al-Karkhi,  etc.,  in  a  rather  non-technical  fashion.  (4)  The  second  part 
(qism)  of  the  work:  Tah-dhib  al-Asmd'  wa  'l-Lugdt,  by  Yahya  al-Na- 
wawi  (676) .  Cf.  supra,  p.  160.  (6)  /J/-Misbah  al-Munir  fi  Garib  al-Sharh 
al-Kabir,  by  A.  b.  M.  al-Muqri  al-Fayyumi  (770).  the  Shafiite.  Cairo, 
1305.  Explains  the  words  used  in  al-iRafi'i's  commentary  on  the  IVajis, 
with  additions.  Gives  many  locutions,  but  in  spite  of  its  name  is  more 
like  a  general  than  a  technical  dictionary.  (6)  Al-Ta'rifdt,  by  'Ali  b.  M. 
al-Jurjani,  al-Sayyid  al-Sharif  (816),  the  Hanifite.  Cairo,  1321  (with  an 
appendix  on  Sufi  terms).  A  well-known  work  giving  brief  definitions 
of  technical  terms  only,  such  as  are  found  in  books  on  law,  fjadith, 
syntax,  etc.  (7)  Maqdlid  ol-'Ultm  fi  'l-Hudud  wa  'l-Rusum,  by  the 
same  author.  Gives  technical  terms  of  21  sciences.  (8)  Ishdrdt  ila  ma 
Waqa'a  ft  Kutub  al-Fiqh  min  al-Asma  wa  'l-Amdkin  wa  'l-Lugdt,  by  a. 
Tahir  M.  b.  Ya'qub  al-Flruzabadi  (817).  Explains  proper  names  and 
terms  of  fiqh  books.  WTAl-Hiddyah  al-Kdfiyah,  by  M.  b.  al-Qasim 
al-Rashsha*  (894),  a  commentary  on  a  work  on  legal  definitions  by  M.  b. 
M.b.'Arafah  al-Wargami  (803) ,  the  Malikite.  (10)  Ta'rifdt,  by  a.  Yahya 
Zakariya'  b.  M.  al-An§ari  (926),  the  Shafiite.  Brief  definitions  of  the 
technical  terms  used  in  dogmatics  (usut-al-din)  and  fiqh.  (11)  Kulliy- 
ydt  al-'Ulum,  by  a.  M-Baqa'  al-Hu.  al-Kaffawi  (1094),  the  Hanifite" 
Bulaq,  1281.  Arrangement  hardly  alphabetical  as  claimed  by  author. 
At  times  very  long,  esp.  as  regards  rules  of  grammar  and  syntax;  at 
other  times  brief  and  non-technical.  (12)  Kashshdf  Istildhdt  al-Funun 
(Tech.  Diet.)  (1158),  by  M.  'Ali  b.  'Ali  aj-Tahanawi,  the  Hanifite.  Ed. 
A.  Sprenger,  Bibl.  Ind.,  Calcutta,  1862.  Explains  technical  terms  by 
long  quotations  from  standard  works.  Contains  an  introduction  on  defi- 
nition, subject-matter,  etc.,  of  sciences.  (13)  Ta'rifdt  al-Funun  wa 
Tardjim  al-Musannifln  wa  Mandqibuhum,  by  M.  al-Aqkerm&ni  (around 
1160).  (14)  Among  general  dictionaries  the  Muhif  al-Mubit,  by  Bulrus 
al-Bustani  (1883),  Bayrut,  1867,  is  particularly  helpful  in  giving  sum- 
mary definitions  of  technical  terms.  Also  the  Qajr  al-Muhij,  an  abridg- 
ment of  the  former  by  the  author  himself. 

KORAN  COMMENTARIES 

(1)  Tafsir  al-Qur'dn,  by  a.  Ja'far  M.  b.  Jarir  al-Tabari  (310),  Cairo, 
1321.  "  The  entire  Mohammedan  community  is  agreed  that  its  like  has 
not  been  written  "  (al-Nawawi,  in  H.  Khal.).  "  The  most  excellent  and 
the  greatest  of  Koran  commentaries"  (Al-Suyuti,  ibid.).  It  is  the  basic 


j68  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

authority.  It  goes  into  the  motives  (wajh)  of  the  opinions  and  indi- 
cates those  that  deserve  preference;  also  goes  into  questions  of  syntax 
(i'rdb)  and  legal  deductions  (istinbdt).  Contains  an  analytical  table  of 
contents.  Index  by  H.  Haussleiter,  entitled  Register  zum  Qorankom- 
mentar  des  Tabari  (Kairo,  1321),  Strassburg,  1912.  It  gives  the  page 
for  each  verse.  (2)  Al-Kash-shdf  'an  Haqd'iq  al-Tanzil,  by  a.  al-Qasim 
Mahmud  b.  'Umar  al-Zamakhshari  (538).  Ed.  Nassau  Lees,  etc.,  Cal- 
cutta, 1856.  Determines  the  meanings  chiefly  from  standpoint  of  syntax 
and  rhetoric,  and  is  Mu'atazilite  in  its  theology  ('aqd'id)  (cf.  Ibn  Khal- 
dun).  "The  author  of  the  Kash-shdf  is  the  sultan  of  this  art  (i.  e., 
rhetoric),  and  therefore  his  book  flew  to  the  East  and  the  West" 
(al-Suyuti,  in  H.  Khal.).  The  "  best"  glosses  by  Sharaf-al-din  al-H.  b. 
M.  al-Tayyibi  (743),  who  refutes  from  the  Sunnite  standpoint  (H. 
Khal.).  (3)  Mafdtlh  al-Gayb,  known  as  al-Tafslr  al-Kabir,  by  Fakhr- 
al-din  M.  b.  'Umar  al-Razi  (606).  An  unfinished  large  work.  Author 
wrote  it  to  disconcert  some  of  "the  jealous  persons"  who  would  not 
believe  a  statement  of  his  to  the  effect  that  10,000  propositions  could  be 
derived  from  the  hidden  meanings  of  the  opening  chapter  of  the 
Koran  (H.  Khal.).  It  is  full  of  singular  views  (Ibn  Khallikan,  in  H. 
Khal.).  It  is  full  of  the  views  of  the  philosophers.  Some  say  that 
there  is  in  it  every  thing  but  a  Koran  commentary  (Itqdn,  p.  917). 
(4)  Anwdr  al-Tanzll  wa  Asrdr  al-Ta'wll,  by  Nasir-al-dir  a.  Sa'Id  'Al. 
b.  'Umar  al-Baydawi  (685?).  Ed.  H.  O.  Fleischer,  Leipzig,  1846. 
Abridged  from  the  Kashshdf,  as  regards  syntax  and  rhetoric,  from 
al-Tafslr  al-Kabir  as  regards  Philosophy  and  Dogmatics,  and  from 
Tafslr  al-Rdgib  as  regards  etymology,  the  mysteries  of  essences 
(haqd'iq)  and  subtle  points.  The  work  is  from  the  Sunnite  standpoint 
and  has  enjoyed  great  favor  as  a  text-book  and  an  object  of  comment. 
(H.  Khal.)  It  is  still  used  in  the  seminaries  (madrasah}  in  Turkey. 
The  work  distinguishes  itself  by  a  summary  treatment  of  all  the  view- 
points. The  best  commentary  on  it  was  written  by  Muslih-al-din 
Mustafa  al-Qujawi  (951)  in  8  vols.  (5)  Tafslr  al-Jaldlayn — begun  by 
Jalal-al-din  M.  b.  A.  al-Mahalli  (864),  and  completed  by  Jalal-al-din 
'Ar.  b.  a.  Bakr  al-'Suyuti  (911),  the  'Shafiites.  "  Small  in  size  but  great 
in  meaning,  for  it  is  the  core  of  the  marrow  of  Koran  commentaries." 
(H.  Khal.)  Also  still  used  in  Turkey. 

SCIENCE  OF  KORAN  INTERPRETATION  (7/m  al-Tafsir) 
Al-Itq&n  fi  'Uliim  al-Qur'dn,  by  Jalal-al-din  al-Suyuti  (911).  Bibl. 
Ind.  Calcutta,  1857.  The  work  is  based  on  the  author's  own  al-Tahbir 
(or  Takhbir?)  fi  'Uliim  al-Tafsir  (an  enlargement  of  the  Mawdqi' 
al-'Ulum  min  Mawdqi'  al-Nujilm,  by  Jalal-al-din  al-Bulqini  and  of  a 
smaller  work  by  al-Suyiiti's  teacher,  a.  'Al.  Muhyi-al-dln  aKKafiji)  and 
on  the  al-Burhdn  fi  'Uliim  al-Qur'dn  of  Badr-al-din  M.  b.  'Al.  al-Zar- 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  ^ 

kashi  (794).  It  was  intended  as  an  introduction  for  the  exhaustive 
Koran  commentary  he  began  writing,  the  Majma'  al-Bahrayn  and  Mafia' 
al-Badrayn,  which  apparently  he  did  not  complete.  The  Itqdn  "  is  the 
most  useful  of  his  works"  (H.  Khal.).  It  is  meant  by  the  author  to 
serve  the  same  function  with  respect  to  the  Koran  as  the  books  on  the 
so-called  sciences  ('ulum)  of  badlth  do  with  respect  to  the  hadiths.  It 
is  in  reality  a  more  or  less  general  treatment  under  separate  topics 
(now'  or  'i/w)  of  the  material  scattered  through  general  and  special 
commentaries.  There  are  80  such  topics  in  the  Itqdn,  e.  g.,  on  abro- 
gated verses,  on  verses  revealed  in  peace  and  war  time,  on  verses  of 
the  mutawdtir  type,  on  Koran  commentators,  etc. 

KORAN  CONCORDANCE,   Fliigel,  G.  L.,   Concordantiae  Corani 
Arabicae,  Leipzig,  1842.    Very  serviceable. 

TRADITION  (Hadlth) 

(1)  .;(/£,  by  a.  'Al.  Malfcb.  Anas  (179).     (a)  Recension  of 

Yahya  h.  Yuhya  al-Masmudi  (234)  (Muwatta*).  Lithogr.  Dihli,  1302. 
It  contains  ±1,720  hadiths.  (b)  Recension  of  M.  b.  al-Hasan  (189),  the 
Hanifite,  with  a  long  introd.  and  copious  notes  by  a.  al-Hasanat  'Abd- 
al-hayy  b.  M.  al-Luknawi.  The  latter  recension  is  shorter,  containing 
often  Muhammad's  own  views.  (Cf.  Goldziher,  M.  Studien.)  There 
are  about  16  recensions,  that  of  Yahya  being  considered  as  the  standard 
one.  The  Muwatta  is  said  to  be  the  first  compilation  of  badiths, 
though  different  views  have  been  also  held.  It  is  properly  speaking  a 
work  of  law,  the  hadiths  mentioned  in  it  being  invoked  in  support  of 
the  author's  views.  It  contains  many  hadiths  of  the  mursal  and  mun- 
rank.  Al-Shafi'i  is  related  to  have  said  concerning  the  Muwaltd\ 
that  after  the  Koran  it  is  the  most  reliable  book.  Later  Shafh'tes  say 
that  this  statement  was  made  before  the  writing  of  the  six  Sahihs  and 
is  no  longer  true.  Commentary  by  M.  b.  'Abd-al-baqi  al-Zarqani  (1122). 
Cairo,  1280.  An  esteemed  commentary.  (2)  Musnad  al-Imdm  Ahmad, 
by  A.  b.  M.  b.  Hanbal  (241).  This  is  the  most  famous  collection  of  the 
inusnad  type,  i.  e.  a  collection  where  hadiths  transmitted,  e.  g.,  by  the 
same  Companion  are  classed  together  without  respect  to  content.  (For 
a  review  of  the  Cairo  edition  of  this  work  by  I.  Goldziher,  see  Z.  D. 
M.  t/".,  vol.  50,  pp.  465  et  seq.)  The  work  is  said  to  contain  about  30,000 
hadiths.  "It  is  a  worthy  work  and  one  of  the  sources  of  Islam"  (H. 
Khal.).  The  work,  as  it  is,  is  extremely  difficult  of  reference.  (8) 
Al-Jdmi'  al-Sahih,  known  as  Sahib  al-Bukhdri,  by  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  Ism. 
al-Bukhari  (256)"  Ed.  L.  Krehl  (vols.  i-iii),  Th.  W.  Juynboll  (vol.  iv). 
Leyden,  1862-8.  This  work  is  of  the  type  called  mus.annaf,  i.  e.,  a  col- 
lection of  hadiths  arranged  in  chapters  according  to  content.  It  is  the 
first  of  the  well-known  sixhadith  collections  considered  reliable  (fablb) 
and  canonical.  This  one,  after  the  Koran,  is  the  most  reliable  (jo/ii/») 


170 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


book  of  Islam.  Al-Bukhari  mentions  in  his  work  all  the  chains  of  re- 
porters (turuq)  by  which  hadlths  have  been  transmitted.  For  this 
purpose  he  visited  all  the  centers  where  Companions  lived.  He  does 
not,  however,  include  a  hadlth  unless  all  its  reporters  are  agreed  on  it. 
Many  hadlths  are  repeatedly  mentioned  (al-Nawawi,  in  H.  Khal.,  and 
Ibn  Khaldun).  The  work  is  said  to  contain  9,000  hadlths,  2,800  being 
repetitions.  According  to  Ibn  Khaldun,  the  Malikites  of  his  time  con- 
sidered that  no  commentary  worthy  of  this  work  had  yet  been  written 
and  that  the  Moslem  community  owed  to  the  author  this  debt.  H.  Khal. 
remarks  that  perhaps  this  debt  has  been  acquitted  by  the  following 
three  commentaries  written  since  then:  (a)  Path  al-Bdri,  by  A.  b.  'Ali 
b.  Hajar  al-'Asqalani  (852),  the  Shafiite,  with  an  introduction.  Well 
known.  One  of  the  largest  commentaries  on  the  work,  in  10  parts, 
(b)  'Umdat  al-Qdri,  by  Badr-al-din  a.  M.  Mahtnud  b.  A.  al-'Ayni 
(855),  the  Hanifite.  Based  largely  on  the  former,  with  additional 
matter.  Not  so  widespread  as  the  former,  (c)  Irshdd  al-Sdri  li  Shark 
Sahih  al-Bukhdri,  by  Shihab-al-din  A.  b.  M.  al-Khatib  al-Qastallani 
(923)>  the  (Shafiite.  Bulaq,  1304-5,  in  10  vols.,  with  an  introduction  on 
'Urn  hadlth  and  al-Bukhari.  Also  based  on  the  Path  al-Bdri,  (4) 
Sunan  al-Ddrimi,  by  'Al.  b.  'Ar.  al-Darimi  (255).  This  work  has  a 
long  introduction  calculated  to  support  the  hadith-folk  side  in  the 
controversy  about  the  use  of  personal  opinion  in  law.  Then,  too,  it 
contains  fewer  hadlths  and  avoids  details.  Probably  these  facts  ex- 
plain why  this  work  has  not  been  included  among  the  six  canonical 
collections,  though  it  enjoys  great  esteem.  Two  other  important  hadlth 
compositions  which  likewise  failed  are  the  Sunans  of  'Ali  b.  'Umar 
al-Daraqutni  (385),  and  A.  b.  al-Hu.  a.  Bakr  al-Bayhaqi  (458),  the  Shafi- 
ites.  The  works  of  al-Bayhaqi  were  much  esteemed  by  the'Shafiites.  (5) 
Jdrni'  al-Sahlh,  by  a.  al-Hu.  Muslim  b.  al^Hajjaj  al-Nlsaburi  (261),  the 
Shafiite.  The  second  of  the  "  Six  books."  This  work  found  especial 
favor  among  the  Moslems  of  the  Magrib  (West),  some  of  whom  went 
as  far  as  placing  it  above  the  Sahih  of  al-Bukhari  (Ibn  Khaldun). 
Muslim  followed  the  plan  of  al-Bukhari,  except  that  his  arrangement  is 
better.  He  mentions  a  given  hadlth  in  one  place  only.  Muslim  quotes 
hadlths  from  625  traditionists  whose  hadlths  al-Bukhari  would  not 
quote.  His  requirements  are  said  to  be  somewhat  less  rigorous  than 
those  of  al-Bukhari.  Commentaries:  (a)  Al-Mu'allim  bi  Fawd'id  K. 
Muslim,  by  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  'Ali  al-Maziri  (536),  the  Malikite.  Treats  also 
of  'ilm-al-hadlth  and  fiqh.  (b)  Tkmdl  al-Mu(allim  fi  Sharh  Muslim, 
by  al-Qadi  'lyad  b.  Musa  al-Yah§abi  (544),  the  Malikite.  It  is  an  en- 
largement of  the  former,  (c)  Al-Minhdj  fi  Sharh  Muslim  b.  al-Hajjdj, 
by  Yahya  b.  Sharaf  al-Nawawi  (676),  the  Shafiite,  with  an  introduction 
on  'Urn  al-hadlth.  Contains  matter  found  in  the  two  previous,  and 
more  (Ibn  Khaldun).  Published  on  margin  of  Qastallani.  (C)  Sunan 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  !7r 

a.  Ddwiid,  by  a.  DawQd  Su.  b.  al-Ash'ath  al-Sijistani  (275),  the  Shafiite. 
This  is  a  hadith  collection  of  the  Sunan  class.    The  works  of  this  class 
treat  the  hadiths  only  in  so  far  as  they  constitute  a  rule  of  conduct 
(sunnah).    They  differ  from  the  J 'ami's,  which  include  hadiths  of  every 
description.    The  author  says  that  out  of  500,000  hadiths  he  had  writ- 
ten down,  he  incorporated  in  his  book  4,008.    This  is  the  third  of  the 
"  Six  Books "  passed  as  canonical,  the  other  three  being  in  order  of 
esteem  the  Sunan  books  of  al-Tirmidhi,  al-Nasa'i  and  b.  Majah.    Ac- 
cording to  Ibn  Khaldun  these  four  are  less  exacting  than  the  first  two, 
including  also  hadiths  of  a  rank  below  the  s.ahi[i  and  hasan.    (7)  Jdmi' 
al-Saf}ih,  also  called  Sunan  al-Tirmidhi,  by  a.  'Isa  M.  b.  'Isa  al-Tirmidhi 
(279),  the  Shafiite.     Goldziher~thinks  that  the  word  Jdmi'  betteflits 
this  work.    (8)  Sunan  b.  Mdjah,  by  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  Yazid  b.  Majah  al-Qaz- 
wlni    (273).     Also  one  of  the  "  Six  Books."     The   following  works, 
which,  written  later,  superseded  the  foregoing  for  purposes  of  refer- 
ence and  instruction,  are  based  on  the  foregoing  and  consist  in  re- 
arrangement, compilation,  comment,  and  re-hash.    (9)  Sunan  al-Sagir, 
called  al-Mujtabi,  by  a.  'Ar.  A.  b.  Shu'ayb  al-Nasa'i  (303),  the  Shafiite. 
Condensed  by  the  author  from  his  larger  work,  the  Sunan  al-Kabir. 
(10)  Al-Jdmi'  bayn  al-Sahihayn,  by  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  a.  Na§r  al-Humaydi 
al-Andalusi   (488),  a  disciple  of  'AH  b.  Hazm,  the  Zahirite.     A  noted 
work  combining  the  two  first  Sahihs.    (11)  Ma$dblh  al-Sunnah,  by  Hu. 

b.  Mas'ud   al-Farra'  al-Bagawi   (516  or  510),  the  Shafiite.     Contains 
4,485  or,  in  another  version,  4,719  hadiths.     Omits  supports   (asdnid) 
and  groups  the  hadiths  of  $ahih  rank  separately  from  those  of  6<wan 
rank,  indicating  those  of  inferior  rank.    This  work  enjoys  great  esteem. 
An    enlargement:    Mishkdt  al-Mas.dbih    (737),   by   a.   'Al.    M.   b.   'Al. 
al-Khatib  al-Tibrizi,  the  Shafiite.    A  standard  work  in  India.    English 
translation  by  A.  N.  Matthews,  Calcutta,  1809-10.    (12)  Tajrid  al-Sihdh 
al-Sittah,  by  Razin  b.  Mu'awiyah  al-'Abdari  (535).    Combines  all  the 
Six  Books,  and  foHows  al-Bukhari  as  regards  chaptering  (abwdb).  Does 
not  comment  on  the  hadiths.    (13)  Jdmi'  al-Us.ul,  by  Majd-al-dm  Mu- 
barak b.  M.  b.  al-Athir  al-Jazari  (606),  the  Shafiite,  with  introduction 
on  'Urn  al-hadith  and  biographies  of  the  Prophet  and  his  Companions. 
Combines  the  previous  work  and  the  Six  Books,  omitting  the  supports 
save  the  name  of  the  Companion  or  the  person  directly  reporting  from 
the  Companion.    Comments  on  difficult  (garib)  hadiths.    Arranged  in 
chapters  alphabetically  disposed.    .Sources  indicated  by  letters.    Abridg- 
ments: (a)  Tajrid  al-Us.ul,  by  Sharaf-al-din  Hibat-allah  'Abd-al-rahlm 
b.  al-Barizi  al-Hamawi  (738),  the  Shafiite.    Omits  comments  and  gram- 
matical and  syntactical  remarks,     (b)   K.   Tayslr  al-Wu$ul  ila  Jdmi' 
al-Us.tl,  by  'Ar.  b.  'Ali  b^aUDiba'   al-Shaybani  al-Zabidi    (944),  the 
Shafiite.    Cairo,  1330.    An  elaboration  and,  according  to  the  author,  an 
improvement  of  the  abridgment  just  mentioned.     "The  best  of   the 


172 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


abridgments"  (H.  Khal.).  Much  used  by  students.  (14)  Mashdriq 
al- Anwar  al-N abawiyyah  min  Sihdh  al-Akhbdr  al-Mustafawiyyah,  by 
Radi-al-din  al-H.  b.  M.  al-Sagani  (or  Sagani)  al-Hindi  (650).  Con- 
tains 2,246  hadiths  of  the  sahih  rank.  Much  commented  upon.  Al- 
Subki  is  quoted  in  the  Tadrlb  (p.  6)  as  having  said:  "The  final  goal 
[in  the  study  (*i7m)  of  hadlth  for  some  people]  is  the  study  of  the 
Mashdriq  al-Anwdr;  therefore,  if  they  rise  as  high  as  the  Masdblh  of 
al-Bagawi,  they  believe  that  they  have  reached  the  degree  of  muhad- 
diths."  (15)  Jam'  al-Jawdmi',  by  Jalal-al-din  'Ar.  b.  a.  Bakr  al-Suyuti 
(911).  Combines  the  Six  Books,  several  Musnads,  and  others,  and  is 
intended  by  the  author  to  exhaust  the  entire  field  of  hadiths.  The 
author  abridged  it  in  his  al-Jdmi'  al-Sagir,  which  he  supplemented  in 
the  Zawd'id.  A  compilation  and  arrangement  of  all  the  three  is  the 
Kanz  al-'Ummdl  fi  Sunan  al-Aqwdl  wa  'I  Af'dl,  by  'Ali  b.  Husam-al-din, 
al-Muttaqi  (975),  the  Indian.  Haydarabad,  1312-14.  Eight  parts.  Ac- 
cording to  the  numbering  on  the  margin,  it  contains  46,681  hadiths, 
cast  in  books  (Kitdb)  (in  the  conventional  manner  of  the  fiqh  books), 
alphabetically  arranged.  Probably  the  easiest  of  reference.  A  conden- 
sation of  it  by  its  author  is  the  Muntakhab  Kanz  al-'Ummdl,  etc. 
Printed  on  the  margin  of  the  Musnad  of  Ahmad.  About  one-third 
reduced.  A  useful  feature  of  both  works  is  the  separate  treatment  of 
the  hadiths  pertaining  to  the  Prophetic  conduct  (afdl). 

SCIENCE  OF  TRADITION 
('Ilm  or  'Ulum  or  Usiil  or  Mustalah  al-Hadith) 
(1)  (Ma'rifat}  'Ulum  al-Hadlth,  also  called  Funtin  al-Hadlth  and 
Usiil  al-Hadlth,  by  a.  'Amr  'Uthman  b.  'Ar.  b.  al-Salah  (643),  the 
Shafiite.  The  first  work  on  the  subject  which  achieved  a  classical 
fame.  Contains  65  topics  (naw'~).  Commentaries:  (a)  Al-Taqyld  wa 
'l-Iddh,  etc.,  by  'Abd-al-rahim  b.  al-Hu.  al-lraqi  (806)  ;  (b)  by  ^Izz- 
al-din  M.  b.  Jama'ah  (819)  ;  etc.  Abridgments:  by  Badr-al-din  M. 
b.  Jama'ah  (733),  Ism.  b.  'Umar  b.  Kathlr  (774),  and  others,  the  most 
famous  of  them  being  the  next  work.  (2)  Al-Taqrlb  wa  'l-T&yslr 
H  Ma'rifat  Sunan  al-Bashlr  al-Nadhlr,  by  Yahya  b.  Sharaf  al-Nawawi 
(676).  It  is  a  second  abridgment  of  a  first  abridgment  of  that  work 
by  the  same  author,  entitled  K.  al-Irshdd  (li-Ma'rifat  Hadlth  Khayr 
al-'Ibdd).  The  Taqrlb  was  translated  into  French  by  M.  Margais  and 
was  published  in  the  7.  Asiatique,  1900-1901,  9eme  serie,  vols.  16,  17,  18. 
The  preface  gives  useful  information  on  bibliography,  etc.  Commen- 
taries: (a)  By  'Abd-al-rahim  al-'Iraqi  (806)  ;  (b)  M.  b.  'Ar.  al-Sakhawi 
(902)  ;  (c)  Tadrib  al-Rdwi  fi  Sharh  Taqrlb  al-Nawawi,  by  Jalal-al-din 
'Ar.  b.  a.  Bakr  al-Suyuti  (on).  Cairo,  1307.  The  work  is  also  in- 
tended as  a  commentary  to  the  works  of  b.  al-Salah  and  others.  It  is 
full  of  information.  (3)  The  Manzumah  of  A.  b.  Farah  al-Ishbili  (699). 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  ^3 

Also  called  Gar  dm  Sahih,  these  being  the  words  with  which  the  work 
begins.  It  is  a  love-poem  in  20  verses,  containing  about  40  technical 
terms.  It  begins  thus:  "My  longing  is  true  (sahih)  and  the  desire 
for  you  is  overcoming  (wu'^i/),"  etc.,  the  words  sahih  and  mu'dil  being 
also  technical  terms.  A  commentary  of  this  is  the  Zawdl  al-Tarah 
fi  Shark  Mansumat  b.  Farah,  by  'Izz-al-din  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  Jama'ah  al- 
Kinani  (816).  Ed.  by  F.  Risch  as  a  Leipzig  dissertation  with  notes. 
Leyden,  1885.  (4)  Al-Khuldsah  fi  Ma'rifat  (or  U&l)  al-Hadith,  by 
Sharaf-al-din  Hu.  b.  M.  al-Tayyibi  (743).  An  "able  compendium" 
(H.  Khal.).  Condensed  from  the  works  of  b.  al-Salah,  al-Nawawi, 
al-Qadi  b.  Jama'ah,  with  additions  from  the  Jdmi"  al-Us.ul,  etc.  (5) 
Al-Alfiyyah  (or  al-Tab^irah  wa  'l-Tadhkirah),  by  Zayn-al-din  'Abd- 
al-rahim  b.  al-Hu.  al-'Iraqi  (806),  the  Shafiite.  It  is  a  condensation 
of  the  work  of  b.  al-Salah  in  rajas  verse.  A  commentary  on  it  is  the 
K.  Path  al-Bdqi  li  Shark  Alfiyyah  al-' Iraqi,  by  a.  Yahya  Zakariya'  al- 
Ansari  (926),  the  Shafiite.  (6)  Nukhbat  al-Fikar  fi  I$tildh  AM  al-Athar, 
by  A.  b.  'Ali  b.  Hajar  (852),  with  a  commentary  by  the  same.  Cairo, 
1323.  Margais  finds  b.  Hajar's  treatment  more  scientific.  A  much 
annotated  work.  (7)  Bayquniyyah,  by  Tahir  b.  M.  al-Bayquni  (ca. 
1080).  A  poem  in  34  rajas  verses  containing  about  35  terms.  Used  by 
students  in  the  Azhar  and  the  Algerian  seminaries.  There  is  a  com- 
mentary on  it  by  M.  b.  'Abd-al-baqi  b.  Yu.  al-Zarqani  (1122).  (8)  The 
introductions  of  the  commentaries  of  al-Qastallani  and  al-Nawawi  on 
the  Sahihs  of  al-Bukhari  and  Muslim,  respectively,  mentioned  before, 
contain  useful  matter  bearing  on  this  subject. 

THE  PRINCIPLES  OF  LAW  (Us&l-al-fiqh) 

(1)  Risalah,  by  M.  b.  Idris  al-Shafrt  (204).  Recension  of  al-Rabl' 
b.  Su.  al-Muradi.  BQlaq,  1321.  Said  to  be  the  first  work  on  usul- 
al-fiqh.  Cf,,  however,  the  Fihrist  (p.  204)  where  M.  b.  al-H.  is 
said  to  have  written  on  "U$ill-al-fiqh,"  "Ijtihdd  al-Ra'y"  and  "Istihsdti." 
The  Risdlah  represents  the  transition  stage  in  the  differentiation  of  this 
science  from  fiqh.  In  many  parts  it  reads  like  a  Shafiite  work  on  fiqh. 
A  most  valuable  source.  Commented  upon,  among  others,  by  M.  al- 
Qaffal  al-Shashi  (507). 

(*)  Taqii'im  al-AdiUah,  by  a.  Zayd  'Al.  b.  'Umar  al-Dabusi  (430), 
the  Hanifitel  "  Best  of  works  written  by  the  earliest  writers"  (Ibn 
Khaldun).  Al-Dabusi  completed  the  elaboration  of  the  laws  of  qiyds 
(ibid.).  Commented  upon  by  'Ali  al-Pazdawi  (482)  and  others. 

(8)  Al-Mu'tamad,  by  a.  al-Hu.  M.  b.  'Ali  al-Basri  (436),  the  Mu'ta- 
zilite.  A  large  work  used  as  basis  by  later  writers.  The  Mu'tamad  is 
a  commentary  on  the  'Ahd  by  'Abd-al-jabbar  b.  A.  al-Asadabadi  Qadi 
al-Qudat  (415),  chief  of  the  Mu'tazilites,  but  Shafiite  as  to  fiqh.  (Ibn 
Khali.,  Subki,  vol.  iii,  p.  220.) 


174 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


(4)  Al-Burhdn,   by   a.   al-Ma'ali    'Abd-al-malik    b.    'Al.    al-Juwayni 
Imam  al-'Haramayn  (478),  the  Shafiite.     Shows  independence  of  view. 
"A  pride  of  the  Shafiites"  (Subki).    Style  very  involved.    The  work, 
though  by  a  Shafiite,  was  commented  upon  by  Malikites  such  as  'Al. 
al-Maziri  and  a.  al-^H.  al-Anbari.    They  attack  the  author  where  he  is 
at  variance,  e.  g.,  with  a.  al-H.  al-Ash'ari.    They,  however,  depend  on 
his  works  exclusively  as  regards  dogmatics.    (iSubki,  vol.  iii,  p.  264.) 

(5)  Al-Waraqdt,  by  the  same  Imam  al-Haramayn.    It  is  a  small  com- 
pendium intended  for  beginners.    This  work  found  great  favor  among 
the  Shafiites  and  was  commented  upon  by  many   (also  by  Hanifites), 
among  others  by  Jalal-al-din  M.  b.  A.  al-Mahalli   (864),  with  glosses 
entitled  Qurrat  al-Ayn  (953)  by  M.  b.  M.  al-Khattdb,  the  Malikite. 

(6)  Kanz  al-lVu$ul  ila   Ma'rifat   al-Ujul   or    U$ul  al-Pasdawi,   by 
Fakhr-al-islam  'Ali  b.  M.  al-Pazdawi   (482),  the  Hanifite.     "Best  of 
works  written  by  later  writers  and  exhaustive"  (Ibn  Khaldun).    This 
is  a  work  of  classic  reputation  among  Hanifites.    It  gives  the  arguments 
at  length.    Style  is  at  parts  difficult.    Commentaries:  (a)  Kashf  al-Asrdr, 
by  'Abd-al-'aziz  b.  A.  al-Bukhari  (730).     Constantinople,  1307.    "The 
largest,  most  profitable  and  clearest  commentary"    (H.  Khal.).     This 
commentary  with  its  text  is  indispensable  for  critical  research  into  his- 
tory of  usul-al-fiqh.    Later  Hanifite  works  are  chiefly  based  on  these 
two.     (b)   Al-Kdfi,  by  Husam-al-dm  al-Hu.  b.  'Ali  al-Signaqi    (7io). 
(c)    Al-Taqrir,  by  Akmal-al-din   M.  b.   Mahmud   al-Mi§ri   al-Babarti 
(786),  the  Hanifite. 

(7)  K.  al-Usul,  by  Shams-al-a'immah  a.  Bakr  M.  b.  A.  al-Sarakhsi 
(483).    Must  be  a  valuable  source.    The  K.  al-Istihsdn,  by  the  same,  is 
printed  in  his  Mabsut,  vol.  x,  pp.  145-85.    After  some  valuable  general 
remarks  on  nature  of  istifasdn,  the  author  argues  at  length  for  its  ap- 
plication in  practical  cases,  chiefly  in  connection  with  modesty. 

(8)  Al-Mustasfa,  by  a.  Hamid  M.  b.  M.  al-Gazzali   (505),  the  Sha- 
fiite.   Bulaq,  1322.    A  valuable  work  used  as  basis  for  later  compila- 
tions.   Original  in  arrangement.    It  goes  into  the  arguments.    Accord- 
ing to  Ibn  Khaldun,  the  Burhdn  and  the  Mustafa,  on  the  one  hand,  and 
the  'Ahd  and  Mu'tamad,  on  the  other,  are  the  four  best  basic  works  on 
usiil-al-fiqh  written  from  a  dogmatic  (mutakallim)  standpoint,  namely, 
in  a  purely  speculative  way  without  reference  to  the  applications  of 
the  principles  in  the  field  of  fiqh. 

(9)  The  works  of  M.  b.  'Al.  b.  Tnmart  al-Mahdi  (524),  the  founder 
of  the  Almohades  dynasty  (dawlat  al-muwahhidin) ,  with  biographical 
extracts   on   b.   Tumart   and   a   critical  introduction   by   I.   Goldziher. 
Algiers,  1903.    These  works  chiefly  bear  on  questions  of  usul-al-fiqh  and 
dogma,  and  represent  a  reaction  to  the  speculative  and  secular  tenden- 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


175 


cies  of  the  four  orthodox  schools.    The  point  of  view  is  akin  to  that 
of  the  Zahirites. 

(10)  Al-Mabsul,  by  Fakhr-al-<lin  M.  b.  'Umar  al-Razi  b.  al-Khajib 
(606),  the  .Shafiite.    A  condensation  of  the  four  works  mentioned  (Ibn 
Khaldun),  especially  the  Musta$fa  and  the  Mu'tamad,  which,  according 
to  al-Isnawi   (Minhdj,  p.  4),  he  transfers  bodily  by  pages,  apparently 
because  he  "used  to  commit  them  to  memory."     Unlike  the  Ahkdm, 
the  Mahful  does  not  indulge  in  argumentation   (Ibn  Khaldun;  cf.  H. 
Khal.).     Abridgments:    (a)    Al-Tahtfl,    by    Siraj-al-din    a.    al-Thana' 
Mahmud  b.  a.  Bakr  al-Urmawi~(682).  the  Shafiite.    The  author  abridged 
the  Tabfil  from  the  Mabs&l  "  in  order  to  supply  "  the  great  demand  for 
abridgments.    Enjoyed  widespread  use.     (b)  Al-Hds'il  mm  al-Maksul, 
by  al-Qadj  Taj-al-dm  M.  b.  Hu.  al-Urmawi.     An  abridgment  of  the 
Mah$ul  (by  about  one-tenth)  as  to  words  rather  than  meaning,  as  the 
author  claims,    (c)  Minna  j  al-Wu$ul  ila  7/m  al-U$ul,  by  'Al.  b.  'Umar 
al-Baydawi    (685?),  based  on  the  Hdjil.     According  to  Jamal-al-din 
b.  H.  al-Isnawi^  (772),  the  Shafiite,  who  wrote  a  commentary  on  it,  the 
Nihdyat  al-Sul  (printed  with  the  Minhdj  on  the  margin  of  the  Taqrlr), 
most  of  his  contemporaries  depended  exclusively  on  the  Minhdj  on 
account  of  its  small  size  and  attractive  style.     (This  is  the  Minhdj  re- 
ferred to  in  Part  I  of  this  dissertation.     The  Minhdj  referred  to  in 
Part  II  is  on  fiqh  by  al-Nawawi.    Cf.  infra,  p.  188.)     (d)  Tanqih  al-Fuful 
fi  'l-Usul,  by  Shihab-al-din  A.  b.  Idris  al-Qarafi   (684),  the  Malikite. 
Based  on  the  Mahjul  and  the  Ifddah  of  al-Qadi  'Abd-al-wahhab,  the 
Malikite.    Favored  by  beginners  and  much  commented  upon. 

(11)  Al-Ahkdm,  by  a.  al-H.  'AH  b.  a.  'Ali  Sayf-al-din  al-Amidi  (631), 
the  Shafiite.    A  condensation  of  the  four  basic  works  mentioned.    The 
author  indulges  in  argumentation  (tahqlq)  and  illustrations  from  the 
applications  (tafri)  (Ibn  Khaldun).    (a)  An  abridgment  of  the  Ahkdm 
is  the  Muntaha  al-Sul  wa  'l-Amal  fi  'Ilmay  al-U$ul  wa  'l-Jadal,  by 
Jamal-al-din  a.  'Amr  'Uthman  b.  'Umar,  b._al-Iiajib  (646),  the  Mali- 
kite,     (b)  Mukhta$ar  al-Muntaha  or  Mukhtasar  b.  al-Hdjib,  by  same. 
Abridged  from  the  former.    This  second  abridgment  enjoyed  great  popu- 
larity  and   was   annotated   by   Malikites   as   well   as    Shafiites.     Com- 
mentary by  'Ad.ud-al-dm  'Ar.  b.  A.  al-Iji   (756),  the  Malikite.     Con- 
stantinople, 1310.    Text  begins  by  "Qdl"  commentary  by  "Aqulu."    Con- 
sidered to  be  one  of  the  best. 

(12)  Al-Muntakhab  fi   Uful-al-Madh-hab,  known   as   al-Muntakhab 
al-Husdmi,  by  Husam-al-din  M.  b.  M.  al-Akhsikati  (644).    A  text  free 
of  superfluous  matter  and  well  arranged  with  its  divisions  (fu$ul)  in- 
dicated, and  containing  nice  points ;  therefore  very  much  sought  after. 
Commentary:  al-Tahqiq,  by  'Abd-al-'aziz  b.  A.  al-Bukhari  (730),  writ- 


176  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

ten  after  the  completion  of  his  commentary  on  al-Pazdawi's  work  on 
usul-al-fiqh. 

(13)  Badl'  al-Nisdm,  by  Muzaffar-al-din  A.  b.  'AH  b.  al-Sa'ati  (694), 
the  Hanifite.  An  "  elegant  compendium "  condensing  the  works  of 
al-Amidi  and  al-Pazdawi  (H.  Khal.).  Ibn  Khaldun  says  that  the  lead- 
ing doctors  of  his  time  currently  used  it  for  reading  and  that  many 
commentaries  were  written  on  it. 


Mandr  al-Anwdr,  by  a.  '1-Barakat  'Al.  b.  A.  Hafiz-al-dln  al-Nasan 
(710,  720),  the  Hanifite.  An  esteemed  compendium,  the  most  used  of 
the  author's  works.  Numerous  commentaries  were  written  on  it.  The 
most  widely  known  of  these  is  the  Shark  al-Mandr  by  'Abd-al-latif  b. 
'Abd-al-'azlz  b.  Firishtah  b.  al-Malak  (around  830).  Glosses  thereon 
by  Mustafa  b.  M.  Azmizadeh  (ca.  1040).  An  abridgment  of  it  is  the 
Mukhtasar  al-Mandr,  by  b.  Hablb  al-Halabi  (808).  (See  infra,  no.  21.) 

(15)  Al-Tawdih    fi   Hall   Gawdmid   al-Tanqih,    a    commentary,    by 
'Ubayd-allah  b.  Mas'ud  b.  Taj-al-shan'ah  b.  Sadr-al-shari'ah  al-Awwal 
al-Mahbubi    (747),    the    Hanifite,    on    his    own    compendium    entitled 
Tanqih  al-Usul.    An  elegant  text  of  classical  fame.     It  is  based  pri- 
marily on  the  work  of  b.  al-Hajib,  the  Mah$ul,  and  especially  the  Usul 
of  al-Pazdawi.     It  is  a  schematic  arrangement  of  those  works  ably 
carried  out.    The  author  claims  priority  for  his  arrangement.    The  best 
of  its  commentaries  is  the  al-Talwih  fi  Kashf  Haqd'iq  al-Tanqih  by 
Sa'd-al-dm  Mas'ud  b.  'Umar  al-Taftazani  (792),  the  Shafiite.    Kazan, 
1301. 

(16)  Jam'   al-Jawdmi',   by   Taj-al-din    fAbd-al-wahhab   b.    al-Subki 
(771),  the  Shafiite.    A  very  comprehensive  compendium  of  great  repu- 
tation "  collected  from  the  flowers  of  100  works,"  containing  the  cream 
of  the  author's  commentaries  on  the  Minhdj  and  the  Mukhtasar  of  b. 
al-Hajib.     A   thorough-going   commentary   by   Jalal-al-din    al-Mahalli 
(864).    Glosses  by  'Ar.  al-Bannani  al-Magribi  (1198)  and  notes  by  'Ar. 
al-Sharblni  (2Oth  cent.).    Cairo,  1309.    One  of  the  text-books  used  in 
the  Azhar. 

(17)  Al-Tahrir,  by  M.  b.  'Abd-al-wahid  b.  al-Humam  (or  Hammam 
or  Humam-al-din)   al-Slwasi  (861),  the  Hanifite.     Treats  both  Hani- 
fite and  Shafiite  views  with  arguments.     Its  style  is  involved.     Com- 
mentary:  ^/-Taqrir  wa  'l-Tahbir,  by  his  student  M.  b.  M.  b^Amir 
al-Hajj  al-Halabi  (879).    Bulaq,  1316-17.    Abridgment:  Lubb  al  Usul, 
by  Zayn  al-'Abidin  b.  Nujaym  al-Misri,  who  rearranged  it  in  the  Hani- 
fite order. 

(18)  Mirqdt  al-Wusiil  fi  'Ilm  al-Usul,  by  M.  b.  Faramurz  Munla 
Khusrew    (885),   the   Hanifite.     Commentary:    Mir' at  al-Usul  by  the 
author  himself.     An  elegant  commentary  containing  the  early  views 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 

with  original  additions ;  the  names  of  14  works  on  ujul-al-fiqh  are 
given  in  the  introduction  (H.  Khal.).  Both  works  are  still  used  in 
the  seminaries  in  Turkey.  Glosses  by  Mawla  Hafid  Efendi  (1098) 
and  notes  by  Su.  al-Izmiri  (1102).  Bulaq,  1262;  Stamboul,  1304. 

(19)  Majdnii'  al-Haqaiq,  by  a.  Sa'Id  M.  al-Khadimi   (after  1200), 
with  his  own  commentary  on  it,  the  Mandfi'  al-Daqd'iq.     One  of  the 
works  on  uful-al-fiqh  used  in  seminaries  in  Turkey.    "Unquestionably 
the  most  methodical  and  complete  of  text-books  (classiques)"  (Savvas). 

(20)  K.  Irshdd  al-Fukhul,  by  M.  b.  'Ali  b.  M.  al-Shawkani  (1255), 
Cairo,  1909.     A  modern  topical  summary  exposition  of  the  views  held 
by  doctors  of  different  schools,  with  arguments.    The  author  indicates 
the   views   that   deserve   preference,    showing    some   independence   of 
opinion. 

(•21)  Majmu*  Mutftn  Ufuliyyah.  Damascus,  al-Hashimiyyah  (ca. 
1324).  A  collection  of  the  following  four  compendiums :  (a)  Mukhta$ar 
al-Mandr  (see  supra,  no.  14),  by  Zayn-al-dln  a.  al-'Izz  Tahir  b.  H. 
b.  Habib  al-Halabi  (808),  the  Hanifite,  pp.  3-26;  (b)  Waraqdt  (see 
supra,  no.  5),  pp.  27-39.  (c)  Tanqlh  al-Fu$ul  (see  supra,  no.  10),  pp. 
40-79.  (d)  Qawd'id  aI-Us.ul  wa  Ma'dqid  al-Fusiil,  by  Safi-al-dln  al- 
Bagdadi  (739),  the  Hanbalite,  pp.  80-154. 

THE  APPLICATIONS  (F«r«')  OF  LAW  (Fiqh,  Fatdwa) 
I.  HANIFITE 

(1)  K.  al-Khardj,  by  Ya'qub  b.  Ibr.  a.  Yusuf   (182)    (or  Kitab  al- 
Kharaj).     Bulaq.  1303.    It  is  a  valuable  treatise  on  financial  and  polit- 
ical questions  addressed  to  the  calif  Harun-al-rashld. 

(2)  Kutub  Zahir-al-riwayah,  or  Zdhir-al-madh-hab,  or  al-Uful.    They 
are  the  source-books  of  the  Hanifite  school  and  were  written  by  M.  b. 
al-H.  al-Shaybani   (187).     According  to  b.  al-Humam,  unless  M.  indi- 
cates the  contrary,  the  views  stated  in  these  books  are  the  views  of  a. 
Hanifah  and  a.  Yu.,  as  well  as  his  own  (Ibn  'Abidln,  p.  19).    They  are 
the  following:   (a)   Al-Mabsut,  also  called  al-A$l.     The  recension  of 
a.  Su.  al-Juzjani  is  considered  to  be  the  best.    Apparently  this  work  was 
dictated  by  a.  Yu.  and  compiled  by  M.,  with  additions.     This  view  is 
confirmed  by  al-Sarakhsi  (Mabsilt,  part  xvi,  p.  129),  who  says:  "The 
work  was  composed  (a$l  al-tasnif)  by  a.  Yu.  and  put  together  (ta'lif) 
by  M.,  and  therefore  it  was  considered  as  a  composition  (tasnif)   of 
M."    The  different  parts  of  the  Mabsiit,  known  as  "  Book  of  so-and-so," 
were   composed    separately,    and    the   name    Mabsiit    (extended)    was 
given  them  when  they  were  combined.     When,  therefore,  the  doctors 
say,  "  M.  said  in  the  book  of  so-and-so,"  they  only  mean  one  of  those 


i78 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


"  books."  The  style  of  the  Mabsut  is  said  to  be  verbose  with  repeti- 
tions. Many  commentaries  were  written  on  the  Mabsut,  among  others 
by  Shams-al-a'immah  'Abd-al-'azlz  b.  A.  al-Halwani  (or  Halwa'i) 
(448)  and  Shaykh-al-islam  a.  Bakr  Khwaharzadah  ^482).  The  latter 
is  known  as  al-Mabsftt  al-Bakri  (or  al-Kabir?)  (Ibn  'Abidln).  (b) 
Al-Jami*  al-Sagir.  (Printed  on  the  margin  of  Yusuf.)  Is  said  to  con- 
tain 1,532  propositions.  A  greatly  esteemed  work.  Judges  and  muftis 
were  required  to  learn  it  by  heart  as  a  condition  of  appointment.  It 
indicates  the  authorities.  Its  arrangement  and  chaptering  were  made 
later.  According  to  the  Bahr  as  quoted  by  Ibn  'Abidin  (p.  19),  every 
book  of  M.  bearing  the  title  al-Sagir  has  had  the  approval  of  a.  Yusuf, 
and,  on  the  contrary,  books  bearing  the  title  al-Kabir,  such  as 
al-Jdmi'  al-Kabir,  or  al-Musdra'ah  al-Kabir  were  never  submitted  to 

a.  Yu.     (For  more  details,  see  Ibn  'Abidln  and  H.  Khal.)     The  most 
well-known  of  the  many  commentaries  on  it  are  (i)  by  Fakhr-al-Islam 
al-Pazdawi    (482)  ;     (ii)     Fakhr-al-din    al-H.    b.  JMansur    al-Uzjandi 
Qadikhan  (592).    When  the  doctors  say,  "Qadikhan  said  so  and  so  in  the 
al-Jdmi'  al-Sagir"  they  mean  the  commentary  in  question  (Ibn  'Abidin, 
p.  17).    These  commentaries  are  mixed  with  the  text,     (c)  Al-Jdmi' 
al-Kabir,    According  to  H.  Khal.,  it  contains  principles  (muttin  al-dird- 
ydt)  and  niceties  in  legal  deduction  (latd'if  al-fiqh).    Many  commentaries. 
Also  versifications.    Two  supplements  were  written  to  this  work  by  M. 

b.  al-H.,  the  Al-Ziydddt  and  the  Ziyddat  al-Ziydddt.    These,  too,  were 
much  commented  upon,     (d)  Al-Siyar  al-Sagir  wa  'l-Kabir.    The  last 
of  M.'s  works.    Written  after  his  departure  from  'Iraq.    The  author, 
owing  to  his  dispute  with  a.  Yusuf,  in  quoting  him  does  not  mention 
his  name,  but  says:  "A  trustworthy  person  (thiqah)  informed  us"  (H. 
Khal.).     The  Siyars  treat  the  subject  of  Jihdd.     Many  commentaries 
were  written. 

(3)  K.  al-Hiyal  al-Shar'iyyah,  by  a.  Bakr  A.  b.  'Umar  al-Kha§saf 
(261),  Cairo,  1316  (b.  Tumart,  p.  32).     The  most  well-known  of  the 
works  written  on  lawful  tricks.    Al-Khassaf  also  wrote  a  K.  al-Khardj 
for  the  calif  al-Muhtadi ;  the  best  known  of  the  works  on  the  duties 
and   functions  of  the  judges,  the  K.  Adab  al-Qdd.i,  and  a  standard 
work  on  pious  foundations,  the  K.  Ahkdm  al-Waqf. 

(4)  Al-Mukhtasar  H  'l-Fiqh,  by  a.  Ja'far  A.  b.  M.  al-Tahawi  (321). 
In  two  sizes.    Follows  the  arrangement  of  the  Mukhtasars  of  al-Mu- 
zani.    Many  commentaries  were  written  on  it. 

(5)  Al-Kdfi  n  'l-Fiqh,  by  M.  b.  M.  al-Marwazi  al-Hakim  al-Shahid 
(334).    This  work  combines  the  works  of  M.  b.  al-H.  already  mentioned, 
and  is  an  authority  for  determining  the  views  of  a.  Hanlfah  and  his  two 
disciples.     A   famous  commentary  on   it  is  the  Mabsut    (vol.  ii)    by 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


179 


Shams-al-a'immah_a.  Bakr  M.  b.  a.  Sahl  al-Sarakhsi^  (483),  Cairo,  1323, 
in  30  parts.  There  are  many  Mabsuts,  but  when  the  word  occurs  with- 
out any  qualification  this  work  is  meant.  The  commentary  is  mixed 
with  the  text.  The  work  was  dictated  by  the  author  in  prison.  He 
says  in  the  preface  that,  seeing  that  many  of  his  contemporaries  en- 
gaged in  controversy  or  subtle  dialectics,  or  subordinated  legal  (fiqh) 
considerations  to  philosophical  ones,  he  attempts  to  base  the  legal 
principles  on  legal  considerations  pure  and  simple.  The  arguments 
used  by  later  doctors  almost  always  are  found  in  the  Mabjut. 

(6)  Al-Muntaqa,  also  by  al-Marwazi.     It  has  disappeared  in  later 
times.     (H.  Khal.)     The  author  is  to  have  culled  his  work  from  about 
300  sources,  such  as  dictations,   (Anidli)   and  works  of  the  Nawddir 
class.     Apparently  the  Muntaqa  is  designed  to  make  use  of  the  legal 
determinations  of  the  Nawddir  class  which  were  not  included  in  the 
Kdfi.    The  secret  of  its  disappearance  may  lie  in  this  fact. 

(7)  Al-Mukhta$ar  fi  'l-Fiqh,  by  a.  '1-H.  'Ubayd-allah   b.  al-H.  al- 
Karkhi  (340). 

(8)  Mukhtasar  fl/-Quduri,  by  a.  '1-Hu.  A.  b.  M.  al-Quduri,  al-Bagdadi 
(428).    Kazan,  1896.    A  compendium  of  very  great  reputation.     It  is 
referred  to  as  "  The  Book."     It  has  been  said  that  the  person  who 
commits  it  to  memory  becomes  secure  from  poverty,  and  that  the  per- 
son who  studies  it  under  a  pious  teacher  and  invokes  upon  him  on  the 
completion  of  his  studies  God's  blessing,  acquires  as  many  dirhatns  as 
there  are  legal  determinations  (ntasd'il)  in  the  book.    These  are  said 
to  be  12,000.     (H.  Khal.)     Some  of  its  commentaries  are:  (a)  by  A. 
b.  M.  al-Aqta'  (475).     (b)  Zdd  al-Fuqahd',  by  M.  b.  A.  al-Isbljabi  (ca. 
530).     (c)  Al-Mujtabi,  by  Najm-al-din  Mukhtar  b.  Mahmud  aj-Zahidi 
(658),  author  of  the  Qunyat  al-Munyah.     (d)  Al-Yandbi1  fi  Ma'rifat 
al-Ustl  wa  'l-Tafdrl',  by  Badr-al-din  M.  b.  ' Al. Toshiba   (769).     (e) 
Al-Sirdj  al-Wahhdj,  by  a.  Bakr  b.  'AH  al-Haddadi^al-'Abbadi   (800). 
(f)  Al-Jawharah  al-Nayyirah,  abridged  from  the  former  by  the  same 
author.    Well  known,     (g)  Jdmi'  al-Mu^mardt  wa  'l-Mushkildt,  by  Yu. 
b.  'Umar  al-Sufi  al-Karuzi.    Th)  ALBaydn~\>y  M.  b.  Rasul  al-Muqani. 

(9)  Al-Muhit,  known  as  al-Muhit  al-Ratfawi  or  al-Muhit  al-Sarakhsi, 
by  Raji-aJ-din  M.  b.  M.  al-Sarakhsi   (544).     In  three  sizes.     Unless 
there  is  indication  to  the  contrary,  the  name  stands  for  the  large  size 
of  this  Muhit  as  distinguished  from  the  next  Muhit.    The  author  gath- 
ered together  in  his  work  all  the  legal  determinations   (masd'il)   with 
their  motives  and  meanings.    He  first  mentions  the  cases  of  the  Mabsut, 
then  the  Nawddir,  then  the  Al-Jdmi',  then  the  Ziydddt. 

(10)  Al-Muhit  al-Burhdni  fi  'l-Fiqh  al-Nu'mdni,  by  Burhan-al-din 
Mahmud  b.  A.  b.  al-Sadr  al-Shahid  al-Bukhari  b.  Mazah   (ca.  570). 
This  Muhit  is   sometimes   confused    with   the  previous,   which   is  the 


180  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

more  standard  of  the  two.  This  is  a  larger  work  than  the  previous, 
utilizing  the  works  of  M.  b.  al-H.  as  well  as  the  legal  decisions  arrived 
at  by  later  jurists  (fatdwa  and  wdqi'dt),  such  as  his  own  father.  It 
often  gives  the  arguments. 

(11)  Badai'  al-Sand'V  fi  Tartib  al-Shard'i',  by  Ala'-al-din  a.  Bakr  b. 
Mas'ud  al-Kasani    (vol.  ii)    (or  al-Kashani)    Malik  al-Ulama'    (587). 
Cairo,  1327.    Apparently  it  is  based  on  the  Tuhfat  al-Fuqaha    of  his 
teacher   Ala'-al-din    M.   b.   A.   al-Samarqandi,   who   according   to   the 
author  is  the  only  jurist  who  before  him  took  pains  to  arrange  (tartib} 
the  legal  material.    The  arrangement  of  the  work  is  highly  schematic. 
It  quotes  the  views  of  al-Shafi'i,  and  sometimes  of  Malik,  with  their 
arguments,  mentioning  the  Hanifite  arguments  last. 

(12)  ^/-Hidayah  (vol.  ii),  by  Shaykh-al-islam  Burhan-al-din  'Ali  b. 
a.  Bakr  al-Marginani  (593).    It  is  a  commentary  on  the  author's  own 
Biddyat  al-Mubtadi.    One  of  the  most  esteemed  Hanifite  compendiums. 
Concerning  it,  it  has  been  said  in  a  verse  that,  like  the  Koran,  it  abro- 
gated (naskh)  its  predecessors.    The  work  may  be  said  to  be  a  com- 
mentary on  the  al-fdmi'  al-Sagir  and  on  the  Mukhtasar  of  al-Quduri,  on 
which  two  works  is  based  the  Biddyat  al-Mubtadi.    The  author,  as  a 
rule,  mentions  the  opinion  and  argument  of  Abu  Hanlfah  after  that  of 
his  disciples,  unless  it  be  that  he  sides  with  the  latter.     When  the 
author   says,   "He  said  in   the  Book    (kitdb)"  he   means   al-Quduri. 
When  the  latter  disagrees  with  the  al-Jdmi'  al-Sagir,  the  author  ex- 
pressly indicates  the  difference.    Al-Shafi'i's  differences  and  the  argu- 
ments of  each  side  are  mentioned.    Commentaries:   (a)  Al-Nihdyah,  by 
his  disciple  Husam-al-dm  Hu.  b.  'Ali  al-Signaqi    (710)  ;    (b)    Mi'rdj 
al-Dirdyah,    by    Qiwam-al-din    M.    b.    M.    al-Bukhari    al-Kaki    (749). 
Gives  the  opinions  of  the  four  Itndms,  their  grounds,  the  old  and  re- 
cent views,  etc.     (c)   Gdyat  al-Baydn,  by  Amir  Katib  b.  Amir  'Umar 
al-Itqani    (758).      (d)    /4/-'Inayah    (vol.   ii),   by   Akmal-al-din    M.    b. 
Mahmud  al-Babarti  (786).    Esteemed  in  Turkey  and  one  of  the  best. 
It  is  an   abridgment   for  purposes  of  instruction   of  his  own  larger 
al-Nihdyah.    Contains  useful  analytical  summaries,     (e)  Fath  al-Qadir 
(vol.  ii)T  by  Kamal-al-din  M.  b.  'Abd-al-Wahid  b^al-Humam    (861). 
Esteemed  for  its  independence  of  view.    The  Path  al-Qadir  was  con- 
densed by  Ibr.  al-Halabi  with  criticisms,     (f)  ^/-Kifayah  (vol.  ii),  by 
Jalal-al-din  b.  Shams-al-dm  al-Khawarizmi  al-Kurlani.     The  Hiddyah, 
the  Path  al-Qadir  and  the  Kifdyah,  with  the  'Indyah  and  the  glosses 
of  Sa'd-allah  b.  'Isa  Sa'di  Tchelebi  or  Sa'di  Efendi  (945)  on  the  mar- 
gin, have  been  printed  together.    Cairo,  1901,  9  vols. 

(13)  Al-Fard'id  al-Sirdjiyyah,  by   Siraj-al-din   a.   Tahir   M.   b.   M. 
al-Sajawandi  (towards  end  of  6th  cent.).    This,  with  its  commentary 
al-Sharifiyyah,  by  al-Sayyid  al-Shanf  'AH  b.  M.  al-Jurjani  (804),  are 
the  standard  works  on  inheritance. 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  jg! 

(14)  Al-Hdwi  al-Qudsi,  by  al-Qatfi  Jamal-al-din  A.  b.  M.  al-Gaznawi 
(600),  called  so  because  written  in  Jerusalem  (Quds).    In  three  parts, 
on    (i)    dogma   (u^ul-al-din) ,    (ii)    ujul-al-fiqh,  and    (iii),  by   far  the 
largest,  fiqh  proper. 

(15)  Wiqdyat  al-Riwdyah  fi  Masail  al-Hiddyah,  by  Burhan-al-din 
(-shari'ah)    Mahmud   b.    Sadr-al-Shari'ah    al-Awwal   'Ubayd-allah    al- 
Mahbubi   (around  680).     A  compendium  based  on  the  Hidayah,  with 
omission  of  the  reasons  and  indication  of  the  right  views,  made  for  the 
benefit  of  his  grandson,  'Ubayd-allah  b.  Mas'ud.     Commentaries:    (a) 
By  'Ubayd-allah  b.  Mas'ud  al-Mahbubi  (747).    This  is  the  most  well- 
known   of   the   commentaries,     (b)    By   'Abd-al-latif   b.    'Abd-al-'azlz 
b.   al-Malak    (around   830).     Abridgment:    al-Nuqdyah   or  Mukhta$ar 
al-Wiqdyah,  by  'Ubayd-allah  b.  Mas'ud  b.  Taj-al-sharl'ah  Mahmud  b. 
Sadr-al-shari'ah  al-Thani  al-Mahbubi  (747).     A  well-known  commen- 
tary on  the  latter  is  the  Jami*  al-Rumus,  by  Shams-al-dln  M.  al-Quhis- 
tani  (950).    Kazan,  1315-16.    It  is  used  as  basis  for  rendering  fatwas 
in  the  countries  east  of  the  river  Oxus  (ma  ward'  al-nahr)  (H.  Khal.). 
Ibn  'Abidin,  however,  would  not  allow  the  use  as  basis   for  fatwas 
of  books  like  the  Jdtni',  the  Durr  and  the  Ashbdh,  which  besides  being 
later   compilations   are  often   very   concise,   and   at   times   cite   views 
which  have  found  no  favor  (tnarjuh)  in  the  school,  or  even  views  of 
other  schools.     The  Jdmi'  gives  no  arguments  but  is  rich  in  details. 
Printed  with  the  Jdnd'  is  an  introduction  to  it  by  Qadizadah   Sharif 
Makhdum  b.  'Abd-al-rahlm  al-Bukhari. 

(16)  Al-Mukhtdr_  (li  'l-Fatwa\  by  a.  al-Fadl  Majd-al-din  'Al.  b. 
Mahmud  al-Mawsili   (b.  al-Buldaji)    (683).     Another  of  the  esteemed 
texts.    Al-Ikhtiydr  is  a  commentary  on  it  by  the  same  author.    It  gives 
the  motives. 

(17)  Majma'  al-Bahrayn  wa  Multaqa  al-Nahrayn,  by  Muzaffar-al-din 
A.  b.  'Aii  b.  al-Sa'ati  al-Bagdadi  (696).    An  "esteemed"  text,  based  on 
the  Mukhtasar  of  al-Quduri  and  the  Manzumah  of  al-Nasafi   (537), 
with  additions.     Extremely  concise,  hence  easy  to  commit  to  memory, 
but   difficult   of   understanding    (H.   Khal.).     It   indicates   the   differ- 
ences of  Abu  Hanlfah's  disciples  as  well  as  those  of  al-Shafi'i  and  Malik 
by  some  clever  device,  such  as  the  use  of  the  nominal  instead  of  the 
verbal  sentence,  etc.    Commentaries:    (a)  By  the  author  himself,     (b) 
Al-Manba',  by  A.  b.  Ibr.  al'Unnabi  (767).     (c)  By  'Abd-al-latif  b.  al- 
Malak.    Much  used. 

(18)  Kanz  al-Daqd'iq,  by  Hafiz-al-dir^a.  '1-Barakat  'Al.  b.  A.  al-Nasafi 
(710).    An  abridgment  of  his  own  al-Wdfi  (modeled  after  the  Hiddyah 
and  commented  upon  by  the  author  himself  in  the  Kdfi).    One  of  the 
esteemed  texts  (mutun  tnu'tabarah},  namely  the  texts  which  are  based 
on  Zdhir-al-riwdyah  sources  only   (Ibn  'Abidin,  pp.  36-7).     Commen- 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 

taries:  (a)  TabyinjiI-Haqd'iq,  by  Fakhr-al-din  'Uthman  b. 'Ali  al-Zayla'i 
(743).  Bulaq,  13113-15.  Very  esteemed.  It  inquires  at  length  into  the 
differences  of  al-Shafi'i  and  refutes  his  arguments  from  the  Hanifite 
standpoint.  With  glasses  by  Shihab-al-din  A.  b.  Yunus  al-Shilbi  (947), 
printed  on  the  margin,  (b)  Rams  al-Haqd'iq,  by  a.  M.  Mahmud  b.  A. 
al-'Ayni  (855).  (c)  By  Mu'in-al-din  M.  b.  Ibr.  Mulla  Miskln  al-Harawi 
(before  960).  Used  in  instruction  in  the  Azhar.  Glosses  thereon  by  M. 

a.  al-Su'ud  al-Misri  entitled  Faih-allah  al-Mu'in  embodying  the  glosses 
of  A.  b.  M.  al-Hamawi.    Gives  the  fatwas  of  later  times  and  is  rich 
in  details,     (d)    ^/-Bahr  al-Raiq   (vol.  ii),  by  a.   Hanifah  al-Thani 
(the  second)  Zayn-al-'abidin  (or  din)  b.  Ibr.  b.  Nujaym  al-Misri  (970). 
Cairo,  1893,  8  vols.     One  of  the  most  esteemed  of  later  works.    The 
author  gives  briefly  the  motives,  makes  many  keen  inquiries   (tahrir) 
and  incorporates  the  principles  involved  in  new  fatwas.    The  preface 
contains   a  list  of  the   author's   sources.     The  8th   vol.   contains   the 
Takmilah  of  M.  b.  Hu.  al-Turi,  covering  the  parts  of  the  Kanz  left 
uncommented-upon  by  Zayn-al-'abidln.     Printed  on  the  margin  is  the 
Minhat  al-Khdliq  by  M.  Amln  b.  'Abidin.    Exolains  the  difficulties  only, 
(e)  Al-Ndhr  al-Fd'iq,  by  Siraj^aTdin'7Umar  b.  Ibr.  b.  Nujaym  al-Mi§ri 
(1005).    Completed  until  the  chapter  on  habs  in  the  book  on  Qadd'. 

(19)  Purar  al-Hukkdm    (883),  by  M.  b.   Faramurz  b.  'AH   Mulla 
Khusrew  (885).     A  commentary  on  his  own  Gurar  al-Ahkdm.    Con- 
stantinople,  1299.     Enjoys  especial  favor  in  Turkey.     Used  in  semi- 
naries.   The  author  shows  independence  of  opinion.    This  fact  explains 
why  Ibn  'Abidin  (pp.  36-7)  would  not  place  it  among  the  esteemed  texts. 
Commentaries  and  glosses:   (a)   By  Qinallzadeh  (979).     (b)  Naqd  al- 
Durar,  by  M.  b.  Mustafa  al-Wanquli  (1000).     (c)  Glosses  by  Mustafa 

b.  Pir  M.   'Azmizadeh    (1040).     Very  esteemed,     (d)    By  Isma'il  b. 
'Abd-al-gani  al-Nabulusi  (1062).    Very  extensive  in  12  vols.     (c)   By 
H.  al-ShurunbuTaliT(  1069) .     (f)  Natd'ij  al-Naggr  fi  Hawdshi  al-Durar, 
by  Nuh  Efendi  b.  Mustafa  (1070).    (g)  By  Mustafa  b.  'Uthman  al-Kha- 
dimi.     (h)    Safinat  al-Durar.     Compiled  by  some  seminary  teachers 
(mudarris)  from  fatwa  collections  and  commentaries  on  the  Hiddyah. 
Turkish  translation  by  Su.  b.  Weli  al-Anqirawi. 

(20)  Multaqa  al-Abhur,  by  Ibr.  b.  M.  al-Halabi  (956).    Contains  the 
determinations  of  al-Quduri,  the  Mukhtdr,  Kanz,  Wiqdyah,  and  partly 
the  Majma'  and  the  Hiddyah.    It  indicates  the  views  to  be  preferred 
(asahh).    At  present  it  is  the  standard  Hanifite  text  (main).    A  com- 
mentary on  it  is  the  Majma'  al-Anhur,  by  'Ar.  b.  M.  Sheykhzadeh  (1078). 
Constantinople,    1308.     An    all-round   well-known    commentary.     This 
commentary  is  known  as  Ddmdd  and  used  in  seminaries  in  Turkey  (H. 
Khal.,  vol.  vi,  p.  608;  Heidborn).    A  Turkish  Translation  by  Hamldi. 
Ragib  with  a  commentary  by  M.  al-Mawqufati. 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  l$^ 

(21)  <4/-Ashbah  wa  'l-Nasd'ir,  by  Zayn-al-'abidin  b.  Nujaym  (970). 
Cairo,  1904-    The  only  Hanifite  work  where  general  legal  principles  are 
discussed  for  their  own  sake  and  not  incidentally  to  the  legal  deter- 
mination of  cases.    Probably  the  best  source  for  obtaining  a  knowledge 
of  the  extent  to  which  Hanifite  legal  discussion  becomes  strictly  scien- 
tific.    Author  is  not  a  pioneer  in  this  respect  (cf.  H.  Klial.,  p.  313), 
for  he  admits  to  have  followed  the  examples  of  Taj-al-dln  al-Subki 
(771),  the  Shafiite.    The  work  treats,  in  seven  sections  (/onn),  of  gen- 
eral   principles    (qazvaid    kulliyyah,    extensively    drawn    upon    in    the 
Majallah),  similarities,  differences,  niceties,  legal  tricks,  etc.     An  ar- 
rangement of  it  under  the  usual  fiqh-book  chapters  is  the  K.  Ithaf  al- 
Absar  wa  'l-Ba§air  bi  Tabwib  K.  al-Ashbdh,  etc.,  by  M.  a.  al-Fath. 
Alexandria,  1289. 

(22)  Tanwir  al-Abfdr  wa  Jam?  al-Bihdr  (995),  by  Shams-al-din  M. 
b.  Al.  al-Gazzi  al-Timirtashi   (1004).     It  combines  the  standard  texts. 
Ibn  'Abidln  does  not  consider  it  as  an  esteemed  text.    Commentaries: 
(a)  Mlnah  al-Gaffdr,  by  the  author  himself,     (b)  ^/-Dnrr  al-Mukhtdr 
(1071),  by  Ala'-al-din  M.  b.  'Ali  al-Ha§kafi  (1088),  mufti  at  Damascus^ 
Bombay,    1309.     Condensed   from   his   larger  commentary    (10  vols.), 
Khasd'in  al-Asrdr  wa  Badd'i'  al-Afkdr.    Very  concise  and  full  of  de- 
tails.    Utilizes    new    fatwas.      A    commentary    on    this    work    is    the 
Radd  al-Mukhtdr  by  M.  Amln  b.  Abidln  (1252).    This  work  may  be 
said  to  be  the  last  word  in  the  authoritative  interpretation  of  Hanifite 
law.     It  shows  originality  in  attempting  to  determine  status  of  present 
practical  situations,  as  a  rule,  shunned  by  others.    Author  shows  a  com- 
plete mastery  of  his  subject.    Very  much  used  in  Turkey,  less  in  India. 

(23)  Artifc  Qdnun-ndmeh-si  Sherhi.    A  commentary  in  Turkish  on 
the  Ottoman  land  code  by  Hu.  Husni,  late  professor  in  the  Imperial  Law 
School  of  Constantinople.     Constantinople,   1324.     The  Ottoman  land 
code  promulgated  as  law  in  1274  is  a  compromise  between  the  rules  of 
fiqh  and  customary  law. 

(24)  Majallah^/tfcaw  'Adliyyah.    It  is  an  official  Turkish  codification 
of  Hanifite  law  made  in  1285  by  a  special  Committee  (Mejelleh  Jem'l- 
eti)   under  the  chairmanship  of  Ahmed  Jewdet  Pasha.     It  represents 
the  last  stage  in  the  development  of   Hanifite  doctrines.     The  com- 
mittee's  report   is   worth    reading.     Commentary:     Durar   al-Hukkam 
Sharh  Majallat  al-Ahkdtn,  by  Khoja  Emin  Efendi  Zadeh  'Ali  Haydar. 
Constantinople,  1330,  4  vols.     (In  Turkish.)     It  is  the  best  and  most 
scholarly  work  of  its  kind.    Used  as  text-book  at  the  Constantinople 
Law  School  and  by  lawyers  and  judges. 

(25)  Fara'id  al-Fard'id.  by  Mahmud  As'ad  b.  Emm  Seydi   Shehri, 
professor  at  the  Imperial  Law  School  at  Constantinople.     A  work  in 
Turkish  on  inheritance  based  on  the  Sirdjiyyah.    Constantinople,  1326. 


184  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

FATWA  COLLECTIONS:  (1)  K.  al-Nawdsil,  by  a.  al-Layth  Nasr 
b.  M.  al-Samarqandi  (376).  Said  to  be  the  first  work  combining  the 
legal  determinations  (masd'il)  of  later  doctors  (mashd'ikh),  such  as  M. 
b.  Shuja'  al-Thalji,  M.  b.  Muqatil  al-Razi,  M.  b.  Salamah  (278),  a.  Bakr 
al-Iskaf,  and  al-faqlh  a. ^Ja^far  M.  b.  'Al.  al-Hinduwani  (362).  The 
work  also  contains,  under  the  heading  of  'Uyun  al-Masd'il,  legal  opin- 
ions reported  from  early  doctors  (ashdb)  which  were  not  recorded  in 
Zdhir-al-riwdyah  or  other  sources. 

(2)  Majma'  al-Nawdzil  wa  'l-Wdqi'dt,   by   a.   al-'Abbas   A.   b.    M. 
al-Natifi  (446).    A  work  of  similar  nature. 

(3)  Al-Wdqi'dt,  or  al-Wdqi'dt  al-Husdmiyyah,  by  Husam-al-din   (or 
Husam)  tJmar  b.  'Abd-al-'azlz  b.  Mazah  al-Sadr  al-Shahld  al-Bukhiri 
(536).    Combines  the  two  previous  with  the  fatwas  of  a.  Bakr  M.  b» 
al-Fadl  and  the  Fatdwa  Ahl  Samarqand,   indicating   the  sources   by 
letters.     Also  by  same  author,  the  al-Fatdwa  al-Sugra  and  al-Kubra, 
which  latter,  judging  from  the  identity  of  contents  (cf.  H.  Khal.  under 
Wdqi'dt  and  Fatdwa  Kubra)   is  probably  the  Wdqi'dt  under  another 
name. 

(4)  Khuldsat  al-Fatdwa,  by  Tahir  b.  A.  Iftikhar-al-din  al-Bukhari 
(542).     Combines   the  fatwas  of   later   mujtahids  and   those  of   the 
founders. 

(5)  Dhakhirat  al-Fatdwa,  or  al-Dhakhirah  al-Burhdniyyah,  by  Bur- 
han-al-din  Mahmud  b.  A.  b.  al-,Sadr  al-Shahid  b.  Mazah  (ca.  570).    An 
esteemed  work.    According  to  the  author,  it  contains  the  fatwas  ren- 
dered by  al-Sadr  al-Shahld  Husam-al-din  and  by  himself  in  his  youth 
and,  later,   during  his   stay  at   Samarqand,  with   additions    from   the 
Nawddir  and  later  sources  (H.  Khal.). 

(6)  Al-Fatdwa  al-'Attdbiyyah,  or  Jdmi'  al-Fiqh,  by  a.  Nasr  A.  b.  M. 
al-'Attabi  (586). 

(7)  Fatdwa  Qddihdn,  also  called  al-Khdniyyah,  by  Fakhr-al-din  al-H, 
b.  Mansur  al-Uzjandi  al-Fargani  Qadikhan    (592).     Calcutta,   1835,  4 
vols.    A  standard  work  of  enduring  reputation.    The  Vade  Me  cum  of 
judges  and  muftis.    Author  draws  upon  the  views  of  later  doctors,  as 
recorded  in  the  fatwa  collections  mentioned,  as  well  as  those  of  the 
founders  of  the  school  recorded  in  the  Zdhir-al-riwdyah  and  the  Nawd- 
dir, in  giving  the  legal  answer  to  cases  of  common  occurrence.    Hence  a 
mine  of  information  for  sociological  study.     In  case  there  are  many 
views  by  later  doctors,  he  only  mentions  two,  his  preference  first. 

(8)  Al-Tajnls  wa  'l-Masld,  by  Burhan-al-din  'Ali  b.  a.  Bakr  al-Mar- 
ginani    (593).     Author    claims   to   have   carried   the   arrangement   of 
al-Sadr  al-Shahld's  work  on  fatwas  (apparently  his  Wdqi'dt}  further, 
by  classifying   (tartib),  also  the  particular  opinions  within  the  books 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  ^5 

(kutub),  and  to  have  enlarged  it  with  additions  from  other  sources. 
The  work  enjoyed  wide  use  owing  to  its  serviceableness.  Author  also 
wrote  the  (K.)  Mukhtdr(-dt)  al-Fatdwa  (-Nawdzil). 

(9)  Al-Fatawa  al-Zahiriyyah,  by  Zahir-al-din  a.  Bakr  M.  b.  A.  (619). 
Contains  the  most  needed  cases. 

(10)  Al-Fatdwa   al-Walwdlijiyyah,    by    a.    '1-Makarim    Zahir-al-din 
Ishaq  b.  a.  Bakr  al-Walwaliji  (710).    Condensed  from  the  fat-was  of 
Husam  al-Shahid,  with  additions. 

(11)  Khisdnat  al-Muftiin,  by  al-Hu.  b.  M.  al-Sam'ani  (740).     Indi- 
cates the  accepted  views,  contained  in  previous  sources,  omitting  con- 
troversial matters. 

(12)  Al-Fatdwa  al-Tdtdrkhdtnyyah,  by  'Alim  (al-A'lam)  Ibn  Ala-al- 
din  (about  800).     ( C '/.  Ahhvardt.)     It  is  a  great  work  combining  the 
Muhit  al-Burhdni,  the  Dhakhirah,  the  Khdniyyah,  and  the  Zalilriyyah, 
with  an  introduction  on  science   (/j'/w).     Arranged  according  to  the 
chapters  of  the  Hiddyah.    Written  by  order  of  the  ruler  Tatarkhan; 
hence  the  name.    Ibr.  al-Halabi  (956)  extracted  from  it  the  fatwas  that 
were  not  mentioned  in  current  fatwa  collections. 

(13)  Jdmi'  al-Fufulayn,  by  Badr-al-din  Mahmud  b.  Ism.  (or  Isra'il) 
Qadj  Simawnah  (ca.  818).    Combines  the  Fu$ul  al-'hnddi  (by  'Abd-al- 
rahim  b.  a.  Bakr  al-Marglnani;  around  670)  andFt^u/  (M.  b.  Mahmud) 
al-Ustrushani  (632),  with  additions  and  nice  points.    It  deals  with  the 
practical  part  (Mu'dmaldt)  of  fiqh  only  and  is  used  by  judges  in  par- 
ticular. 

(14)  Al-Fatdwa  al-Bazzdsiyyah,   or   al-Jdmi'   al-lVajiz,   or   Fatdwa 
al-Kardari,  by  M.  b.  M.  al-Bazzazi  al-Kardari   (827).     It  contains  the 
"cream"  of  previous  works  and  is  relied  upon.    Abu  '1-Su'ud,  the  mufti, 
when  asked  to  compile  a  collection  of  the  important  fatwas,  is  said  to 
have  answered :  "  Would  I  not  be  ashamed  of  the  author  of  Bazsd- 
ziyyah  when  he  has  written  his  book? — for  it  is  a  venerable  collection 
containing  the  points  of  importance,  as  is  proper." 

(15)  Fatdwa,  Zayniyyah  are  in  reality  essays  on  matters  of  practical 
interest  (such  as  the  status  of  the  lands  of  Egypt,  istis.hdb,  land  con- 
cessions, Khardj,  etc.)  by  Zayn-al-'abidin  b.  Ibr.  b.  Nujaym  al-Migri 
(970)  as  collected  and  arranged  by  his  son  A.,  with  additions. 

(16)  Fatdwa  a.  al-Su'ud,  by  a.  al-Su'ud  M.  b.  M.  al-'Imadi  (982-3). 
In  Turkish.    Lived  in  the  reign  of  the  sultan  Su.,  the  Magnificent.    His 
fatwas  throw  light  on  adaptation  of    shari'ah  to  practical  requirements, 
particularly  as  regards  land.    A  collection  of  the  same  by  Weli  al-Aske- 
libi  Weli  Yekan,  also  containing  fatwas  by  others,  is  current  (H.  Khal.). 

(17)  Mugni  al-Mustafti'  an  Su'dl  al-Mufti  (or  al-Fatdwa  al-Hdmi- 
diyyah),  by  Hamid  Efendi  b.  M.  al-Qunawi  (985).    (But  cf.  Ahlwardt.) 
A  practical  work,  but  too  long.    An  extract  with  modifications  is  the 


!86  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

Al-'Uqud  al-Durriyyah  fi  Tanqlh  al-Fatdwa  al-Hdmidiyyah,  by  M.  Amm 
b.  'Abidin  (1258).  Bulaq,  1300.  Ibn  'Abidm  draws  upon  his  previous 
works,  such  as  the  Radd  al-Mukhtdr,  Minhat  al-Kltdliq,  and  Essays 
(Rasd'il).  A  useful  work,  in  the  form  of  questions  and  answers. 

(18)  Fatdwa  Khayriyyah,  by  Khayr-al-din  b.  A.  al-Fariiqi  al-Ramli 
(1081),  collected  by  his  son  and  one  of  his  students.    2d  ed.     Bulaq, 
1300.    Consists  in  reasoned  answers  to  actual  questions. 

(19)  Wdqi'dt  al-Muftnn,  by  'Aq.  b.  Yu.  Qadri  Efendi  (after  1088). 
Bulaq,  1300.     A  compact  guide  for  common  cases  as  settled  by  pre- 
vious authorities. 

(20)  Fatdwa  al-Anqirawi,  by  Shaykh-al-Islam  M.  b.  Hu.  al-Anqirawi 
(1098).     Gives  most  of  the  accepted  decisions  and  is  relied  upon  by 
doctors  and  jurists. 

(21)  Fatdwa  'Ali  Efendi,  by  Shaykh-al-Islam  'AH  Efendi  Jataljawi 
(1103).    Constantinople,  1323.     (In  Turkish.)     Well  known.    Consists 
in  actual  fatwas.    Contains  the  arguments  derived  later  by  Salih  b.  A. 
al-Kaffawi  from  the  Arabic  sources.     Printed  on  the  margin  are  the 
Fatdwa  Faydiyyah  by  Shaykh-al-islam  Fayd-allah  Efendi. 

(22)  Al-Fatdwa  oZ-'Alamkiriyyah,  compiled  upon  the  order  of  the 
sultan  Muhyi-al-dm  'Alamklr  Ewrenkzlb  (ruled  from  1069-1118)  by  a 
commission  under  the  chairmanship  of  Shaykh  Nizam.    Calcutta,  1243. 
The  work  is  meant  to  be  exhaustive  and  to  dispense  with  the  need  to 
refer  to  other  fatwa  collections.    It  enjoys  in  India  the  highest  esteem. 

(23)  Fatdwa  'Abd-al-rahim,  by  Shaykh-al-islam  Menteshzadeh  'Abd- 
al-rahim  Efendi  al-Bursawi  (1128).    Constantinople,  1827.    An  esteemed 
large  collection  in  Turkish.    Contains  many  fatwas  on  modern  matters 
such  as  the  agrarian  relations. 

(24)  Fatdwa  Hammddiyyah  (1241),  by  Mawlana  a.  '1-Fath  Rukn  b. 
Husam   al-Nakuri.     A  compact  work  of  the  ' ' Alamklriyyah  type.     It 
gives  in  preface  a  long  list  of  sources. 

II.  SHAFIITE 

(1)  K.  o/-Umm  (vol.  ii),  by  M.  b.  Idris  al-Shafi'i  (204).  Recension 
of  al-Rabi'  a.  M.  b.  Su.  al-Muradi.  Bulaq,  1321.  There  is  also  a  re- 
cension by  al-H.  al-Za'farani,  one  of  al-Shafi'i's  Bagdad  disciples,  which 
has  gone  into  oblivion.  The  Mab$ut  referred  to  by  the  Fihrist  must  be 
the  old  Bagdad  version  of  the  Umm,  since  the  chapters  tally.  Appar- 
ently the  K.  al-Hujjah  which  al-Shafi'i  is  said  to  have  composed  in  Bag- 
dad (Tah-dhlb,  p.  61)  is  another  name  for  the  recension  of  al-Shafi'i's 
Bagdad  teachings.  In  the  long  list  of  the  works  ascribed  to  al-Shafi'i 
in  Yakut  neither  title  is  mentioned.  Evidently  these  names  were  given 
by  al-Shafi'i's  students  when  they  collected  his  teachings.  The  Umm 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  ify 

is  a  valuable  source  for  the  study  of  law.  It  is  full  of  hadiths  and 
contains  many  repetitions.  There  are  abridged  recensions  (mukhta$ar) 
of  al-Shafi'i's  doctrines  by  Al-Rabi',  a.  Ya'qub  al-Buwayti,  and  a.  Ibr. 
Ism.  b.  Yahya  al-Muzani  (264).  The  Mukhtasar  of  al-Muzani  is  the 
most  widely  known  of  them.  It  is  printed  on  the  margin  of  the  Umm. 
Al-Nawawi  speaks  of  it  as  one  of  the  five  widely-used  books  at  his 
time,  the  other  four  being  the  Muhadh-dhab,  the  Tanbih,  the  Wasit 
and  the  IVajiz,  to  be  mentioned  later.  The  Mukhta$ar  of  al-Muzani 
hardly  deserves  its  name,  for  it  is  still  large,  often  literally  quoting  the 
Umm.  Many  commentaries  were  written  on  it,  notably  by  a.  al-Tayyib 
al-Tabari,  M.  b.  A.  al-Shashi.  and  Zakariya'  b.  M.  al-An§ari.  There  is 
a  smaller  compendium  by  al-Muzani,  called  Nihdyat  al-Ikhtijdr,  where 
he  often  indicates  his  own  views,  which  in  many  instances  disagree 
with  those  of  al-Shafi'i  (Subki,  p.  244).  The  opinions  of  al-Shafi'i 
cited  in  the  Umm  and  the  other  recensions  of  his  teachings  in  Egypt 
are  called  his  recent  (jadid)  opinions  in  distinction  from  his  older 
views  (qadim)  contained  in  recensions  of  his  teachings  in  Bagdad, 
such  as  the  K.  al-Hujjah. 

(2)  Al-Hdwi  al-Kobir,  by  a.  al-H.  'AH  b.  M.  al-Mawardi  (450).    An 
exhaustive   treatise   of    fiqfi.     A    condensation    of   it   is    the   author's 
al-Iqndt.    Al-Mawardi  is  said  to  have  written  the  Iqndf  upon  the  order 
of  the  calif  al-Qadir-bi-'llah  in  competition  with  al-Quduri,  the  Hanifite. 
a.  M.  'Abd-al-wahhab  b.  M.,  the  Malikite,  and  a  Hanbalite.    The  story 
says  that  al-Mawardi  was  the  winner.     (Yaqut,  vol.  v,  p.  406.) 

(3)  Al-Ahkdm  al-Sultdniyyah,  by  the  same  al-Mawardi.     Ed.   Max 
Enger,  Bonn,   1853.     This  is  a  justly  renowned  work  giving  the  de- 
scription of  an  ideal  state.     Some  of  the  subjects  it  covers  are  not  to 
be  found  elsewhere,  as  the  author  himself  points  out  in  his  conclusion. 
The  treatment  is  schematic  and  clear-cut,  as  regards  content,  in  many 
cases,  closely  following  upon  al-Shafi'i's  Umm.    The  views  of  a.  Hani- 
fah  and  Malik  are  mentioned.    The  motives  are  not,  as  a  rule,  gone  into. 
Strictly  speaking,  it  is  not  a  work  of  fiqh  proper.    In  so  far  as  it  treats 
questions  of  fiqh,  it  does  so  from  the  standpoint  of  the  state.     The 
first  part  of  the  work  (the  first  107  out  of  432  p.)  has  been  translated 
into  French  by  L.  Ostrorog,  Paris.  1901-6. 

(4)  ^/-Tanbih,  by  a.  Ishaq  Ibr.  b.  'Ali  al-Shirazi  (476).    Ed.  A.  W. 
T.  Juynboll,  Leyden,  1879.     A  well-known  compendium  which  may  be 
said  to  have  eclipsed  its  predecessors,  though  itself  has  had  a  similar 
fate.    Clear  and  detailed.    The  best  known  of  the  commentaries  on  it 
is  that  by  Badr-al-din  M.   (b.  Bahadur)   b.  'Al.  al-Zarkashi.     Al-Mu- 
hadh-dhab  fi  'l-Madh-hab  is  another  well-known  work  of  al-Shirazi, 
formerly  much  used.    It  gives  the  arguments  and  difficult  points. 

(5)  Nihdyat  al-Matlab  fi  Dirdyat  al-Madh-hab,  by  a.  '1-Ma'ali  'Abd- 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 

al-Malik  b.  a.  M.  'Al.  al-Juwayni,  Imam-al-haramayn  (478).  An  exten- 
sive work  in  40  parts,  "  such  as  has  not  been  composed  in  Islam  its 
like"  (Ibn  Khallikan  in  H.  Khal.).  (H.  on  S.) 

(6)  Al-Basit,  by  Hujjat  al-islam  a.  Hamid  M.  b.  M.  al-Gazzali  (505). 
Based  on  the  Nihdyat  al-Matlab  of  his  teacher  Imam-al-Haramayn. 
Al-Waslt  al-Muhlt  bi  Aqtdr  al-Basit  is  a  condensation  of  the  former 
by  the  author  himself.    One  of  the  five  books  referred  to  by  al-Nawawi 
as  being  in  use.    Al-W&jiz,  by  the  same  author;  a  condensed  compen- 
dium based  on  the  former,  with  additions.    Cairo,  1317.    Also  one  of 
"  the  five  books,"  and  the  best  known  of  his  works  on  fiqh.     It  is  an 
excellent   schematic  summary  of   all   the   Shafiite  views,  independent 
(aqwdl)    or  deduced    (wajh),  the  authors   responsible   for   them  not 
being  mentioned.    The  differences  of  al-Muzani,  a.  Hanifah  and  Malik 
are  indicated  by  letters.    The  best  known  of  the  commentaries  on  the 
Wajiz  is  the  Path  al-'Asls  'ala  K.  al-Wajis,  by  a.  al-Qasim  al-Rafi'i 
(623).    Al-Rawdah,  by  al-Nawawi,  is  an  abridgment  of  it. 

(7)  Ihyd'  'Uliim  al-Din,  by  the  same  al-Gazzali.     Bulaq,  1289.     Al- 
though it  contains  many  chapters  of  fiqh,  the  book  is  not  strictly  a 
book  on  fiqh  but  has  a  larger  scope.    It  is  meant  by  the  author  as  a 
plea  for  the  regeneration  of  religion,  and  represents  a  reaction  against 
its  increasing  secularization.     It  gives  valuable  sidelights  into  existing 
conditions.      It    treats    in    four    parts    (rub'),    questions    of    worship 
('ibdddt),  personal  manners,  character,  and  social  relations.     "It  has 
been  said  about  this  book  that  if  the  books  of  Islam  were  destroyed 
except  the  Ihyd',  it  would  dispense  with  those  destroyed"  (H.  Khal.). 

(8)  Al-Taqrib  fi  'l-Fiqh,  or  Mukhtasar  a.  Shuja    (also  called  Gdyat 
al-Ikhtisdr},  by  a.  Shuja'  A.  b.  al-H.  al-Igfahani  (593).    Brief  and  clear. 
The  most  widely-spread   Shafiite  compendium    (S.).     Commentaries: 

(a)  Al-Iqna  fi  Hall  A  If dz  a.  Shuja,  by  M.  b.  al-Khatib  al-Sharbini  (977). 

(b)  Fath  al-Qarib  al-Mujib  fi  Shark  Alfdz  al-Taqrib,  also  called  Al- 
Qawl  al-Mukhtdr  fi  Sharh  Gdyat  al-Ikhtisdr,  by  M.  b.  al-Qasim  al-Gazzi 
(981).    Publ.  with  French  translation  by  Van  den  Berg,  Leyden,  1895. 
It  is  elementary,  explaining  chiefly  questions  of  grammar  and  syntax. 
Used  by  students  in  Java.     Glosses  on  it  by  Ibr.  b.  Qasim  al-Bajuri 
(1278).    Cairo,  1901.    They  consist  in  his  lectures  in  the  Azhar  and  are 
used   as  text-book.     Author  wrote  his   glosses  because  the  previous 
glosses  by  Ibr.  b.  M.  al-Birmawi  (1106),  known  as  al-Muhash-shi  (S.), 
though    complete,   contained    difficult   passages.     Goes    at   length    into 
grammatical  and  syntactical  details.    Very  useful  for  beginners.     (For 
criticism  of  Bajiiri  by  Hurgronje,  cf.  De  indische  Gids,  1884.) 

(0)  Minhaj  al-Tdlibln,  by  Muhyi-al-dln  a.  Zakariya'  Yahya  b.  Sharaf 
al-Nawawi  (676),  an  improved  abridgment  of  the  Muharrar  by  a. 
'1-Qasim  'Abd-al-kanm  b.  M.  al-Rafi'i  (623),  a  well-known  work  based 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  !89 

on  the  works  of  al-Gazzali  (H.  on  S.).  It  is  a  standard,  concise,  clear 
text  of  great  fame.  It  indicates  by  a  clever  terminology  (see  its  pref- 
ace) the  original  views  (na$s  or  qawl)  of  al-Shafi'i  as  well  as  the  views 
(wajh,  qawl  mukharraj)  deduced  by  his  followers  by  analogy.  Publ. 
by  Van  den  Berg  with  a  French  translation.  Batavia,  1882-84.  Com- 
mentaries: (a)  By  Jalal-al-din  M.  b.  A.  al-Mahalli  (864).  Goes  into 
the  arguments,  (b)  Tuhfat  al-Mukhtdj  li  Shark  al-Minhdj,  by  A.  b.  M. 
b.  II ajar  (973).  Cairo,  1290.  (c)  Mugni  al-Mukhtdj  ila  Ma'rifat  Mafdni 
Alfdz  al-Minhdj,  by  M.  b.  al-Khatib  al-Sharbini  (977).  Cairo,  1308. 
A  fairly  exhaustive,  useful  work,  giving  in  a  concise  manner  most  of  the 
matter  found  in  other  commentaries.  It  indicates  the  views  that  have 
found  acceptance  and  gives  briefly  the  motives,  but  does  not  go  into 
syntax  and  grammar,  (d)  Xihdyat  al-Mukhtdj  ila  Shark  al-Minhdj,  by 
Shams-al-din  M.  b.  A.  al-'Ramli  (1004),  with  glosses  printed  on  the 
margin  by  A.  b.  M.  'Abd-al-razzaq  al-Rashidi  (wrote  in  1086)  and 
a.  al-Diya'  'Ali  b.  'AH  al-Shabramallisi  (1087).  Cairo,  8  vols.  Indi- 
cates clearly  the  views  that  have  been  endorsed  by  the  Sham'te  school. 
By  "qdld"  (they  two  said)  he  maans  the  "two  imdms,"  namely 
al-Rafi'i  and  al-Nawawi,  by  "al-Shdrih"  (the  commentator),  Jalal-al-din 
al-Mahalli,  and  by  "  al-Shaykh,"  Zakariya'  al-Ansari.  The  Muharrar 
and  the  Minhdj  with  its  two  commentaries,  the  Tukfah  and  the  Nihdyah, 
"are  considered  as  the  Law  books  of  the  Shafiite  school"  (H.  on  S.). 

(10)  Manhaj  al-Tulldb,  by  a.  Yahya  Zakariya'  b.  M.  al-An§ari  (926). 
An  abridgment  of  the  Minhdj  which  itself  became  classical  and  is  to- 
day used  in  instruction  (S.).    A  well-known  commentary  on  it  is  the 
Path  al-Wahhdb  by  the  author  himself.     Glosses  by   Su.  al-Bajirmi 

(1221). 

(11)  Tahrir  al-Tanqlk,  by  the  same  Zakariya',  an  extract  from  the 
Tanqlh  al-Lubdb  of  a.  Zur'ah  (b.)  al-'Iraqi  (826),  with  some  additions, 
controversial  matter  being  left  out.    The  Tanqth  itself  was  a  conden- 
sation of  the  Lubdb  of  a.  al-H.  A.  b.  M.  aj-Mahamili  (415).    A  com- 
mentary on  the  Tahrir  is  the  Tuhfat  al-Tulldb  by  Zakariya'  himself. 
Glasses  thereon:   (i)  by  al-Madabigi   (1170);   (ii)  by  'Al.  al-Sharqawi 
(1227).    Very  much  favored.     Used  by  students  in  the  Azhar   (S.). 
Printed  with  notes  by  al-Sayyid  Mustafa  al-Dhahabi  on  the  margin, 
Bulaq,  1891. 

(12)  Asna  al-Matdlib,  by  the  same  Zakariya'  al-Ansari.    A  commen- 
tary on  the  Rawd  al-Tdlib  by  Sharaf-al-din  Ism.  b.  a.  Bakr  b^aJ^Muqri 
(837).     Printed  with  glosses  by  Shihab-al-din   a.   al-' Abbas  A.  b.  A. 
al-Ramli   (957).  Cairo,  1895.     Very  much  like  the  Mugni,  though  not 
quite  so  exhaustive. 

(18)  Qurrat  al-Ayn  (982),  by  Zayn-al-din  al-Malibari.    A  commen- 
tary on  it  by  the  author  himself  is  the  Path  al-Mu'in.    Glosses  on  it: 


190 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


Tdnat  al-Tdlibin,  by  Sayyid  Bekri  a.  Bekr  Shatta',  a  Mecca  professor. 
Cairo,  1884,  4  vols.  Gives  the  recent  fatwas.  The  works  of  this  group 
are  very  much  used  in  East  Africa  and  British  and  Dutch  Indias  (H. 
on  S.). 

FATWA  COLLECTIONS:  (1)  Fatdwa  b.  al-Saldh,  by  'Uthman  b. 
'Ar.  b.jd-Salah  (642),  collected  by  his  disciples.  Very  useful.  (H.  Khal.) 
("2)  'Uyun  al-Masd'il  al-Muhimmdt,  by  Yahya  b.  'Sharaf  al-Nawawi 
(676),  in  two  sizes.  Answers  on  actual  cases.  (3)  Fatdwa  b.  Firkdb, 
by  a.  M.  'Ar.  (b.)  Ibr.  al-Fazari  al-Firkah  al-Misri  (690).  ("4)  Fatdwa 
al-Zarkashi,  by  Badr-al-din  M.  b.  Bahadur  al-Mi§ri  al-Zarkashi  (794). 
(5)  Fatdwa  al-Ramli,  by  'Shihab-aWin  a.  al-'Abbas  A.  b.  A.  al-Ramli 
(957),  edited  by  his  son  Shams-al-din  M.  b.  A.  al-Ramli  (1004). 
Printed  on  the  margin  of  the  al-Fatdwa  al-Kubra.  (6)  Al-Fatawa  al- 
Kubra  al-Haytamiyyah  al-Fiqhiyyah,  by  A.  b.  M.  b.  Hajar  (973).  Cairo, 
1890,  1308.  Answers  to  actual  questions  with  long  arguments. 

III.  MALIKITE 

(1)  (Al-Masd'U)  o/-Mudawwanah  (vol.  ii).  Recension  of  Qa^Ji 
Sahnun  a.  Said  b.  'Abd-al-salam  al-Tanukhi  (240).  Cairo,  1323-24.  It 
consists  of  questions  by  Sahnun  and  answers  by  'Ar.  b.  al-Qasim  (191), 
a  student  of  Malik  for  20  years.  These  answers  as  a  rule  repeat  the 
literal  words  of  Malik,  though  at  times  they  are  b.  al-Qasim's  own  in- 
terpretation of  the  same.  The  Mudawwanah  is  a  revision  by  b.  al-Qasim 
of  the  Asadiyyah  of  Asad  b.  al-Furat,  when  it  was  submitted  to  b. 
al-Qasim  by  Sahnun,  who  had  studied  the  Asadiyyah  under  Asad. 
Asad  having  failed  to  incorporate  the  corrections  of  b.  al-Qasim  as  found 
in  Sahnun's  copy,  the  Asadiyyah  fell  into  oblivion.  After  b.  al-Qasim's 
death,  Sahnun  incorporated  in  his  copy  hadiths  in  support  of  some  of 
the  views  and  improved  its  arrangement.  Mukhtalitah  is  another  name 
given  to  the  Mudawwanah  (Fihrist  al-Ishbili,  p.  240,  seems  to  confirm 
this),  though  in  another  version  it  is  the  name  given  to  the  A sadiyyah  on 
account  of  Asad's  having  studied  previously  the  Hanifite  law  also.  (Cf. 
Ibn  Khaldfin,  Vincent,  Mudawrwanah,  vol.  i,  p.  12;  Kharashi,  'Adawi, 
vol.  i,  p.  38.)  The  Mudawwanah  is  the  greatest  Malikite  authority. 
Its  relation  to  other  books  has  been  likened  to  that  of  the  opening 
chapter  (al-Fdtihah)  of  the  Koran.  The  Malikites  by  "The  Book" 
mean  it.  The  Mudawwanah  found  special  favor  among  the  Moham- 
medans of  W.  N.  Africa  (Ifriqiyah)  (such  as  b.  Yunus  and  al-Lakhmi) 
(Ibn  Khaldfin),  who  showed  great  zeal  in  studying  and  commenting 
on  it. 

("2)  Al-JVadihah,  by  a.  Marwan  'Abd-al-malik  b.  Habib  al-Sulami 
(238),  of  Spain,  who  studied  under  b.  al-Qasim  and  spread  the  Malikite 
doctrines  in  Spain.  The  Wddihah  naturally  found  favor  in  Spain. 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  lgl 

(3)  Al-Mustakhrajah   min   al-Asmi'ah  al-Masmu'ah    mm   Malik   b. 
Anas,  known  as  Al-'Vtbiyyah,  by  M.  b.  A.  al-'Utbi  al-Qurtubi   (255), 
student  of  b.  Habib.    This  work  superseded  the  Waftbah  and  itself  be- 
came an  object  of  study  and  comment  (Ibn  Khaldun).    The  commen- 
tary on  it  by  M.  b.  A.  b.  Rushd  (520)  deserves  mention.    It  is  entitled 
K,  al-Baydn  iva  'l-Tahs.il  wa  'l-Sharb  wa  'l-Tawjlh  wa  'l-Ta'lil  fi  Masd'il 
al-Mustakhrajah.    (Cf.  Prof. C.  A. iNallino's  "  Intorno  de  Kitdb  al-Baydn 
del  Giuristo  Ibn  Rushd  "  in  the  Homenaje  a  D.  Fr.  Codera,  Zaragoza, 
1904.)     Arranged  in  the  conventional  fiqh-book  chapters.    The  author, 
after  citing  the  questions  and  Malik's  answers  and  e.  g.  the  view  of  b. 
al-Qasim,  introduces  his  own  view  by  "Qdl  M.  b.  Rushd,"  supporting 
it  by  lengthy  arguments.    A  valuable  source-book  for  determining  the 
development  of  the  school.    The  Mudawwanah,  IVddijiah  and  'Utbiyyah, 
with  the  Mawdziyyah  of  M.  b.  Ibr.  b.  al-Mawaz  (281),  a  student  of 
b.    'Abd-al-Hakam     (cf.    Husn    al-Muhdd.arah,    p.    169),    are    called 
al-Ummahdt,  i.  e.,  the  mother  books.    The  last  work  does  not  seem  to 
have  spread  as  widely  as  the  others.    Ibn  Khaldun  does  not  mention  it. 
Some  would  add  to  this  list  also  the  following:  (a)  al-Majmu'ah,  by 
M.  b.  'Abdus  (260;  but  cf.  Brockelmann,  p.  177)  ;  (b)  al-Mabsutah,  by 
a.  Ishaq  al-Qadi  Ism.  b.  Ishaq  (282),  of  Bagdad  (cf.  Vincent).    All  of 
them  are  necessarily  very  long  and  badly  arranged  and  uncoordinated. 

(4)  Tah-dhib,  by  a.  Sa'id  al-Barada'i.     It  is  a  condensation  of  the 
Mudawwanah  and  the  Mukhtalitah  which  found  great  favor  »vith  the 
jurists  of  Ifriqiyyah  and  superseded  its  predecessors.     (Ibn  Khaldun; 
cf.  also  b.  Tumart,  p.  41.)     Al-Maqqari  (vol.  ii,  p.  122)  reads  as  follows 
concerning  a  K.  al-Tah-dhib  by  al-Baradha'i  al-Saraqusti :  "As  regards 
(books  of)   fiqh,  the  book  that  is  relied  upon  at  present,  and  the  one 
that  is  designated  by  the  Malikites  as  far  as  Alexandria  as  the  Book,  is 
tbe  Tah-dhib  of  al-Baradha'i  al-Saraqusti."     (Brockelman  speaks  of  a 
Tah-dhib  Masd'il  al-Mudawwanah  wa  'l-Mukhtalitah  (372)  by  a  certain 
Khalaf  b.  a.  al-Qasim  al-Bagdadi,  a  student  of  b.  a.  Zayd.    It  may  be 
the  same  book.) 

(5)  K.  al-Nawddir,  by  'Ubayd-allah  b.  'Ar.  b.  a.  Zayd  al-Qayrawani 
(386).    It  combines  the  previous  works. 

(6)  Al-Rlsdlah  is  by  the  same  b.  a.  Zayd.    Cairo,  2d  ed.,  1905.    It  is 
a  clear,  brief  compendium — said  to  be  the  first  in  the  Malikite  school — 
covering  also  questions  of  catechism  and  meant  to  be  a  guide  for  the 
layman.     It  is  a  compendium  of  great  authority  that  has  been  copied 
and  commented  upon  more  than  any  other.     (Vincent.)     The  author 
also  wrote  a  Mukhta$ar,  where  he  abridged  the  Mudawwanah  and  the 
Mukhtalitah.    (Ibn  Khaldun.) 

(7)  Abu  Bakr  M.  b.  'Al.  b.  Yunus  al-Tamlmi  al-Saqali  (451)  wrote  a 
commentary  on  the  Mudawwanah  where  he  included  the  greater  part 


192 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


of  b.  a.  Zayd's  Nawddir.    Ibn  Yunus'  originality  of  thought  consisted  in 
indicating  (tarjih)  the  views  to  be  preferred. 

(8)  K.  al-Tabsirah,  by  a.  al-H.  'Ali  b.  'Al.  al-Lakhmi  (478).    It  is  a 
well-known   Ta'liq  on   the  Mudawwanah.     Al-Lakhmi's   characteristic 
has  been  his  independence  of  view  (ikhtiydr). 

(9)  Al-Muqaddamdt  al-Mumahhaddt  li  Bay  an  ma  Aqtadat-hu  Rusum 
al-Mudawwanah  min  al-Ahkdm  al-Shar'idt  wa  'l-Tahsildt  al-Muhkamdt 
li  Ummahdt  Masd'iliha  al-Mushkildt  (Ibn  Rushd,  M.),  by  a.  al-Walid 
M.  b.  A.  b.  Rushd  al-Qurtubi  (520),  grandfather  of  the  famous  phil- 
osopher b.  Rushd  (Averroes).    Cairo,  1907.    It  indicates  the  etymology 
and  the  justification  of  the  words  and  meanings  of  the  Mudawwanah. 
Treatment  analytical.    Ibn  Rushd  distinguished  himself  by  singling  out 
the  true  reports  (riwdyat)  from  Malik  ('Adawi,  p.  41). 

(10)  Abu  'Al.  M.  b.  'Ali  al-Tamlmi  al-Maziri   (536),  known  as  the 
Imam.    He  is  another  famous  doctor  who  commented  on  the  Mudaw- 
wanah.    Al-Maziri  distinguished  himself  by  his  generally  accepted  in- 
dependent views  (qawl).    Ibn  Yunus,  al-Lakhmi,  b.  Rushd  and  al-Maziri 
are  the  four  authorities  whose  opinions  are  mentioned  and  authorship 
is  specified  by  Khalil  in  his  famous  Mukhtasar. 

(11)  Mukhtasar,  by  a.  'Amr  'Uthman  b.  'Umar  b.  al-Hajib   (646). 
This  is  a  compendium  that  combines  all  the  Malikite  views  and  was 
much  read  in  the  Magrib  in  the  days  of  Ibn  Khaldun.    It  was  commented 
upon  among  others  by  M.  b.  'Abd-al-salam  al-Umawi   (wrote  in  799), 
b.  Rushd,  and  Khalil  b.  Ishaq  (the  Tawdlh). 

(12)  Biddyat  al-Mujtahid  wa  Nihdyat  al-Muqtasid  (Ibn  Rushd,  B.), 
by  a.  al-Walid  M.  b.  A.  b.  Rushd  al-Qurtubi,  well  known  as  b.  jRushd 
al-Hafid  (the  grandson)    (595).    Cairo,  1329.    The  work  was  written 
by  the  author  in  order  to  enable  the  jurists  to  decide  cases  for  which 
the  shari'ah  did  not  provide.     It  is  a  masterly  analysis  of  the  main 
issues  at  law  with  the  views  held  by  doctors  of  various  schools  and 
the  grounds  underlying  their  viewpoints  ably  discussed.     The  grounds 
ascribed  by  b.  Rushd  to  the  doctors  do  not,  therefore,  always  tally 
with  those  claimed  by  them. 

(13)  Al-Mukhtasar,    by    Diya'-al-din    a.    al-Safa'    Khalil    b.    Ishaq 
al-Jundi  al-Misri  (767).    Paris,  1318.    It  is  the  most  famous  compen- 
dium of  the  Malikite  school,  and  since  its  writing  virtually  the  most 
authoritative  summing-up  of  the  Malikite  doctrines.    Perhaps  no  com- 
pendium  has   found   such   favorable  reception   as  this.     It  is   said   to 
contain  100,000  explicit  and  as  many  implicit  legal  determinations.    It 
is  an  attempt  to  include  in  the  briefest  possible  compass  the  accepted 
doctrines  of  the   school   on  the  minutest   details,   the  holders  of  the 
opinions  and  the  unsettled  points  being  hinted  at  by  a  clever  use  of 
words  as  explained  in  the  preface.     Probably  here  lies  the  secret  of 


BIBLIOGRAPHY  ig$ 

its  success  despite  the  fact  that  the  work  is  involved  to  an  un- 
heard-of degree  and  absolutely  defies  understanding.  A  French  trans- 
lation of  the  Mukhta$ar,  with  explanatory  phrases  thrown  in  the  text, 
by  Perron,  in  Exploration  scientifique  de  I'Algerie,  Sciences  hist,  et 
gtogr.,  vols.  x-xvi,  Paris,  1848-52.  Commentaries:  (a)  By  Taj-al-dln 
Bahram  b.  'Al.  al-Damiri  (805),  in  three  sizes;  (b)  by  a.  'Al.  M.  b. 
Yu.  al-Mawwaq  al-'Abdari  al-Garnati  (897),  in  two  sizes,  (c)  Fatb 
al-Jalil,  by  M.  b.  Ibr.  al-Tata'i  (942).  Glosses  thereon  by  al-Kharashi 
(lioi).  Jaivdhir  al-Durar  is  another  smaller  commentary  by  al-Tata'i. 
(d)  By  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  MTal-Khattab  (953).  A  large  commentary,  (c) 
By  al-Laqani  (958)  on  the  preface  (khutbah)  with  glosses  by  al-Zar- 
qani  (1099).  (f)  By  a.  al-Naja'  Salim  al-Sanhuri  (1015).  (g)  By 'Ali 
al-Ujhuri  (1066),  in  two  sizes,  (h)  By  'Abd-al-baqi  b.  Yu.  al-Zarqani 
(1099),  with  glasses  by  M.  b.  al-Talib  al-Taudi  (1207).  Bulaq,  1307.  8 
parts.  An  advanced  commentary  going  into  arguments  and  quoting 
views  of  other  commentators  (Vincent).  Also  glosses  by  M.  b.  al-H. 
al-Bannani.  (i)  by  a.  'Al.  M.  al-Kharashi  (vol.  ii)  (noi),  with 
glosses  by  'AH  al-'Adawi  (vol.  ii)  (1189).  Cairo,  1307.  A  very  well- 
known  commentary.  Goes  into  grammatical  and  syntactical  details. 
Does  not  as  a  rule  go  into  arguments.  There  is  also  a  larger  commen- 
tary by  al-Kharashi.  (j)  By  Ibr.  b.  Mar'i  al-Shabrakhiti  (1106),  in 
three  sizes,  (k)  By  A.  b.  M.  al-Dardir  (1201).  Bulaq,  1282.  Glosses 
thereon  by  M.  b.  'Arafah  al-Dasuqi.  Cairo,  1310.  Both  the  commen- 
tary and  the  glosses  are  very  much  esteemed.  (1)  By  M.  'Alish  (1299), 
with  glosses  by  himself.  Printed  in  4  vols.  Bulaq. 

(14)  Tab$irat  al-Hukkdm  fi  U$ul  al-Aqtfiyah  wa  Mandhij  al-Ahkdm, 
by  Ibr.  b.  'Ali  b.  Farhun  al-Andalusi  (799).  Formerly  much  used.  In- 
tended for  judges  especially. 

(16)  Al-Mukhtasar  fi  'l-Fiqh,  by  M.  b.  M.  al-Wargami  al-Tunisi, 
b.  'Arafah  (803). 

(16)  Tuhfat  al-Hukkdm  H  Nukat  al-'Uqud  wa  'l-Ahkdm,  by  a.  Bakr 
M.  b.  M.  b^Asim   (829)   of  Granada.     A  celebrated  compendium  in 
rajas  verse.     it"Ts~brief  and  clear.    Commentaries:    (a)    By  M.  b.  A. 
Mayyarah  al-Fasi.     Cairo,  1807.     (b)   By  'Ali  b.  'Abd-al-salam  Tasuli 
Sabrari.     Bulaq,  1256. 

(17)  Aqrab  al-Masdlik  Ii  Madh-hab  al-Imdm  Malik,  by  a.  al-Barakat 
A.  b.  M.  al-Dardir  al-'Adawi  al-Azhari  (1201).    An  abridgment  of  the 
Mukhtasar  of  Khalll.    Though  not  quite  as  rich  in  details  as  the  latter 
work,  it  is  remarkably  clear  for  a  Malikite  compendium.    Commentary 
by  the  author  himself  known  as  Shark_al-Saglr.    Bulaq,  1281.    Where 
Khalll  indicates  two  views,  al-Dardir  often  gives  only  the  one  pre- 
ferred by  him.     This  work,  and  the  author's  and  al-Kharashi's  com- 
mentaries  on   Khalll,   are  used  by   students   in   the   Azhar    (Iktifd1). 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 

Glosses  by  A.  b.  M.  Al-Sawi  (1241).    Named  Bulgat  al-Sdlik  li  Aqrab 
al-Masdlik.    Cairo,  1903. 

(18)  Al-Majmu'  fi  'l-Fiqh,  by  M.  b.  M.  al-Sunbawi  al-Amir  (1232). 
A  compendium  written  on  the  same  plan  as  that  of  Khalil.  Commen- 
tary and  glosses  by  the  author  himself. 

FATWA  COLLECTION'S :  (1)  Al-Mi'y&r  al-Mugrib  wa  'l-Jdmi' 
al-Mu'rib  'an  Fatdwi  A'ldm  Ifriqiyah  wa  'l-Andalus  wa  'l-Magrib,  by  A. 
b.  Yahya  al-Wanshansi  (914).  (2)  Path  al-Ali  al-Mdlik  fi-'l-Fatwa 
'a/a  Madh-hab  al-Imdm  Malik,  by  a.  'Al.  M.  b.  A.  'Alish  (1299).  2  vols., 
Cairo,  1300.  The  fatwas  given  by  the  author  arranged  in  the  conven- 
tional fiqh-book  chapters. 

IV.  OTHER  SCHOOLS 

HANBALITE:  Dalll  al-Tdlib  fi  Nayl  al-Ma'drib,  by  Shaykh  Mar'i, 
b.  Yu.  (1033).  This  is  the  text  used  by  Hanbalite  students  in  Mecca. 
(Mekka,  vol.  ii,  p.  249.) 

SHI'ITE:  SharaV  al-Isldm  (between  436  and  676),  by  Najm-al-din 
Ja'far  b.  M.  al-Hilli  a.  al-Qasim.  A  commentary  on  it  is  the  Masdlik 
al-Afhdm  (964)  by  Zayn-al-dln  b.  'AH  al-Shami  al-'Amili.  A  French 
translation  of  the  Shard'i'  is  A.  Querry's  Droit  Musulman,  Paris,  1871. 
N.  B.  E.  Baillie's  A  Digest  of  Moohummudan  Law,  etc,,  part  ii,  2d  ed., 
London,  1887,  is  based  on  the  same  work. 

V.  BOOKS  ON  DIFFERENCES  OF  MOHAMMEDAN  SCHOOLS 
(Ihktildf  al-Madhdhib) 

(1)  Ikhtildf  al-Fuqahd',  by  a.  Ja'far  M.  b.  Jarir  al-Tabari  (310),  the 
Shafiite.  Ed.  F.  Kern,  Cairo,  1320.  (2)  Ikhtildf  al-Fuqahd',  by  a.  Ja'far 
A.  b.  M.  al-Tahawi  (321),  the  Hanifite.  (3)  Rabmat _al-Ummah  fi  Ikh- 
tildf al-A'immah  (780),  by  Sadr-al-dln  M.  b.  'Ar.  al-Dimashqi  al-'Uth- 
mani,  the  Shafiite.  Bulaq,  1300  (with  the  al-Mlzan  al-Khidriyyah  of 
al-Sha'rani).  (4)  ^/-Mizan  al-Kubra,  by  'Abd-al-wahhab  b.  A.  a^Sha^ 
rani  (973),  the  Shafiite.  2d  ed.,  Cairo,  1318  (the  Rahmat  al-Ummah 
on  the  margin).  An  abridgment  of  it  by  the  author  himself  is  the 
al-Mizdn  al-Khidriyyah.  French  translation  entitled  Balance  de  la  lot, 
etc.,  by  Perron,  Algiers,  1898. 

BOOKS  ON  SECTS  (RELIGIOUS  AND  PHILOSOPHICAL) 

(1)  K.  al-Farq  bayn  al-Firaq  wa  Bay  an  al-Firqah  al-Ndjiyah  minhum, 
by  a.  Mansfir  'Aq.  b.  Tahir  al-Bagdadi  (429),  the  Shafiite.  Cairo,  1328. 
(2)  K.  (al-Fisal  fi}  al-Milal  (wa  'l-Ahwd'}  wa  'l-Nihal,  by  a.  M.  'Ali 
b.  A.  b.  Hazm  (456),  the  Zahirite.  Cairo,  1317.  Polemical.  Goes  into 
lengthy  metaphysical  and  other  arguments.  "This  book  is  from  the 


BIBLIOGRAPHY 


195 


worst  of  books,  and  our  doctors  have  never  ceased  forbidding  its  study 
on  account  of  its  despise  of  the  Sunnites  "  (al-Subki  as  quoted  by  H. 
Khal.).  (8)  K.  al-Milal  wa  'l-Nibal,  by  a.  al-Fath  M.  b.  'Abd-al-karim 
al-Shahrastani  (548).  'Ed.  W.  Cureton,  London,  1842.  Also  printed 
on  the  margin  of  the  preceding  book.  A  compact  work  treating  of 
religious  and  philosophical  sects  in  general  in  a  clear  and  summary 
manner.  Al-Subki  approves  of  this  book.  (H.  Khal.)  (For  further 
details,  cf.  I.  Goldziher,  "  Zur  Litteratur  des  Ikhtildf  ol-Madhdhib," 
ZDMG,  1884,  vol.  38,  pp.  669-82;  d.  Zohiriten,  pp.  37  et  seq.;  F.  Kern, 
"  Tabari's  Ikhtildf  al-Fuqahd1,"  ZDMG,  1901,  vol.  55,  pp.  61-95.) 

MISCELLANEOUS 

(1)  K.  o/-Agani.  by  a.  al-Faraj  'Ali  al-I§fahani  (356).  Cairo,  1285. 
(2)  Belin,  "  fitude  sur  la  propriete  fonciere,"  /.  Asiatique,  1861-62.  (8) 
Bercbem,  Max  van,  La  propriete  territorial  et  fimpot  fancier  sous  les 
premiers  calif  es,  Geneve,  1886.  (4)  Bruno,  H.,  Regime  des  eaux  en 
droit  musulman,  Paris,  1913.  (5)  Caetani,  L.,  Annali  dell'  Islam,  Mi- 
lano,  1905.  A  monumental  work  in  course  of  publication.  Published 
as  far  as  vol.  vii  (year  32).  (6)  Defteri  Muqtasid,  by  Su.  Sudi;  2d 
ed.,  Constantinople,  1307.  (7)  Gatteschi,  D.,  Real  Property,  Mort- 
gage and  Waqj  According  to  Ottoman  Law.  Translated  from  the 
Italian  by  Edw.  A.  Van  Dyck.  London,  1884.  (8)  Ghali,  R..  De  la 
tradition  consider^  comme  source  du  droit  musulman,  Paris,  1909. 
(9)  Goldziher,  I.,  die  (d.)  Zahiriten,  Leipzig,  1884.  (10)  Goldziher,  I., 
"Kampfe  urn  die  Stellung  des  Hadit  im  Isldm"  ("Kampfe").  Z.  D. 
M.  G.,  vol.  61,  pp.  860-72.  (11)  Goldziher,  I.,  Vorlesungen  iiber  den  Islam, 
Heidelberg,  1910.  (12)  Goldziher,  I.,  "  Das  Princip  des  Istisbdb  in  der 
muh.  Gesetzwiss.,"  Vienna  Oriental  Journal,  pp.  228-36.  (18)  Goldziher, 
I.,  "  Muh.  Recht  in  Theorie  und  Wirklichkeit "  Zeits.  fur  vergl  Rechts- 
iviss.,  vol.  viii,  pp.  406-23.  (14)  Ibn  Hisham:  Das  Leben  Muhammad's 
nach  Muhammad  ibn  Ishaq  (151)  bearbeitet  von  'Abd-al-malik  Ibn 
Hischam  (218).  Ed.  F.  Wiistenfeld,  Gottingen,  1858-60.  (16)  Hurgronje, 
C.  Snouck,  "  Le  droit  musulman,"  Revue  de  I'histoire  des  religions,  1898, 
vol.  37,  pp.  i  et  seq.,  and  174  et  seq.  (16)  Hurgronje,  C.  Snouck,  The 
Achehnese.  English  trans,  by  A.  W.  S.  O'Sullivan,  Leyden.  1906.  Based 
on  critical  first-hand  observation.  For  bibliogr.  information  see  vol.  ii, 
p.  9.  (17)  Kohler,  Dr.  J.,  "  Die  Wirklichkeit  und  Unwirklichkeit  des 
islam.  Rechts,"  Zeits.  fur  vergl  Rechtswiss.,  vol.  viii,  pp.  424-32.  (18) 
Maqrizi,  K.,  Al-Mawd'ig  wa  'l-I'tibdr  fi  Dhikr  al-Khitat  wa  'l-Athdr,  by 
a.  al-'Abbas  A.  b.  'Ali.  al-Maqrizi  (845).  Cairo,  1324-26.  (19)  Margo- 
liouth,  D.  S.,  The  Early  Development  of  Mohammedanism,  Lectures  de- 
livered in  the  University  of  London,  New  York,  1914.  (20)  Padel  et 
L.  Steeg,  De  la  legislation  fonciere  ottomane,  Paris,  1904,  (21)  Spren- 
ger,  A.,  "  Eine  Skizze  der  Entwickelungsgeschichte  des  musl.  Gesetzes." 


I95  BIBLIOGRAPHY 

Zeitsch.  fur  vergl.  Rechtsw.,  1892,  vol.  x,  pp.  1-31.  (22)  Worms,  Dr., 
"'Recherches  sur  la  constitution  de  la  propriete  territoriale  dans  les 
pays  musulmans  et  subsidiairement  en  Algerie,"  7.  Asiatique,  1842-44. 
(23)  Yahya:  K.  al-Khardj,  by  Yahya  b.  Adam  b.  Su.  al-Qurashi  (203). 
Ed.  Th.  W.  Juynboll,  Leyden,  1896.  A  valuable  source  written  in  the 
way  of  hadith  collections.  (24)  Young,  G.,  Corps  de  droit  ottoman, 
Oxford,  1005-6.  (25)  Zaydan:  Tdrikh  al-Tamaddun  al-Isldtni,  by  Jurji 
Zaydan,  late  editor  of  the  Hildl;  5  vols.,  Cairo,  1902-6. 


PART  II 
FINANCIAL  THEORIES 


CHAPTER  I 
PRELIMINARY  REMARKS 

"  MOHAMMEDAN,"  as  used  in  these  pages,  does  not  mean 
every  financial  theory  evolved  by  a  Mohammedan  writer; 
nor  does  it  mean  the  theories  evolved  concerning  every 
Mohammedan  financial  practice.  It  means  only  the  theories 
evolved  by  Mohammedan  writers  in  conformity  with  the 
principles  of  shari'ah  on  the  basis  of  the  financial  practices 
of  the  early  Mohammedan  state,  particularly  during  the 
calif  ship  of  Omar.  In  other  words,  only  the  financial  prac- 
tices which  were  sanctioned  by  usage  in  the  early  Moham- 
medan state  and  only  the  financial  theories  treated  in  the 
books  of  fiqh  are  called  "  Mohammedan  ".  Financial  prac- 
tices which  have  not  received  sanction  from  the  early  Mo- 
hammedan state  or  financial  theories  which  have  not  been 
based  on  the  shari'ah,  even  if  practiced  or  written  by  Mo- 
hammedans, remain  outside  the  pale  of  shari'ah  and  may 
not  properly  be  called  "  Mohammedan  ".  This  is  in  strict 
accordance  with  the  usage  of  the  Mohammedan  writers, 
who  in  their  works  on  fiqh  discuss  only  the  "Mohammedan" 
theories  of  finance  and  do  not  treat  the  practices  which 
came  into  Mohammedan  use  later,  except  in  terms  of  sum- 
mary condemnation. 

These  extra-shari'ah  practices  made  their  way  into  Mo- 
hammedan history  rather  early,  and  in  the  course  of  time 
entirely  displaced  the  shari'ah  practices.  The  new  taxes 
resulting  from  the  introduction  of  these  practices  have  been 
given  various  designations,  such  as  hilali,  marafiq,  ma'awin, 
mukus  x  and  'urfi.2 

1  Maqrlzi,  p.  167.  Defteri  Muqtajid,  p.  22. 

199 


200  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Al-Maqrizi,  who  in  his  Khitat  gives  a  detailed  description 
of  the  extra-sharl'ah  taxes  in  Egypt  during  his  time,  states 
that  the  revenue  of  Egypt  at  that  time  consisted  of  the  two 
classes  of  kharaji  (i.  £.,  the  shari'ah  taxes  levied  on  the  non- 
Moslems)  and  hilali  revenue  (mat),  and  condemns  the  latter 
as  instituted  "  one  after  another  by  evil  waits  (gover- 
nors) ".l 

The  author  of  the  Defteri  Muqtasid,2  on  the  other  hand, 
sees  no  objection  to  the  extra-^arf  ah  taxes  on  the  part  of 
the  shari'ah,  when  they  are  not  exorbitant.  In  Mohamme- 
dan histories  frequent  allusion  is  made  in  terms  of  praise 
to  attempts  of  pious  Mohammedan  rulers  immediately  after 
their  accession  to  power  to  remove  the  pernicious  practice 
of  extra-shari'ah  taxes,3  but  the  invariable  refrain  is  that 
the  practice  reappeared.4  Part  II  concerns  itself  exclusively 
with  the  Mohammedan  theories  of  finance  and  has  nothing 
to  do  with  the  eyLtra-shari'ah  taxes. 

The  various  shari'ah  sources  of  revenue  discussed  by  the 
Mohammedan  writers  fall  into  two  well-defined  classes: 
the  class  of  religious  revenue  collected  from  Moslems 
alone;  and  the  class  of  secular  revenue  derived  primarily 
from  non-Moslems.  The  religious  revenue  includes  the 
three  zakat  taxes  constituting  the  so-called  sadaqah  or  zakat 
revenue  and  the  financial  contribution  for  the  conduct  of 
holy  war  and  other  affairs  of  public  interest.  The  three 
zakat  taxes  are  the  zakat  on  flocks  and  herds,  the  zakat  of 
gold  and  silver  and  the  articles  of  trade,  and  the  zakat  of 
the  produce  of  the  earth,  or  tithe.5  The  secular  revenue, 

1  Maqrizi,  p.  166. 

'  P.  24. 

1  Cf.  Maqnzi,  p.  167,  11.  i,  15,  19;  p.  169,  1.  10. 

4  Cf.  ibid.,  p.  167,  1.  17;  p.  169,  1.  13. 

6  As  this  dissertation  deals  primarily  with  the  Hanifite  doctrines,  its 


PRELIMINARY  REMARKS  2Ol 

on  the  other  hand,  comprises  the  kharaj  or  land-tax,  the  jiz- 
yah  or  poll-tax,  the  tax  on  non-Moslem  traders,  the  imposts 
on  spoils,  mines,  and  treasure-trove,  and  the  estates  of  per- 
sons who  died  intestate  and  without  heirs. 

For  the  sake  of  clearness,  these  taxes  are  discussed  under 
two  main  divisions,  one  on  revenue,  and  the  other  on  ex- 
penditure; while  the  subject  of  public  domain,  which 
seemed  to  belong  in  neither  of  these  divisions,  is  treated  as 
a  third  coordinate  division  in  a  chapter  bearing  that  title. 
The  division  on  revenue  includes  discussions  of  assessment 
and  collection,  while  that  on  expenditure  considers  the  prin- 
ciples governing  the  disposal  of  public  funds  and  the  allied 
topics  of  public  treasury  and  budget,  military  stipends, 
grants,  and  public  records.  The  sharp  distinction  between 
the  religious  and  the  secular  revenue  is  indicated  by  the 
separate  treatment  accorded  to  religious  and  secular  reve- 
nue. Owing  to  the  intimate  connection  between  the  prin- 
ciples concerning  the  status  of  persons  and  lands,  on  the  one 
hand,  and  the  kharaj  and  jizyah,  on  the  other,  the  discus- 
sion of  the  latter  has  been  preceded  by  an  explanation  of 
the  former.  The  discussion  of  spoils,  as  a  source  of  reve- 
nue, is  justified  by  the  fact  that  one-fifth  of  them  belonged 
to  the  state,  and  the  remaining  four-fifths  divided  among 
the  soldiers  in  reality  constituted  a  state  expenditure.  This 
is  easy  to  understand  if  it  be  remembered  that  the  conduct 
of  holy  war  was  one  of  the  primary  functions  of  the 
Mohammedan  state  and  the  expense  for  it  had  to  be  pro- 
vided for  by  the  state  in  some  way.  Moreover,  the  four- 
internal  arrangement  has  been  made  to  fit  those  doctrines,  and  there- 
fore need  not  always  be  in  accordance  with  the  Shafiite  and  Malikite 
views.  For  instance,  according  to  the  Shafiites,  and  partly  to  the  Mali- 
kites  also,  the  taxes  levied  on  mines  and  treasure-trove  are  consid- 
ered as  sakat,  and  should  consequently  be  treated  under  the  zakdt  taxes 
rather  than  under  the  secular  taxes  where  they  have  been  treated. 


202  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

fifths  so  divided  might  be  considered  as  an  advance  pay- 
ment on  the  pay  of  the  soldiers  and  a  supplement  to  the 
military  stipends  provided  by  the  state. 

Finally,  in  the  conclusion,  an  analysis  of  the  Mohamme- 
dan theories  of  finance  is  given.  In  this  analysis,  the 
theories  are  taken  entirely  at  their  face  value  and  the  deeper 
philosophy  underlying  them  is  not  discussed. 


CHAPTER  II 
THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  l 

SECTION  I 

General  Principles 

Zakat  literally  means  growth  and  increase  (as  in  the 
phrase  zaka  al-zar' ,  the  crop  grew),  and,  according  to  some, 
purity  (as  in  the  verse  qad  aflaha  man  tazakka?  i.  e.,  verily 
the  pure  ones  prospered).  The  tax  has  been  named  zakat 
with  respect  to  the  first  meaning  of  the  word,  because 
its  giving  leads  to  increase  of  property  in  this  world  and 
growth  of  religious  merit  (thawab)  in  the  next;  and  with 
respect  to  the  second  meaning,  because  its  payment  purifies 
from  sins.  God  said :  "  Take  from  their  property  alms 
(sadaqah)  in  order  thus  to  purify  them  (tusakki-him) 
[from  their  sins]  ".* 

Technically  zakat  is  defined  by  the  Hanifite  doctors  as 
"the  giving4  (tamllk),  as  an  act  of  piety,  of  a  legally 

1  Majma',  p.  157;  Quduri,  p.  20;  Mabsut,  p.  149;  Kasani,  p.  2;  Hiddyah, 
Path,  Kifdyah,  and  'Indyah,  p.  112;  Durar,  p.  112;  Durr,  p.  131;  Jam?, 
p.  297;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  239;  Bahr,  p.  216;  Umm,  p.  2;  Wajlz,  p.  79; 
al-Fatdwa  al-Kubra,  vol.  ii,  p.  32;   Mawardi,  p.  195;  Minhdj,  p.  228; 
Ansari,  p.  338;  Zarqani,  vol.  ii,  p.  41 ;  Ibn  Rushd,  M.,  p.  200;  Ibn  Rushd, 
B.,  p.  225;  Mudawwanah,  p.  2;  Muwattd,  p.  103;  Kharashi,  p.  51. 

2  Koran,  chap.  87,  verse  14. 

3  Ibid.,  chap.  9,  verse  104. 

4  "Giving"  is  used  here  in  the  sense  of  transferring  the  ownership 
of  a  thing. 

203 


204  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

(shar'a)  stated  portion  of  one's  property  to  a  poor  Mos- 
lem who  is  not  of  the  Hashim  family  or  their  clients 
(mawla),  in  such  a  way  as  to  preclude  for  the  giver  any 
sort  of  benefit."  *  Zakat  also  means  the  thing  so  given. 
Sadaqah  is  another  name  for  zakat.  The  general  usage, 
however,  is  to  consider  sadaqah  as  a  more  generic  term 
applying  to  the  alms  whose  payment  is  a  fard  (obliga- 
tion), as  well  as  to  the  alms  the  giving  of  which  is  en- 
tirely voluntary  (tatawwu').  In  other  words,  while  every 
zakat  is  also  sadaqah,  only  the  sadaqah  which  is  a  fard  is 
zakat.  Al-Shafi'i  and  al-Mawardi,  on  the  other  hand,  claim 
that  there  is  no  distinction  between  the  two  terms  and  that 
they  both  denote  the  same  thing.2 

The  giving  of  zakat  by  Moslems  is  a  fard  based  on  evi- 
dence found  in  the  Koran,  the  sunnah,  the  ijma'  and  in 
reason.  In  the  Koran  zakat  is  set  down  as  the  third  faith 
(thalithat  al-tman)  as  becomes  evident  from  these  divine 
words:  "and  if  they  [i.  e.,  the  infidels]  have  repented  and 
performed  the  prayers  and  paid  the  zakat ,  they  are  your 
brethren  in  religion."  3 

In  the  sunnah,  zakat  is  reckoned  as  one  of  the  five  "pillars 
of  faith  ".  The  Prophet  said :  "  Islam  has  been  built  on 
five  [things],  namely,  testimony  that  there  is  no  God  but 
the  God,  the  performance  of  the  prayers,  the  giving  of 
zakat ,  the  fast  during  the  month  of  Rajnadan,  and  the  pil- 
grimage to  Mecca  when  one  can  afford  it."  4 

It  is  justified  in  the  ijma' ' ,  because  the  entire  Mohamme- 
dan community  has  agreed  upon  zakat 's  being  a  fard.5 

Finally,  it  is  supported  by  reason,  because  the  giving  of 

1  Majma',  p.  157. 

1  For  details  see  Part  III. 

3  Koran,  chap.  9,  verse  II. 

4  Mabsut.  p.  149.  '  Kasani,  p.  3. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  205 

zakat  is  an  assistance  to  the  poor  and  enables  them  to  per- 
form their  religious  obligations — to  help  perform  a  fard  is 
itself  a  fard — and  because  the  giving  of  zakat  purifies  one's 
morals  by  inculcating  habits  of  generosity  and  greathearted- 
ness  and  by  eradicating  those  of  niggardliness,  since  it  is  a 
fact  that  possession  of  property  leads  one  to  greed.1  Ac- 
cording to  the  Mulut,  failure  to  believe  that  zakat  is  a  fard 
entails  unbelief  (kufr),  and  refusal  to  practice  it  involves 
the  death  penalty.2 

The  cause  (sabab)  of  zakat's  being  a  wajib  3  is  the  pos- 
session in  full  ownership  (milk  tamm)  of  a  productive 
(nami)  nisab  (minimum)  of  property.  This  is  based  on  the 
divine  words  :  "Take  from  their  properties  sadaqah".  "Prop- 
erty is  a  cause  of  zakat  not  per  se,  but  in  so  far  as  it  con- 
tributes to  the  wealthiness  of  the  owner,  for  the  Prophet 
said  to  Mu'adh :  '  Tell  them  that  God  has  prescribed  for 
them  sadaqah,  to  be  taken  from  the  rich  among  them  in 
order  to  be  given  to  their  poor '.  But  wealthiness  results 
only  from  the  possession  of  a  definite  quantity  of  wealth, 

1  Ibid.  The  Bahr  (p.  217)  objects  to  the  sunnah,  and  especially  to 
reason  being  invoked  as  evidence  for  sakdt's  being  a  fard. 

*'AlaMkiriyyah,  p.  239. 

8  It  will  be  noticed  that  while  in  the  previous  paragraph  the  giving  of 
zakdt  was  referred  to  as  a  fard,  here  the  cause  of  sakdt's  being  a  wdjib 
only  is  discussed.  Most  of  the  Hanifite  texts  follow  this  usage.  The 
commentators  explain  the  discrepancy  in  two  ways:  (i)  The  giving  of 
zakdt  is  called  a  fard  because  it  is  based  on  positive  evidence  (dalit 
qat'i).  On  the  other  hand,  it  is  spoken  of  the  cause  of  sakdt's  being 
a  wdjib  only,  because  in  certain  respects  it  is  based  on  presumptive 
evidence  alone  (dalll  sanni).  (Majma',  p.  157;  'Indyah,  p.  113.)  (2) 
In  this  connection  wdjib  is  used  by  extension  in  the  sense  of  fard. 
(Hiddyah,  p.  112;  Kifdyah,  p.  112;  Bahr,  p.  217;  'Indyah,  p.  213.)  Cer- 
tain texts  use  the  word  fard  in  both  instances.  (Durr,  p.  132;  Kasani, 
p.  4.)  However,  this  difference  of  usage  affects  only  the  obligation  of 
believing  in  sakdt  but  not  of  practising  it,  since  in  engendering  an  obli- 
gation for  doing  a  thing  the  fard  and  wdjib  are  on  a  par.  (See  Part  I.) 


206  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

and  this  quantity  is  the  nisab."  However,  the  nisab  be- 
comes a  cause  only  by  virtue  of  productivity,  for  zakat  is  a 
contribution  set  apart  from  superfluous  property,  as  may  be 
inferred  from  this  passage  in  the  Koran  :2  "  And  they 
shall  ask  you  as  to  what  they  shall  bestow  in  alms  (yunfi- 
quna).  Say,  'The  superfluous'."3  And  so  the  cause  of 
zakat  is  the  productive  nisab,  and  the  zakat  is,  therefore, 
referred  to  the  nisab,  as,  for  example,  when  we  say,  "  the 
zakat  of  cattle  ".  Consequently,  when  the  nisab  is  doubled 
the  zakat  is  also  doubled. 

Productivity  (numa')  is  either  real  (tahqlqi),  as  in  pro- 
creation and  trade,  or  hypothetical  (taqdiri),  as,  for  ex- 
ample, in  the  case  where  productivity  has  been  possible, 
though  not  actual,  in  that  the  property  has  been  in  the  pos- 
session of  the  owner  or  his  agent.4  Productivity,  real  or 
hypothetical,  is  considered  to  have  existed  whenever  one  of 
the  following  three  cases  is  present :  ( I )  when  property  is 
gold  or  silver  (naqdan  or  thaman)  ;  (2)  when  animals  are 
pastured  (sawm)  ;  (3)  when  property  is  intended  for  trade 
(niyyat  al-tijarah).5  According  to  the  'Alamkmyyah* 
productivity,  both  real  and  hypothetical,  is  further  classified 
into  natural  (khilqi)  and  artificial  (ffli).  The  first  is  found 
in  gold  and  silver,  which  have  been  created  for  trade  and  in 
themselves  are  not  fit  for  the  satisfaction  of  wants.  Gold 
and  silver  pay  zakat  whether  or  not  they  are  intended  for 
trade  or  personal  consumption.  Artificial  productivity,  on 
the  other  hand,  is  found  in  other  than  gold  and  silver, 

1  Mabsut,  p.  149. 

*  Chap.  2,  verse  217. 
8  Ibid.,  p.  150. 

4  Majnta',  p.  158. 

*  Jdmi',  p.  299. 

*  P.  244.    Zaila'i,  p.  256. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  207 

whenever  there  is  intention  of  trade  or  of  pasture,  provided 
the  intention  in  each  case  is  borne  out  by  an  act  of  trade 
or  pasture. 

Besides  being  productive,  the  nisab  must  also  be  owned 
in  full  ownership  (milk  tamm),  that  is,  ownership  (milk) 
combined  with  possession  (yad).  Consequently,  mere  pos- 
session of  property  does  not  subject  it  to  zakat.  "  For  the 
state  of  wealthiness  does  not  exist  without  ownership 
(  milk),  and  the  productive  property  was  a  cause  for  zakat 
only  by  virtue  of  contributing  to  the  wealthiness  of  the 
owner,  and  when  it  fails  to  do  so  it  is  no  longer  a  cause  [of 
zakat}  ."  According  to  Abu  Hanifah,  neither  does  owner- 
ship without  possession  subject  to  zakat 2  since  the  nisab 
could  not  have  then  been  productive.  Consequently  the 
wife  is  not  subject  to  zakat  on  her  marriage  price  (sidaq) 
before  she  has  received  it,  although  she  owns  it. 

The  nisab,  furthermore,  must  be  over  and  above  what  is 
necessary  for  the  satisfaction  of  the  primary  necessities  of 
life  (hajah  asliyyah),  because  property  destined  for  such 
necessities  is,  as  it  were,  non-existent. 

The  nisab,  finally,  must  be  free  of  debt  subject  to  demand 
of  payment  by  one's  fellow-men  ('ibad), — whether  the  debt 
be  owing  to  them  or  to  God, — as  distinguished  from  debts 
which  are  not  subject  to  demand  on  payment  by  one's  fel- 
low-men, such  as  debts  of  vow  or  sadaqat  al-fitr*  and  which, 
therefore,  do  not  oppose  the  obligation  of  zakat.  Accord- 

1  Mabstt,  p.  164. 

•  Path,  p.  113;  cf.  'Alamkiriyyah,  pp.  241,  245. 

8  Sadaqat  al-fitr  is  a  kind  of  sadaqah  (also  called  zakat  al-fip)  be- 
stowed upon  the  poor  on  the  festival  of  breaking  Lent.  Its  chief  dif- 
ference from  zakdt  is  that,  while  its  settlement  is  morally  just  as 
obligatory  (since  it  is  a  wdjib),  it  does  not  come  under  state  control 
and  lies  entirely  with  the  person  himself.  The  zakdt  al-filr  is  also 
called  zakdt  al-ru'iis  (zakdt  of  heads)  in  distinction  from  the  xakdt 
with  which  we  are  here  concerned  and  which  strikes  property. 


208  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

ing  to  al-Shafi'i,1  indebtedness  does  not  affect  the  obliga- 
tion of  zakat.  According  to  one  Shafiite  view,  however, 
indebtedness  opposes  zakat  in  the  case  of  non-apparent  prop- 
erty. Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,2  indebtedness  ex- 
empts (yusqit3)  from  the  zakat  of  gold  and  silver  ('ayn) 
and  the  articles  of  trade,  though  not  of  crops,  cattle,  and 
mines.  The  argument  of  al-Shafi'i  is  that  the  cause  of  zakat 
is  the  ownership  of  a  complete  nisab  and  the  debtor  possesses 
one.  Moreover,  the  debt  of  a  free  man  attaches  to  his  per- 
son and  does  not  encumber  his  property  which  he  may 
handle  as  he  pleases  and  so  make  productive.  The  Hanifite 
argument  is  as  follows:  The  calif  'Uthman  said  in  his 
address  in  the  mosque  during  the  month  of  Ramadan :  "Be- 
hold, the  month  of  your  zakat  has  come.  Whoever  has 
property  and  debts,  let  him  deduct  from  what  he  owns  what 
he  owes  and  pay  zakat  for  the  remaining  property,"  *  and 
none  of  the  Companions  blamed  'Uthman  for  his  action, 
and  so  it  was  an  ijma'  on  their  part  to  the  effect  that  there 
is  no  zakat  on  the  amount  covered  by  debt.  Besides,  the 
debtor  is  really  a  poor  man  and  the  zakat  is  paid  by  the  rich 
alone.  Furthermore,  the  debtor  deserves  help  himself,  and 
there  is  no  reason  in  taking  from  him  as  a  taxpayer,  for  in- 
stance, a  sheep,  and  then  returning  the  same  to  him  as  a 
beneficiary  of  the  tax.  Finally,  it  cannot  even  be  properly 
said  that  the  debtor  completely  owns  the  nisab,  since  it  is 
affected  by  the  right  of  the  creditor. 

1  Hiddyah,  p.  118;  Umm,  p.  22;  Minhdj,  p.  261. 
1  Kharashi,  p.  106;  Dardir,  p.  124. 

8  The  word  yusqit  means  to  cause  to  lapse,  and  if  its  use  was  ad- 
vised it  would  imply  that  indebtedness  does  not  oppose  the  operation 
of  zakdt  in  the  first  place.  The  Hanifites  and  Shafiites,  however,  ex- 
pressly stand  for  this  last  meaning  by  using  the  expression  yamna'u 
wujubaha,  i.  e.,  the  debt  prevents  the  sakdt  from  becoming  due. 

4  Mabsut,  p.  160. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  209 

There  has  been  dispute  as  to  whether  a  debt  of  zakat 

should  constitute  a  cause  of  exemption.  According  to 
Zufar,  a  debt  of  zakat  is  like  a  debt  of  vow  or  kafffirah,1 
and  does  not  exempt  from  zakat.  In  fact,  it  is  canceled  in 
case  of  death  before  payment,  and  therefore  is  not  really  a 
debt.  Al-Balkhi  establishes  a  distinction  between  the  sakat 
due  on  "  apparent  "  property  and  that  due  on  "  non-appar- 
ent "  property,  holding  that  only  the  zakat  due  on  "  appar- 
ent "  property  exempts  from  zakat,  because,  according  to 
him,  only  the  latter  kind  of  zakat  is  subject  to  demand  of 
payment  on  the  part  of  the  public  collector.  Al-Sarakhsi 
takes  exception  and  claims  that  the  zakat  due  on  both 
"  apparent  "  and  "  non-apparent  "  property  is  alike  subject 
to  demand  of  payment.  He  contends  that,  during  the  time 
of  the  Prophet  and  the  two  califs  after  him,  the  zakat  of 
"  non-apparent "  as  well  as  of  "  apparent "  property  was 
collected  by  the  public  collectors,  and  that  the  third  calif 
'Uthman,  in  order  to  remove  from  the  taxpayers  the  incon- 
venience and  trouble  attendant  on  the  investigation  of  their 
"  non-apparent "  properties  by  evil  collectors,  limited  the 
jurisdiction  of  the  public  collectors  to  the  "  apparent  "  prop- 
erty and  delegated  the  right  of  collecting  the  zakat  of 
"  non-apparent "  property  to  the  property  owners  them- 
selves ;  that,  therefore,  the  zakat  of  "non-apparent"  property 
is  still  subject  to  demand  of  payment  (though  now  by  the 
property  owners  themselves  instead  of  by  the  public  col- 
lectors) and  that  consequently,  the  zakat  on  "non-apparent" 
property,  too,  is  a  cause  of  exemption.  On  the  other  hand, 
according  to  Abu  Yusuf ,  a  zakat  debt  is  cause  of  exemption 
if  the  property  on  which  the  zakat  is  due  is  still  intact,  but 
it  is  not  so,  if  the  property  has  been  destroyed,  because  in 

1  Kaffdrah  is  a  financial  expiation  for  such  sin  as  the  breaking  of 
fast  or  an  oath. 


2io  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

case  the  property  is  intact,  there  is  always  a  possibility  that 
the  owner  may  pass  a  public  collector  with  that  property 
and  so  be  subject  to  demand  of  payment  as  regards  its 
zakat.  It  is  stated  in  the  Mabsut  that,  when  Abu  Yusuf 
was  called  upon  to  show  cause  for  not  assenting  to  Zufar's 
view,  he  replied,  "  What  is  my  cause  against  a  man  who 
makes  one  pay  400  dirhams  of  zakat  for  200  dirhams  of 
property !",  meaning  thereby  that  according  to  Zufar  a  per- 
son owning  200  dirhams  would  have  to  pay  after  80  years 
400  dirhams  of  zakat,  if  he  had  failed  to  pay  the  zakat  for 
each  year  at  the  end  of  the  same.  According  to  the  view 
which  considers  a  zakat  debt  as  a  cause  of  exemption,  the 
zakat  due  on  the  200  dirhams  in  question  would  be  only  one 
year's  zakat,  namely  5  dirhams,  since  after  the  falling  due 
of  the  first  year's  zakat  the  200  dirhams  would  be  affected 
with  the  zakat  debt  of  5  dirhams  for  the  first  year,  and  the 
second  year  no  zakat  would  be  due,  the  condition  of  an  un- 
obstructed nisab  of  200  dirhams  being  absent.1  Abu  Ham- 
fah  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  hold  the  same  view  as  al- 
Sarakhsi. 

Al-Shafi'i,2  with  respect  to  sawaim  animals,  says  that  a 
previous  debt  of  zakat  on  them  exempts  from  zakat,  but  he 
recommends  that  advantage  should  not  be  taken  of  this  ex- 
emption. Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,8  a  debt  of 
zakat,  like  other  debts,  exempts  from  the  zakat  of  gold  and 
silver  and  the  articles  of  trade  only. 

A  debt  of  kharai  is  like  other  debts,  although  according 
to  some  this  is  true  only  in  case  the  kharaj  was  justified. 
As  regards  tithe  debts,  if  the  crop  remains  intact,  the  zakat 
is  not  affected  by  it,  since  the  tithe  debt  attaches  to  the  crop. 
Again,  if  the  crop  is  accidentally  destroyed,  the  zakat  is  not 

1  Mabsiit,  p.  169.  J  Umm,  p.  15. 

*  Kharashi,  p.  106;  Dardir,  p.  124. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  2II 

affected,  since  the  tithe  debt  has  in  that  case  lapsed.  If, 
however,  the  crop  was  destroyed  wilfully,  the  tithe  thereby 
becomes  a  personal  debt  and  in  such  case  like  other  debts 
exempts  from  zakat.1 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah,  Abu  Yusuf,  and  Muhammad 
Ibn  Al-Hasan,  a  debt  must  have  been  incurred  during  the 
year,  but  not  after  it,  in  order  to  constitute  a  cause  of  ex- 
emption as  regards  the  zakat  of  that  year.2  As  regards  debts 
incurred  during  the  year  but  since  discharged;  according 
to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  and,  in  the  opinion  of  Ibn 
'Abidm,3  according  to  Zufar,  they  exempt  from  zakat 
and  the  year  begins  anew ;  but  according  to  Abu  Yusuf,  and, 
in  the  opinion  of  Ibn  'Abidin,  also  according  to  Abu  Hani- 
fah and  Muhammad,  such  debts  result  only  in  a  decrease  of 
the  nisab,  not  its  total  disappearance,  and  consequently  the 
zakat  is  due  when  the  year  is  complete.  According  to  the 
Bahr*  debts  incurred  as  a  result  of  suretyship  (kaftflah) 
are  like  other  debts. 

A  debt  is  a  cause  of  exemption  whether  or  not  it  has 
fallen  due.5  Consequently  the  marriage  price  (mahr)  stipu- 
lated by  the  husband  in  favor  of  his  wife  exempts  him  from 
zakat  even  if  the  price  is  to  fall  due  at  a  future  date  (mu'aj- 
jal).  Some  differ  on  the  ground  that  such  debts  are  not 
ordinarily  demanded.  Others  hold  that  they  should  exempt 
only  in  case  the  husband  really  intends  to  settle  them  when 
demanded  to  do  so  by  his  wife.  Some  say  that  only  debts 
which  have  fallen  due  justify  exemption.'  The  author  of 
the  Jdmi(  approves  of  this  last  view. 

1  Jdmf,  p.  300;  'Alantkiriyyah,  p.  242;  Bahr,  p.  220. 

*  'Alantkiriyyah,  p.  243. 

*  Minbah,  p.  220.  *  P.  220. 
6  'Alomkiriyyah,  p.  242;  Bahr,  p.  220. 

6  /ami'   p.  300. 


212 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


When  a  person  owns  several  nisabs  in  several  kinds  of 
pioperty  at  the  same  time  that  he  owes  a  debt,  he  makes 
allowance  for  the  debt  as  follows.  He  applies  the  debt  first 
against  the  dirhams  and  dinars  (the  gold  and  silver  cur- 
rency), and,  if  there  remains  a  surplus  of  debt,  against  the 
articles  of  trade,  and  if  there  is  still  a  surplus,  against  the 
sawaim  animals,  beginning  with  the  kind  of  sawa'im  ani- 
mals that  is  subject  to  the  least  amount  of  zakat,  unless  they 
are  all  subject  to  an  equal  amount  of  zakat,  in  which  case 
he  may  first  apply  the  surplus  to  whichever  kind  he  pleases. 
The  above  is  true  when  the  collector  has  called  in  person 
for  the  collection  of  the  zakat t  for  in  the  contrary  case  the 
property  owner  may  apply  the  debt  against  any  property  he 
chooses,  since  he  is  liable  to  zakat  equally  with  respect  to 
every  kind  of  property.  This  is  not  true,  however,  of  the 
collector,  for  he  has  jurisdiction  over  the  sawaim  animals 
alone,  and,  therefore,  he  applies  the  debt  against  the  cur- 
rency and  collects  the  zakat  of  the  animals.1 

According  to  the  accepted  Hanifite  view  the  debt  is  ap- 
plied against  the  property  which  is  subject  to  zakat  and 
not  against  property  which  is  destined  for  the  satisfaction 
of  necessities  and  is  consequently  exempt  from  zakat.  How- 
ever, according  to  Zufar,  it  is  applied  to  property  of  its 
own  genus.  Thus  a  person  possessing  200  dirhams,  a  slave 
and  a  quantity  of  borrowed  grain,  and  owing  a  slave,  pays 
no  zakat  because  the  debt  is  applied  to  the  dirhams.  Ac- 
cording to  Zufar  the  debts  of  grain  and  slave  are  applied  to 
the  grain  and  slave  he  possesses  and  a  zakat  is  due  on  the 
dirhams.  Likewise,  a  person  owning  a  house,  a  personal 
slave  worth  10,000  dirhams  and  i,ooo  dirhams  pays  no 
zakat  if  he  also  owes  1,000  dirhams,  for  the  house  and  slave, 
far  from  satisfying  his  needs,  on  the  contrary,  increase 

1  'Ahmkiriyyah,  p.  244;  Mabs&i,  p.  184. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  213 

them.1  According  to  the  Malikites,2  a  debt  may  be  applied 
to  gold  and  silver  and  the  articles  of  trade  with  a  view  to 
canceling  or  reducing  their  zakat  only  if  the  zakat  payer 
does  not  possess  other  appropriate  property  against  which 
he  may  apply  the  debt  in  question.  By  appropriate  property 
here  is  meant  gold  or  silver  extracted  from  a  mine,  tithable 
grain,  collectible  claims  already  accrued,  or,  finally,  com- 
modities (fard)  which  he  has  had  for  a  year  and  which  may 
legally  be  sold  for  the  satisfaction  of  debts,  such  as  cloth- 
ing, cattle,  riding  beasts,  books  of  law;  but  not  clothing 
destined  for  his  person  or  a  house  destined  for  his  resi- 
dence, unless  they  exceed  his  needs.  Thus  a  person  having 
forty  dinars  and  a  commodity  worth  twenty  dinars  and 
owing  forty  dinars  pays  zakat  only  for  twenty  dinars  if  at 
the  time  the  zakat  falls  due  he  has  had  that  commodity  for 
at  least  a  year  and  it  is  worth  twenty  dinars. 

The  conditions  of  zakat's  being  a  wajib  are  the  follow- 
ing: 

(1)  Reason  (faql)  and  maturity  (bulug),  for  there  can 
be  no  responsibility  without  them. 

(2)  State  of  Islam,  because  the  payment  of  zakat  is  an 
act  of  worship  and  as  such  it  can  validly  be  performed  only 
by  a  Moslem. 

(3)  Freedom  of  person  (hurriyyah),  in  order  that  the 
provision  in  the  definition  of  zakat  concerning  the  trans- 
ferring of  ownership  (tamlik)  by  the  zakat  payer  to  the 
zakat  beneficiary  may  be  realized,  for  the  slave  can  not 
own  any  property. 

Exemptions.  As  a  result  of  failure  in  one  or  more  of 
the  above  requirements,  the  following  are  exempt  from 
zakat  : 

(i)  The  Mukatab,3  because  though  he  enjoys  the  right 

l'Alamkiriyyah,  pp.  243,  244.          *  Kharashi,  p.  107;  Dardir,  p.  124. 
1  The  mukdtab  is  the  slave  who  obtained  from  his  master  the  privi- 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

to  dispose  of  (tasarruf)  his  goods,  he  does  not  completely 
own  them. 

(2)  The  debtor  subject  to  demand  of  payment  of  his 
debt  on  the  part  of  a  fellow-man,  to  the  amount  of  his  in- 
debtedness, provided  the  debt  is  of  the  kind  above  de- 
scribed.   Such  fellow-man  may  be  the  creditor,  the  imam  x 
as  regards  the  zakat  of  "  apparent "  property,  or  the  debtor 
himself,  as  regards  the  zakat  of  his  "  non-apparent "  prop- 
erty, such  as  gold  and  silver.    If,  however,  the  debt  is  not 
subject  to  demand  of  payment  and  refusal  to  pay  it  does 
not  involve  imprisonment,  it  does  not  result  in  exemption. 
A  debt  of  vow  is  of  this  last  kind.2 

(3)  Dimar  property,  which  has  been  recovered,  for  past 
years.    Dimar  is  property  which  has  slipped  out  of  one's 
possession  with  little  chance  of  recovery,  such  as  fugitive 
or  stray  slaves.    Dimar  property  is  exempt  from  sakat  ac- 
cording to  Abu  Hanlfah,  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muhammad  Ibn 
Al-Hasan  ('indahum),  because  the  condition  of  productivity 
is  absent.     According  to  Zufar  and  al-Shafi'i,3  however, 
dimar  property  is  subject  to  sakat  for  past  years,  when  re- 
covered, because  upon  its  recovery  the  cause  of  zakat, 
namely  a  complete  nisab,  has  come  into  existence.     They 
base  their  view  on  the  analogy  of  the  traveler.    The  others 
invoke  the  hadlth  of  'AH,  who  said :  "  There  is  no  zakat  on 
dimar  property  " ;  and  as  regards  the  analogy  of  the  trav- 
eler, they  claim  that  the  case  is  different,  because  he  can 
still  make  his  property  produce  through  an  agent.     Fin- 

lege  of  manumission  on  payment  of  a  fixed  price.  Such  slaves  have 
the  right  to  engage  in  trade  and  buy  and  sell  in  order  to  earn  the 
price  of  their  freedom. 

1  That  is,  the  head  of  the  Moslem  state. 

s  /ami',  p.  300. 

*  Umm,  p.  44;  Minhdj,  p.  260. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  215 

ally,  according  to  the  Malikites,1  dimar  property,  provided 
it  is  gold  or  silver,  when  recovered,  pays  zakat  for  one 
year  only,  even  if  meanwhile  many  years  should  have 
passed.  If  it  is  cattle,  then  according  to  the  prevalent 
view  the  zakat  is  paid  for  all  past  years.  As  regards  trees 
this  is  always  the  case.  The  following,  when  recovered,  are 
examples  of  dimar  property:  slaves — lost,  fugitive,  or  gone 
astray;  property  fallen  into  the  sea;  property  usurped, 
when  there  is  no  evidence  to  prove  that  fact;  prop- 
erty buried  in  the  country,  in  a  place  since  forgotten; 
property  seized  tyrannically  by  the  sultan;  claims  pub- 
licly disclaimed  by  the  debtor  with  no  evidence  to 
disprove  him.  However,  claims  acknowledged  by  a 
debtor  who  is  well-to-do,  or  even  in  financial  diffi- 
culties, or  who  has  been  declared  by  a  judge  insolvent 
(muf alias),  are  not  considered  dimar  property,  because 
there  is  yet  a  possibility  of  recovering  them.  In  fact,  as  re- 
gards the  debtor  who  is  in  difficulties,  he  may  still  recover 
his  fortune,  and  as  regards  the  case  of  the  debtor  who  has 
been  declared  insolvent,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  such 
declaration  is  not  valid  and  debts  owed  by  the  insolvent  are 
not  lost  considering  that  wealth  flows  back  and  forth.  Mu- 
hammad Ibn  al-Hasan  has  dissented  from  Abu  Hanifah  as 
regards  the  validity  of  declaring  a  debtor  insolvent,  and  so 
he  has  considered  claims  owed  by  an  insolvent  as  dimar. 
Abu  Yiisuf ,  while  agreeing  with  Muhammad  as  regards  the 
validity  of  the  judgment  of  insolvency,  followed  Abu  Hani- 
fah in  not  considering  the  debts  of  the  insolvent  as  dimar 
property.  The  motive  in  their  case  was  to  guard  the  inter- 
ests of  the  poor  who  are  the  chief  beneficiaries  of  zakat.  Like- 
wise, according  to  most  of  the  leading  doctors  (mashtfikh), 
claims  denied  by  the  debtor,  if  they  have  been  proved  by 
evidence,  are  not  dimar.  However,  according  to  Muham- 

1  Khalil,  p.  41 ;  Mudaurwanah,  p.  98;  Kharashi,  p.  84. 


2i6  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

mad  Ibn  al-Hasan  they  are  dimar  and  are  not  subject  to 
zakat,  because  every  judge  is  not  just  and  all  evidence  is 
not  reliable.  Similarly,  claims  concerning  the  validity  of 
which  a  judge  has  personal  information  are  not  dimar. 
However,  this  is  not  true  at  the  present  time,  because  the 
judges  now  may  no  longer  render  judgment  on  the  basis  of 
personal  information  they  may  happen  to  possess.  Finally, 
property  which  has  been  buried  in  a  place  answering  the 
description  of  hirz?  such  as  the  house  or  shop  of  the  owner, 
is  not  dimar  even  if  its  exact  location  has  since  been  for- 
gotten, because  it  may  be  recovered  by  being  dug  up.  Ac- 
cording to  the  Bohr  this  is  also  true  of  property  buried  in 
another's  house  (hirz).z  The  Hanifite  doctors  have  dif- 
fered as  regards  property  buried  in  the  owner's  garden 
(karm)  or  field.  Some  hold  that  such  property  is  not  dimar 
considering  that  it  may  be  recovered  by  digging.  Others 
take  the  opposite  view  because  of  the  difficulty  of  digging 
up  the  entire  garden  or  field ;  they  claim  that  for  this  reason 
also  property  buried  in  a  large  house  would  be  dimar. 

(4)  Also,  for  want  of  productivity,  or  because  of  being 
destined  for  primary  necessities,  or  for  both  reasons,  the 
following  articles:  dwelling-houses;  wearing  apparel; 
household  utensils ;  slaves  employed  as  servants ;  riding  ani- 
mals; arms  kept  for  use;  food  used  by  one's  self  and  fam- 
ily; articles  of  adornment,  if  not  made  of  gold  and  silver; 
gems,  pearls,  rubies,  hyacinths,  emeralds,  and  the  like ;  coins 
of  other  than  gold  and  silver,  if  intended  for  personal  ex- 
penditure; books  and  tools.  All  the  preceding  articles  are 
exempt  from  zakat  even  when  they  are  not  destined  for 
primary  necessities,  and  are  not  actually  used — for  instance, 
even  when  the  tools  are  not  owned  by  people  who  use  them, 

1  Hire  technically  means  a  place  where  property  is  customarily  kept, 
such  as  one's  house,  shop,  tent,  or  person. 
*  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  245. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  2l? 

provided,  however,  they  are  not  intended  for  trade.1  It 
must  be  remarked  that  the  tools  (alat)  referred  to  above 
are  the  tools  which  render  a  use  without  leaving  a  trace  in 
the  thing  on  which  they  have  been  used.  If,  however,  they 
do  leave  a  trace  in  the  thing,  as  is  the  case  with  yellow  dye 
or  saffron  bought  by  a  dyer  in  order  to  be  used  for  the 
dyeing  of  people's  clothing  in  consideration  of  a  price  (ajr), 
they  are  then  subject  to  zakat,  provided  their  value  amounts 
to  a  nisab  and  a  year  has  passed  from  the  time  of  their  pur- 
chase. Likewise  subject  to  zakat  is  every  article  (fayn) 
bought  for  use  in  the  process  of  work,  if  a  trace  of  it  re- 
mains in  the  object  worked  upon.  Gall-nut  and  grease  used 
for  the  dressing  of  leather  are  of  this  category.  No  zakat 
is  due  on  instruments,  however,  if,  as  in  the  case  of  soap 
and  potash,  no  trace  of  them  is  left.2 

(  5 )  Property  of  minors  and  the  insane,  because,  in  their 
case,  the  conditions  of  maturity  and  reason  are  wanting; 
and  of  non-Moslems,  because  the  condition  of  Islam  is 
wanting.  However,  according  to  the  Malikites  (especially 
as  regards  cattle  and  crops)  and  also  according  to  al-Sha'fii,* 
minors  and  the  insane  are  subject  to  zakat.  Al-SharVi's 
ground  is  that  zakat  is  an  obligation  connected  with  prop- 
erty, irrespective  of  ownership.  The  Hanifites,  on  the  other 
hand,  reply  that  zakat  is  an  act  of  worship  and  therefore 
incumbent  only  on  those  who  can  exercise  an  option  in  its 
discharge.4 

1  The  reason  for  this  is  that  zakat  is  due  on  property  other  than 
sawd'im  animals  or  gold  and  silver  only  when  that  property  is  in- 
tended for  trade.  Consequently  an  amount  of  property  that  is  not 
intended  for  trade  does  not  pay  sakdt,  merely  because  it  is  not  destined 
for  primary  necessities,  no  matter  how  large  such  amount  may  be. 
There  is,  however,  a  difference  in  the  disbursement  of  sakdt.  There, 
the  possession  by  a  person  of  a  nifdb  of  books  bars  him  from  having  a 
share  in  the  zakdt  unless  he  needs  to  use  those  books.  Durar,  p.  113. 

1  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  242. 

1  Wajiz,  p.  87.  *Hiddyah,  p.  115. 


2i8  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Insanity  is  of  two  kinds,  original  (asli)  and  acquired 
('aridi).  It  is  original,  if  a  person  is  insane  when  he 
comes  of  age ;  it  is  acquired,  if  he  goes  insane  after  coming 
of  age.  There  is  no  difference  between  the  two  kinds  of  in- 
sanity, except  that  in  the  original,  according  to  Abu  Hani- 
fah,  the  year  begins  from  the  date  of  recovery.  Further- 
more, according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  the  zakat  is  due  on  the 
insane' s  property  if  he  has  had  a  lucid  interval  during  the 
year,  no  matter  how  short  the  interval  was.  According  to 
Abu  Yusuf,  however,  the  lucid  interval  must  be  at  least 
more  than  half  of  the  year,  since  otherwise  insanity  would 
have  had  predominated  over  sanity.1 

The  condition  of  the  payment  of  zakat  being  a  wajib  2 
is  the  lapse  of  a  year  (hawalan  al-hawl)  over  the  nisdb  of 
productive  property  while  it  is  in  the  proprietor's  full  pos- 
session, provided  the  conditions  of  age,  freedom,  etc.,  are 
fulfilled.  In  other  words,  if  one  possesses  in  full  ownership 
for  a  year  articles  coming  under  the  description  of  thaman 
or  sawa'im,  or  articles  that  he  intended  to  trade  in  for  profit, 
he  pays  zakat  for  those  articles  at  the  end  of  the  year,  re- 
gardless of  whether  or  not  they  have  been  actually  pro- 
ductive. 

The  lapse  of  a  year  is  necessary,  "because  time  is  indis- 
pensable for  productivity  to  materialize — this  time  has  been 
fixed  by  the  sharlah  at  one  year  according  to  the  hadlth: 
'  No  zakat  is  due  on  property  before  there  elapses  over  it  a 
year ',  and  because  productivity  during  a  year  is  possible  " 
by  virtue  of  the  succession  of  seasons  in  the  course  of  which 
prices  usually  vary.8 

1  'Indyah,  p.  117. 

1  This  condition  must  not  be  confused  with  the  condition  of  "  the 
zakdt  per  se  "  being  a  wdjib,  since  the  zakat  per  se  may  have  become  a 
wdjib  without  its  payment  being  due,  owing  to  the  fact  that  the  con- 
dition of  payment  is  not  yet  realized. 

8  Hiddyah,  p.  113. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  2ig 

According  to  the  Malikites,1  in  conformity  with  the  prac- 
tice of  Medina,  in  cattle  the  obligation  of  zakat  does  not 
arise  upon  the  mere  lapse  of  the  year  but  only  after  the  ar- 
rival of  the  collectors,  provided  there  are  such  who  can 
reach  the  cattle  owners. 

With  respect  to  the  requirement  of  the  lapse  of  a  year, 
it  must  be  borne  in  mind  that  nothing  must  supervene  dur- 
ing the  year  which  in  the  technical  language  is  called  "  dis- 
solution "  of  the  nisab,  or,  what  is  the  same,  dissolution  of 
the  year  (inqita'  al-hawl),  as  in  that  case  there  would  have 
to  elapse  a  new  year  before  zakat  became  due  on  the  new 
nisab.  Thus  according  to  al-Sarakhsi  if  one  should 
sell  his  nisab  of  sawaim  animals  just  one  day  before  the 
completion  of  the  year,  whether  the  price  was  sawaim  ani- 
mals of  the  same  genus  (jins),  or  whether  it  was  wealth 
of  another  genus,  such  as  gold  and  silver  currency,  the  year 
would  be  dissolved  and  another  year  would  have  to  elapse 
over  the  price  before  a  zakat  was  due  on  it.  According  to 
Zufar,  the  year  is  not  dissolved  if  the  price  was  sawaim 
animals  of  the  same  genus.  Al-Shafi'i,  on  the  other  hand, 
claims  that  the  year  is  not  dissolved  in  either  case,  because, 
as  he  argues,  the  wealth  of  the  owner  has  not  been  affected 
by  the  transaction,  just  as  this  is  the  case  in  the  exchange 
of  trade  articles  against  one  another.  Zufar  argues  that 
when  the  price  is  of  the  same  genus  as  the  animals  sold,  the 
provisions  concerning  the  original  animals  continue  in  force 
as  regards  their  price.  Al-Sarakhsi,  on  the  other  hand,  re- 
marks that  the  sawaim  animals  are  subject  to  zakat,  in  and 
of  themselves  ('ayn),  and  not  on  account  of  their  value  as 
is  the  case  with  the  articles  of  trade.  Indeed,  the  nisab  of 
the  sarva'im  animals,  as  well  as  their  productivity,  is  reck- 
oned with  respect  to  the  physical  identity  ('ayn)  of  the 


1  Dardir,  p.  115;  Kharashi,  p.  66. 


220  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

animals,  not  their  commercial  value,  and  so  when  they  are 
sold  the  year  is  dissolved ;  for  their  price,  even  though  it  be 
sawa'im  animals  of  the  same  genus,  is  no  longer  the  very 
same  animals.  In  articles  of  trade  the  case  is  different, 
since  there  the  object  in  view  is  not  the  physical  identity  of 
the  thing  but  its  value,  which  is  not  affected  by  exchange. 
Moreover,  an  exchange  in  articles  of  trade  is  conducive 
to  the  realization  of  the  object  of  trade,  namely  profit.  An 
exchange  in  sawaim  animals,  on  the  contrary,  is  subversive 
of  the  object  in  owning  sawa'im  animals — namely,  keeping 
them  in  permanent  possession  for  their  physical  produce. 
The  view  above  ascribed  to  al-Shafi'i  is  his  older  view  (ii 
'l-qadim),  namely,  the  view  he  held  during  his  stay  in  'Iraq 
before  his  departure  to  Egypt.  The  view  expressed  in  the 
Umm  *  apparently  is  his  more  "recent"  (fi'l'jadid)  view, 
since  it  is  to  the  contrary  effect,  namely,  that  if  a  person  ex- 
changes his  sawaim  animals  against  other  animals  of  the 
same  genus  or  against  other  kinds  of  wealth,  such  as  gold 
or  silver,  he  does  not  pay  zakat  on  the  animals  he  sold  if 
the  sale  occurred  before  the  completion  of  the  year,  and  he 
pays  zakat  on  the  price  he  received  in  exchange  only  after 
the  lapse  of  a  year.  However,  according  to  the  Malikites,* 
exchange  (ibdal)  does  not  dissolve  the  year  if  made  with 
the  purpose  of  escaping  the  zakat — for  instance,  if  made 
within  a  month  from  the  completion  of  the  year. 

Must  the  nisab  be  complete  every  moment  through  the 
entire  year  or  may  it  vary  to  a  certain  extent  without  re- 
sulting in  the  dissolution  of  the  year?  According  to  al- 
Sarakhsi,  the  nisab  must  be  complete  at  least  in  the  begin- 
ning and  at  the  end  of  the  year,  and  furthermore,  at  no 
time  must  it  have  entirely  disappeared  (inqittf).  Accord- 

1  P.  20 ;  cf.  Minhdj,  p.  236. 

*  Kharashi,  'Adawi,  p.  58;  cf.  Mudawwanah,  p.  81. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  22l 

ing  to  Zufar,  the  nisab  must  be  complete  throughout  the 
entire  year,  and,  on  the  other  hand,  in  al-ShafiTs  opinion, 
this  is  only  true  of  the  sawaim  animals  and  of  gold  and 
silver  (naqd),  while  in  the  case  of  articles  of  trade  it  is  suf- 
ficient if  the  nisab  is  complete  at  the  end  of  the  year  only. 
The  argument  of  Zufar  is  that  there  is  no  difference  be- 
tween the  different  periods  of  the  year  and  that  the  condi- 
tion of  a  complete  nisab  must  be  present  at  every  period  of 
the  year.  Al-Shafi'i  joins  with  Zufar  in  his  argument  as 
regards  the  sawaim  animals  and  admits  that  analogy  would 
require  that  this  should  be  true  of  the  articles  of  trade  also, 
but  remarks  that  the  latter  pay  zakat  on  the  basis  of  their 
value,  which  it  is  well-nigh  impossible  to  ascertain  for  every 
day  in  the  year.  Therefore,  for  the  sake  of  convenience,  he 
requires  that  this  condition  should  be  met  only  at  the  time 
the  zakat  falls  due,  that  is,  at  the  end  of  the  year.  Al-Sar- 
akhsi,  however,  argues  that  a  complete  nisab  is  required  in 
order  that  the  state  of  wealthiness  may  be  realized.  Con- 
sequently, it  is  necessary  at  the  beginning  of  the  year, 
in  order  that  the  year  may  begin  to  run,  and  at  the  end 
of  the  year,  in  order  that  the  zakat  may  fall  due;  but  it  is 
not  necessary  that  the  nisab  should  be  complete  in  the  mean- 
while, provided  it  does  not  entirely  disappear.  The  analogy 
of  sawa'im  animals  (which  cease  to  be  sawa'im  if  in  the 
middle  of  the  year  they  are  turned  into  beasts  of  burden), 
invoked  by  the  opponents  is  not  valid,  because  in  that  case 
the  nisab  has  entirely  disappeared ;  for  as  soon  as  the  ani- 
mals have  been  used  as  beasts  of  burden  they  have  forth- 
with ceased  to  be  sawaim  animals,  but  we  have  not  allowed 
the  destruction  of  the  entire  nisab  but  only  its  decrease. 
Finally,  as  regards  the  inconvenience  of  the  appraisal  of 
the  articles  of  trade  which  al-Shafi'i  alleges,  it  is  not  any 
harder  to  appraise  the  articles  at  the  beginning  of  the  year 
than  it  is  at  the  end,  and  there  is  no  great  inconvenience  in 


222  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

doing  so  twice  a  year,  at  the  beginning  as  well  as  at  the  end 
of  it.1  Consequently,  if  a  nisab  of  grape  juice  should  turn 
into  wine  and  then  into  vinegar  before  the  completion  of 
the  year,  the  year  would  be  dissolved  with  respect  to  the 
grape  juice  and  a  new  year  would  have  to  elapse  before 
the  vinegar  would  become  subject  to  a  year's  zakat.  If, 
however,  a  nisab  of  sheep  should  perish  during  the  year 
but  the  wool  of  the  same  was  worth  200  dirhams,  the  year 
would  not  be  dissolved,  considering  that  the  nisab  was  not 
entirely  destroyed.  Indebtedness,  even  when  it  covers  the 
entire  nisab,  does  not  dissolve  the  year,  although  Zufar 
holds  the  contrary  view.2 

Property  acquired  (istifadah)  in  the  course  of  the  year 
is  added  to  the  nisab  of  property  already  in  existence  and 
their  zakat  is  paid  together  when  the  year  is  complete  for 
the  nisab  in  question.  Thus  a  person  who  has  200  dirhams 
and  acquires  100  more  during  the  year,  pays  zakat  for  300 
dirhams  at  the  end  of  the  year.  If,  however,  the  acquisi- 
tion is  made  after  the  completion  of  the  year,  or  the  prop- 
erty already  possessed  is  not  of  nisab  quantity,  or,  finally, 
the  two  properties  in  question  are  not  of  the  same  genus, 
the  above  rule  does  not  apply  and  they  are  treated  separ- 
ately.* 

According  to  al-Shafi'i  additional  property  acquired  dur- 
ing the  year  is  not  added  to  the  original  nisab,  because  it  is 
independent  in  its  ownership  and  should  be  independent  also 
in  its  obligation  of  zakat }  unless  the  increment  consists  in 

1  Mabstt,  p.  172. 

*  Majma',  p.  170. 

It  goes  without  saying  that  if  the  indebtedness  continues  through 
the  year  the  zakdt  does  not  fall  due,  because  the  ni$db  must  be  free  of 
debt.  We  are  concerned  here  with  the  indebtedness  that  disappears 
before  the  completion  of  the  year.  Such  indebtedness  does  not  dis- 
solve the  year. 

3  Jdmi',  p.  316;  Majma',  p.  170;  Bohr,  p.  239. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


223 


offspring  or  in  a  profit  (ribh)  which  has  not  been  liquidated, 
such  as  an  increase  in  price  which  has  not  been  turned  into 
cash  (lam  yanidd).  For  the  profit  as  well  as  the  offspring 
are  dependent  on  the  original  nisab  as  regards  their  owner- 
ship and  must  be  dependent  on  it  also  as  regards  the  obli- 
gation that  attaches  to  their  ownership.  Then,  too,  it  is 
difficult  to  follow  the  rise  and  fall  of  prices.  The  Hani- 
fites  reply  that  the  reason  why  the  offspring  and  profits  are 
added  to  the  original  property  is  their  homogeneity,  since 
in  their  case  it  is  difficult  to  single  out  the  increment  from 
the  original  property ;  and  this  is  also  true  of  every  acquisi- 
tion which  is  of  the  same  genus  as  the  original  property.1 

It  follows  from  the  above  that  if  one  should  have  a  nisab 
of  camels  and  acquire  more  camels  during  the  year  through 
purchase  or  gift  or  otherwise,  according  to  the  Hanifites, 
he  adds  them  together  and  pays  zakat  for  the  whole  when 
the  year  is  complete;  but  according  to  the  Shafiites,  he  can 
do  so  only  if  the  increment  of  camels  acquired  is  an  off- 
spring of,  or  an  unliquidated  profit  from,  the  camels  for- 
merly owned — otherwise  they  are  treated  separately.  Ac- 
cording to  the  Path,2  in  Abu  Hanifah's  opinion,  the  price 
of  animals  whose  zakat  was  paid  is  not  added  to  a  nisab  of 
gold  and  silver  already  owned,  as  this  would  result  in  double 
taxation.  In  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan's 
opinions,  however,  such  price  is  added,  since  the  reason  for 
so  doing,  homogeneity,  is  present.  All  three  of  them  have 
agreed  that  the  price  of  land  or  of  its  produce,  on  which 
the  tithe  has  been  paid,  is  added  to  the  nisab  of  gold  and 
silver  already  possessed. 

Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,  four  cases  are  dis- 
tinguished in  the  acquisition  of  additional  property — two 

1  Hiddyah,  p.  148;  Minhdj,  pp.  236,  251 ;  Anjari,  pp.  352,  383. 
1  P.  148. 


224  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

for  the  case  of  animals  and  two  for  other  cases.  ( i )  The 
case  of  animals:  (a)  The  additional  animals  are  acquired 
either  as  a  result  of  procreation  or  by  the  exchange  of  the 
original  animals  against  a  larger  number  of  animals  of  the 
same  species,  as  of  camels  for  camels.  In  either  case  the 
additional  animals  pay  zakat  on  the  basis  of  the  year  of  the 
original  animals,  and  it  is  not  necessary  that  the  latter 
should  be  of  nisab  quantity,  (b)  The  additional  animals 
are  acquired  in  some  other  way.  In  such  case  they 
pay  zakat  with  the  original  animals  when  the  latter's 
year  is  complete,  even  if  acquired  one  day  before  the  com- 
pletion of  that  year,  provided  they  are  of  the  same  genus, 
and  provided  the  original  animals  are  of  at  least  a  nisab 
quantity.  For  should  they  be  fewer,  the  year  begins  from 
the  day  the  nisab  is  completed.1  (2)  The  case  of  other 
property:  (a)  The  increment  consists  in  profit  (ribh)  as, 
for  example,  from  trade,  or  in  the  rental  of  a  house  or  of  a 
slave  leased  for  silver  or  gold  coins  for  profit.  The  profit 
or  the  rental  received  is  added  to  the  original  value,  and 
pays  zakat  with  it,  when  its  year  is  complete.  For  instance, 
if  one  starting  with  a  capital  of  one  dinar  should  earn  by 
the  end  of  the  year  nineteen  more,  he  would  pay  zakat  on 
twenty  dinars,  without  having  to  wait  for  the  completion  of 
a  year  with  respect  to  the  nineteen  dinars.  Or  if  he  should 
rent  with  that  dinar  an  animal  and  by  re-renting  it  make 
nineteen  dinars  of  rental,  a  day  before  the  end  of  the  year, 
the  nineteen  dinars  of  rental  are  added  to  the  original  value 
of  one  dinar,  and  the  zakat  of  the  twenty  dinars  so  result- 
ing is  paid  when  a  year  has  passed  from  the  possession  of 
the  original  one  dinar,  (b)  The  increment  consists  in 
what  is  called  fa'idah,  i.  e.,  silver  and  gold  (currency)  ac- 
quired in  some  other  way.  Such  increment  pays  zakat 

1  Dardir,  p.  112;  Kharashi,  p.  52;  Ibn  Rushd,  B.,  p.  247. 


THE  ZAKAT TAXES  22$ 

after  the  completion  of  a  year  from  its  date  of  acquisition. 
When  the  increment  is  less  than  a  nisab  quantity,  it  is 
added  to  later  ones,  and  the  year  for  the  whole  begins  from 
the  date  of  the  completion  of  the  nisab.  Examples  of  this 
increment  are  gifts  and  other  fortuitous  acquisitions,  the 
price  of  property  not  subject  to  zakat,  rental  of  trade 
articles,  etc.1 

In  reckoning  up  the  nisab,  the  rule  is  to  add  together 
only  articles  which  belong  in  the  same  genus  (jins).  As 
the  zakat  of  the  sawaim  animals  attaches  to  their  physical 
identity  and  not  to  their  commercial  value,  each  physical 
genus  constitutes  a  separte  legal  genus,  and  therefore  it  is 
not  allowed  by  ijma' ,  for  instance,  in  computing  the  nisab 
of  camels,  to  make  up  the  shortage  by  adding  together  with 
the  camels  sheep  or  cattle.2  The  articles  of  trade,  on  the 
other  hand,  are  subject  to  zakat  in  virtue  of  their  value,  and 
therefore  with  respect  to  zakat  they  constitute  one  single 
genus.  Consequently  the  different  kinds  of  trade  articles 
may  be  added  together  in  order  to  complete  the  nisab. 
Furthermore,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  the  nisab  of  either 
gold  or  silver  may  be  completed  by  the  other  or  even  by 
articles  of  trade  and  vice  versa.  However,  according  to  his 
two  disciples,  although  the  nisab  of  gold  or  silver  may  be 
completed  by  adding  articles  of  trade,  the  converse  is  not 
allowed,  because  in  their  opinion  gold  and  silver  pay  zakat 
in  terms  of  weight  and  therefore  may  not  be  added  to 
articles  of  trade  which  pay  zakat  in  terms  of  value.3  Thus  a 
bushel  of  wheat  and  five  mithqals  of  gold,  according  to  Abu 
Hanifah,  pay  zakat  if  their  total  value  amounts  to  two  hun- 
dred dirhams,  but  according  to  his  two  disciples  they  do 
not. 

1  Dardir,  p.  119;  Kharashi,  p.  87. 
1  Majnia',  p.  170,  1.  7. 
5  /ami',  p.  317. 


226  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

According  to  al-Shafi'i,1  gold  and  silver  are  distinct  gen- 
era and  may  not  be  added  together  to  complete  the  nisab  of 
either.  However,  the  nisab  of  articles  of  trade  may  be  com- 
pleted by  such  coin  (gold  or  silver)  as  may  legally  be  used 
for  their  appraisal,  the  year  for  the  whole  being  reckoned 
with  respect  to  the  coin  only.  Thus  if  a  person  hav- 
ing one  hundred  dirhams  buys  with  fifty  an  article  of 
trade,  and  should  such  article  at  the  end  of  the  year  be 
worth  one  hundred  and  fifty,  the  fifty  dirhams  are  added 
to  them  and  a  zakat  of  five  dirhams  becomes  due  on  the 
two.  According  to  the  Malikites,2  gold  and  silver  may  be 
added  together. 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah  gold  and  silver  are  added 
together  in  terms  of  value.  According  to  Abu  Yusuf  and 
Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  however,  they  are  added  in  terms 
of  weight.  Consequently,  if  a  person  has  10  dinars  worth 
1 50  dirhams  and  also  50  dirhams,  according  to  Abu  Hani- 
fah he  pays  zakat  because  their  value  amounts  to  200  dir- 
hams, i.  e.,  a  full  nisab ;  but  according  to  the  two  disciples 
he  does  not  pay  zakat  because  their  weight  falls  short  of  a 
nisab.  Conversely,  if  a  person  has  5  dinars  and  150  dir- 
hams worth  only  jl/2  dinars,  according  to  the  disciples  he 
pays  zakat,  for  the  nisab  is  complete  in  terms  of  weight — Y^ 
in  gold  and  £4  m  silver;  but  according  to  Abu  Hanifah, 
he  does  not  pay  zakat.  Some  dotcors  say  that  Abu  Hani- 
fah would  have  addition  in  terms  of  Value  only  in  case  the 
nisab  would  not  be  complete  in  terms  of  weight,  and  that 
in  this  case,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  the  owner 
would  have  to  pay  a  zakat  of  5  dirhams.  The  author  of  the 
Bahr,  however,  retorts  that  Abu  Hanifah  stands  for  addi- 
tion in  terms  of  value  in  every  case,  and  that  the  owner  in 
this  case  would  have  to  pay  zakat  also  according  to  Abu 

1  Utntn,  p.  34',  Mugni,  p.  387;  Wajlz,  p.  93- 
1  Kharashi,  p.  81. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 

Hanifah,  for  although  the  nisab  might  be  incomplete  if  com- 
puted in  terms  of  dinars,  it  would  be  complete  if  computed 
in  terms  of  dirhams — in  fact,  it  would  amount  to  250  dir- 
hams  and  the  zakat  due  on  them  would  be  not  5  but  6%  dir- 
hams. In  other  words,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  either 
metal  may  be  computed  in  terms  of,  and  added  to,  the  other 
in  order  to  complete  a  nisab.1  The  Malikite  view  in  this 
respect  is  like  that  of  the  two  disciples.2 

Finally,  as  regards  crops  which  are  subject  to  the  tithe, 
Abu  Hanifah  exempts  them  from  the  requirement  of  nisab, 
but  his  two  disciples,  Muhammad  and  Abu  Yusuf,  require 
the  presence  of  a  nisab.  Muhammad  holds  that  the  dif- 
ferent genera  of  grains  are  not  added  together.  Accord- 
ing to  him  and  one  report  from  Abu  Yusuf,  they  are 
added  together  if  they  may  not  be  exchanged  against  one 
another  in  unequal  quantities ;  otherwise,  as  for  instance  in 
the  case  of  wheat  and  barley,  they  may  not  be  added  to- 
gether, and  each  pays  tithe  by  itself  if  it  amounts  to  a  nisab. 
According  to  another  report  from  Abu  Yusuf  they  are 
added  together  and  pay  tithe  if  together  they  amount  to  a 
nisab,3  provided  that  they  ripen  at  the  same  time,  like  bar- 
ley and  wheat,  because  in  his  opinion  the  tithe  is  a  charge 
by  reason  of  the  benefit  derived  from  the  ground,  and  when 
they  ripen  together  they  are  one  single  benefit. 

According  to  a  report  from  Abu  Yusuf,  when  a  person 
has  two  pieces  of  land  they  are  treated  independently,  if 
the  collectors  are  different,  and  they  are  treated  as  one 
single  piece  of  land  if  they  both  come  under  the  jurisdiction 
of  the  same  collector.  In  the  latter  case,  therefore,  the  nisab 
of  one  piece  may  be  completed  by  the  produce  of  the  other. 

1  Mabsiit,  p.  193;  Bahr,  p.  247;  /ami',  p.  317;  Fatb  al-Mu'tn,  p.  393. 

*  Kharashi,  p.  81. 

3  Mabsiit,  part  iii,  p.  3;  cf.  Afajma',  p.  176. 


22g  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

However,  according  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  the  pro- 
duce of  one  piece  is  added  to  the  produce  of  the  other  and 
the  nisab  is  reckoned  with  respect  to  the  sum,  because  the 
tithe  is  a  charge  on  the  owner  and  the  owner  in  this  case  is 
one  and  the  same  person.  Al-Sarakhsi  adds  that  Muham- 
mad must  mean  simply  that  the  owner  as  between  him  and 
God  should  pay  tithe  on  the  basis  mentioned,  since  in  no 
case  the  collector  of  one  farm  could  collect  the  tithe  of  a 
piece  of  land  over  which  he  has  no  jurisdiction. 

According  to  the  Shafiites,1  the  nisab  of  one  genus  may 
not  be  completed  from  another  genus,  though  one  species 
may  be  added  to  another.  In  this  last  case  each  species 
(naw1)  pays  a  proportionate  part  of  the  entire  zakat. 
Wheat,  barley,  rice,  maize  (dhurah),  beans,  lentils  ('adas), 
peas  (himmas),  and  millet  (dukhn)  are  distinct  genera. 
Fruits  of  the  same  year  may  be  added  together  even  if  they 
matured  at  different  times.  But  fruits  and  crops  of  one 
year  may  not  be  added  to  those  of  another.  The  Malikites 
agree  with  the  Shafiites  that  the  different  genera  may  not 
be  added  together,  but  they  disagree  as  to  the  meaning  of 
"  genus  ".  Thus  with  respect  to  tithe  they  consider  the  so- 
called  qatani  (literally,  sheath-bearers),  such  as  beans,  peas 
and  lentils,  as  one  genus,  although  they  admit  that  with 
respect  to  sale  they  are  distinct  genera,  and  consequently 
may  be  exchanged  against  one  another  in  different  quan- 
tities without  involving  usury  (riba).  Likewise  wheat 
(qamh)  and  barley  (sha'lr)  are  one  genus.  But  maize, 
millet  and  rice  are  distinct  genera.  So  are  dates  (tamr), 
raisins  (zabib),  and  the  four  oil-bearers  (dhawat  al-zuyut), 
such  as  olives  and  sesam.2 

In  reckoning  the  nisab  of  cattle  jointly  owned,  each 


lMinhdj,  p.  239;  Wajlz,  p.  90;  Mawardi,  p.  205. 
sDardir,  p.  117;  Kharashi,  p.  74. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  22Q 

share  is  considered  separately.  Thus  although  five  camels 
owned  by  one  person  constitute  a  nisab  and  pay  zakat,  they 
are  exempt  from  it  if  owned  by  two  persons,  since  the  share 
of  neither  partner  amounts  to  a  nisab.  According  to  al- 
Shafi'i,  however,  such  property  pays  zakat  as  a  whole  irre- 
spective of  its  joint  ownership  if  it  is  in  the  state  of  khultah* 
and  each  of  the  owners  belongs  to  the  category  of  people 
subject  to  the  obligation  of  zakat?  On  this  point  Malik 
agrees  with  the  Hanifites  to  the  extent  of  not  considering 
combined  properties  as  one  lot  unless  the  share  of  each 
amounts  to  at  least  one  nisab.  In  such  case  the  zakat  is 
divided  between  the  two  proportionally. 

Al-ShafiTs  ground  for  his  view  is  the  hadith :  "  The 
separate  are  not  combined  and  the  combined  are  not  separ- 
ated, for  fear  of  sadaqah"  It  is  not  therefore  permissible, 
he  argues,  to  separate  cattle  and  pay  their  zakat  inde- 
pendently, when  they  have  been  together  all  the  time. 
Moreover,  by  rearing  their  cattle  together  they  have  had 

1  Khulfah  is  the  state  of  two  properties  being  so  mixed  that  they 
cannot  be  separated.  According  to  the  Muwaiicf  (p.  112),  in  this  con- 
nection a  state  of  khultah  exists  if  the  shepherd,  the  bull  (/«&/), 
the  watering-pail  (dalw),  and  the  resting-place  (murdh)  are  common, 
even  if  the  two  owners  can  tell  their  cattle  apart — it  being  a  case  of 
joint  ownership  if  they  cannot  tell  them  apart.  According  to  al-Kha- 
rashi,  it  is  sufficient  if  three  or  more,  of  the  above-mentioned  four 
things  and  the  barn  (mabyit),  are  common,  provided,  however,  that  the 
two  partners  have  intended  the  state  of  khultah  and  are  both  free 
Moslems,  and  provided  this  state  has  lasted  for  a  year.  According  to 
al-Shafi'i  (Untm,  p.  u),  on  the  other  hand,  it  is  a  case  of  khultah  if, 
for  instance,  the  cattle  are  jointly  owned.  If,  however,  the  cattle  are 
not  jointly  owned  but  have  been  merely  herded  together  by  the  owners, 
and  the  cattle  of  each  may  be  distinguished  from  those  of  the  other, 
it  is  still  a  case  of  khultah  if  the  cattle  have  had  common  resting-place 
(murdh),  pasture,  watering-place,  and  bull  (fahl).  In  either  case  the 
state  of  khul^ah  must  have  existed  during  the  entire  year.  According 
to  the  Minhdj  (p.  235),  intention  is  not  necessary. 

*  Mabsut.  p.  153;  Umnt,  p.  12;  cf.  Wajiz,  p.  82;  Muzani,  p.  205. 


230  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  benefit  of  reducing  the  expense,  and  it  is  not  unrea- 
sonable that  they  should  bear  this  burden.  If  therefore 
the  entire  zakat  should  be  collected  from  one  of  the  two 
partners,  or  part  of  the  zakat  from  the  property  of  one  and 
part  of  it  from  that  of  the  other,  each  partner  would  have 
a  right  of  recourse  to  the  other  (tarajuf)  for  his  share  of 
the  zakat,  provided  the  amount  collected  does  not  exceed 
the  legal  rate.  For  such  part  of  it  as  has  been  collected  un- 
lawfully the  person  from  whose  property  it  was  collected 
may  bring  action  against  the  collector  only.1 

The  Hanifite  argument,  on  the  other  hand,  is  that  by  the 
very  terms  of  the  divine  prescriptions  a  person  is  subject  to 
zakat  when  he  owns  a  certain  minimum  of  property,  and 
therefore  in  case  of  joint  ownership  each  partner  is  liable 
for  his  own  share.  As  regards  the  hadlth  invoked  by  al- 
Shafi'i,  the  words  "  separate  "  and  "  combined  "  occurring 
in  it  refer  to  ownership  and  not  to  locality,  since  it  is  unani- 
mously admitted  that  the  property  of  the  same  person,  even 
if  scattered  in  many  places,  pays  zakat  as  one  lot.  In  other 
words,  the  hadlth  only  means  that  it  is  not  allowed  to  the 
collector  or  the  property  owner  to  treat  a  lot  of  cattle  owned 
by  one  person  as  two  lots,  or  lots  owned  by  several  persons 
as  one  lot,  with  a  view  to  increasing  or  decreasing  the  zakat , 
as  the  case  may  be.  Thus  it  is  not  allowed  to  a  person,  in 
order  to  escape  the  tax  of  one  sheep  due  on  his  forty  sheep, 
to  split  them  into  two  lots  of  twenty  each;  neither  is  the 
collector  allowed,  in  order  to  collect  a  zakat  of  one  sheep, 
to  consider  two  lots  of  twenty  owned  by  different  indi- 
viduals as  one  lot  of  forty  sheep.2 

Consequently,8  if  one  of  the  partners  (shirkah  mufawa- 

1  Umm,  p.  12 ;  An§ari,  p.  349. 

1  Mabsiit,  p.  154;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  254. 

1  Mabsiit.  part  iii,  p.  40. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  231 

dah,  or  shirkah  'indn)  pays  (add')  the  zakat  of  the  other's 
share  he  has  no  recourse  to  him  for  reimbursement.  The 
reason  for  this  is  that  he  had  no  authority  to  settle  the  zakat 
of  his  partner,  and  therefore  he  loses  the  money  he  paid  on 
his  account.  Especially  is  this  true,  because  by  paying  for 
his  partner  he  has  not  cancelled  the  latter's  debt  of  zakat 
since  the  zakat  debt  is  discharged  only  when  there  is  an  in- 
tention on  the  part  of  the  person  for  whose  zakat  the  money 
is  paid.  To  the  hadith,  "As  regards  that  which  concerns  two 
partners  (khalit),  they  have  recourse  to  one  another  (yata- 
raja'ani)  equally  ",  invoked  by  the  Shafiites,  the  Hanifites 
answer  that  they,  too,  believe  in  one  partner's  having  re- 
course to  the  other  (taraju')  but  they  claim  that  this  hap- 
pens only  in  case  the  collector  takes  the  whole  of  the  zakat 
from  the  joint  property  (akhadha  min  'urd  al-ganam)  ; 
in  such  case  each  partner  has  recourse  to  the  other  for  such 
part  of  the  other's  share  of  zakat  as  was  collected  from  his 
own  property,  because  there  is  implied  permission  to  the 
collector  on  the  part  of  each  partner  to  collect  his  share  of 
zakat  from  the  common  property.  For  instance,  if  the  col- 
lector collects  from  one  hundred  and  twenty  sheep  owned 
by  two  persons  (eighty  by  one  and  forty,  that  is,  one-third, 
by  the  other),  the  zakat  due  on  them,  namely,  two  sheep 
(one  on  the  forty  and  one  on  the  eighty),  the  owner  of  the 
two-thirds  has  recourse  to  the  owner  of  the  one-third  for 
one-third  of  a  sheep's  value,  because  one-third  of  the  entire 
sheep  due  on  his  share  of  forty  sheep  was  paid  by  his 
partner,  since  of  the  two  sheep  taken  as  sakat,  he  owned 
only  one-third,  namely,  two-thirds  of  a  sheep.1 

According  to  both  the  Shafiites  and  Malikites,2  the  state 
of  khultah  is  not  limited  to  the  case  of  animals  but  applies 

1  Kasani,  p.  30;  Mabs&t,  p.  154;  'Alatnkiriyyah,  p.  254. 

1  Minhdj,  p.  235 ;  Wajiz,  p.  83 ;  Ansiri,  p.  348 ;  Mudawwanoh,  p.  103. 


232  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

also  to  crops  and  fruits,  gold  and  silver,  and  the  articles 
of  trade.  The  Hanifites  again  disagree  with  them  except 
that  Abu  Yusuf,  as  regards  crops  only,  requires  the  tithe,  if 
the  jointly  owned  produce  amounts  to  a  nisab,  because,  in 
his  opinion,  the  tithe  is  a  charge  upon  the  produce  itself,  not 
upon  the  owners  of  the  same,  and  therefore,  as  in  the  case 
of  the  produce  of  waqf  lands,1  the  tithe  is  due  when  the 
entire  produce  is  of  nisab  quantity,  irrespective  of  its  joint 
ownership.  On  the  contrary,  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  re- 
quires that  the  share  of  each  partner  amount  to  a  nisab.2 

The  lapse  of  the  zakat  debt.  If  the  nisab  is  accidentally 
destroyed  (halak)  after  the  lapse  of  the  year,  that  is,  after 
the  zakat  fell  due,  the  zakat  debt  lapses,  whether  the  prop- 
erty was  "  apparent  "  or  "  non-apparent  "  or  whether  it  had 
meanwhile  been  possible  to  pay  the  zakat.  This  view  is 
unanimously  adhered  to  by  the  Hanifites  as  regards  the  case 
in  which  the  public  collector  had  not  yet  demanded  payment 
of  the  zakat.  If,  however,  the  collector  had  demanded  pay- 
ment of  the  zakat,  according  to  some,  the  zakat  debt  still 
lapses — and  this  is  the  view  generally  accepted ;  but  accord- 
ing to  others  the  debt  must  be  paid  (daman).  Tithe  is  like 
zakat  in  this  respect.3 

According  to  Al-SharVi,  the  zakat  lapses  if  the  property 
has  been  destroyed  accidentally  before  the  payment  of  zakat 
has  been  possible  (tamakkun  min  al-adtf),  but  it  does  not 
lapse  if  meanwhile  payment  of  zakat  has  been  possible.* 

Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,5  the  zakat  does  not 
lapse,  in  case  of  destruction,  if  the  owner  delayed  its  settle- 

1  Cf.  Ibn  -Rushd,  M.,  p.  230;  Angari,  p.  369. 

1  Mabsut,  part  iii,  p.  4. 

*  Majma',  p.  166. 

4  Hiddyah,  p.  152;  'Indyah,  p.  152;  Mabstt,  p.  174;  Minhdj,  p.  268. 

6  Kharashi,  p.  130. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  233 

ment  for  more  than  a  day  or  so,  or  if,  for  instance,  he  took 
the  tithe  home,  for  future  settlement,  although  he  could 
have  settled  it  right  away. 

The  argument  of  al-Shafi'i  is  that  zakat  is  a  financial  ob- 
ligation ordained  by  God  and  that  it  does  not  lapse  merely 
because  the  property  is  destroyed,  if  its  settlement  in  the 
meanwhile  had  been  possible.  He  bases  this  on  the  analogy 
of  the  debt  of  sadaqat  al-fitr  and  pilgrimage.  Indeed,  if  a 
person  was  well-to-do  when  he  started  out  for  pilgrimage, 
he  is  not  freed  from  the  obligation  if  his  property  is  later 
destroyed.  Furthermore,  he  argues  that  the  zakat  debt  is 
a  divine  trust  and  one  becomes  responsible  for  it  if  he  re- 
fuses to  settle  it  when  it  has  been  demanded  by  a  person 
who  has  the  right  to  demand,  for  instance,  a  poor  person.1 

Al-Sarakhsi's  argument  in  support  of  the  Hanifite  view 
is  that  the  zakat  is  a  charge  on  the  nisab  and  lapses  when 
the  nisab  is  destroyed ;  that  there  is  no  ground  for  holding 
the  property  owner  to  liability  (daman)  for  his  zakat  debt, 
because  there  is  liability  only  when  a  right  of  ownership 
or  possession  has  been  encroached  upon,  and  it  cannot  be 
said  that  in  this  case  the  right  of  the  poor  to  ownership  or 
possession  has  been  invaded ;  that  the  analogy  of  the  debt  of 
sadaqat  al-fitr  and  pilgrimages  is  not  valid,  because  in  their 
case  the  obligation  attaches  to  the  person  of  the  worshiper 
and  not  to  his  property,  and  hence  it  continues  even  after 
the  destruction  of  the  property ;  then,  too,  in  the  case  of  the 
sadaqat  al-fitr  and  pilgrimage,  property  is  a  condition  of 
their  being  wajibs,  not  a  condition  of  their  payment  being  a 
wajib,  and  so  when  once  they  have  become  due  owing  to 
possession  of  property  they  do  not  lapse  after  its  destruc- 
tion; that  zakat  has  been  made  obligatory  for  the  consola- 
tion of  the  poor,  and  after  the  destruction  of  his  prop- 

1  Mabsut,  pp.  I74-S. 


234  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

erty  the  owner  is  in  need  of  consolation  as  much  as  the 
poor  and  therefore  is  not  obliged  to  console  others;  that 
zakat  is  a  small  contribution  from  a  great  quantity  of  prop- 
erty in  order  that  its  payment  may  not  be  heavy  and  for  this 
reason  it  strikes  only  productive  property  so  that  the  hard- 
ship involved  in  its  settlement  may  be  offset  by  the  produc- 
tivity of  the  property,  and  that  therefore  if  the  zakat  were 
extracted  in  this  case,  there  would  have  been  exacted  other 
than  what  was  due ;  finally,  that  the  fact  that  a  poor  person 
has  demanded  payment  of  zakat  is  of  no  account,  because  he 
is  by  no  means  the  very  one  beneficiary  entitled  to  the  zakat 
and  the  zakat  payer  has  the  right  himself  to  disburse  the 
zakat  to  the  poor  person  and  it  is  exactly  in  order  to  dis- 
burse it  to  a  more  deserving  poor  person  that  he  refused  to 
disburse  it  to  him.  The  Hanifite  doctors  of  'Iraq,  however, 
claim  that  if  the  owner  refuses  to  disburse  the  zakat  to  the 
public  collector  he  becomes  responsible  for  it  in  case  of 
destruction,  because  the  public  collector,  unlike  the  poor,  is 
entitled  to  demand  payment  of  the  zakat. 

If  only  a  part  of  the  nisab  has  been  destroyed  accident- 
ally, then  only  its  share  of  the  zakat  lapses  since  the  rest 
can  still  pay  zakat.  If,  for  example,  out  of  130  sheep  all 
but  40  were  destroyed,  there  would  still  be  due  a  zakat  of 
one  sheep  on  the  40.  The  rule  in  this  respect  is  that  the 
part  destroyed  is  applied  first  to  the  'afw  (the  surplus  over 
the  nisab)  which  does  not  pay  zakat ,  and  if  it  does  not  cover 
the  'afw  entirely,  the  amount  of  the  zakat  to  be  paid  is  not 
affected,  since  the  nisab  has  been  left  intact.  But  if  the  de- 
stroyed part  more  than  covers  the  'afvu  and  runs  over  into 
the  nisab,  the  excess  over  the  'afw  is  applied  to  the  various 
nisabs  successively,  beginning  with  the  nisab  next  to  the  (afw 
until  the  first  nisab  is  reached.  For  instance,  if  15  out  of 
40  camels  were  destroyed,  the  various  nisabs  being  5,  10, 
15,  20,  25,  36  and  46  camels,  and  the  intervals  between  those 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  235 

numbers  being  the  respective  'afws,  the  1 5  camels  destroyed 
are  applied  successively  to  the  'afw  of  4  camels  (between 
40  and  the  next  nisab  of  36),  then  to  the  nisab  of 
36  down  to  25,  just  leaving  25  camels,  the  zakat  for 
which  would  be  a  bint  makhad.  If,  instead  of  15,  20  camels 
were  lost,  then  there  would  be  due  zakat  on  20  camels, 
namely,  4  sheep,  and  so  on.  This  is  according  to  Abu  Hani- 
fah.  According  to  Abu  Yusuf,  the  destroyed  number  ap- 
plies first  to  the  'afw  and  then  to  all  the  remaining  nisabs 
proportionately,  for  instance,  in  the  above  case,  the  15 
camels  are  applied  first  to  the  'afw  of  4,  and  the  remaining 
ii  are  distributed  proportionately  among  the  rest,  that  is, 
the  remaining  25  camels  are  subject  to  a  zakat  of  25/36  of 
a  bint  labun,  which  is  the  zakat  of  36  camels.1  According 
to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  however,  in  the  above  case,  the 
zakat  due  on  the  remaining  25  camels  would  be  25/40  of  a 
bint  labun.  This  difference  of  view  is  due  to  the  fact  that 
while  according  to  Abu  Hanifah  and  Abu  Yusuf  the  zakat 
attaches  to  the  nisab  alone,  according  to  Muhammad  and 
also  to  Zufar,  it  attaches  to  both  the  nisab  and  the  (afw. 
Their  argument  is  that  zakat  is  due  as  a  thank-offering  for 
the  blessing  of  property  and  in  this  respect  the  'afw  is  like 
the  nisab.  The  former  two  reply  that  there  is  a  hadtth  to 
the  effect  that  zakat  is  a  charge  on  the  nisab  alone.  The 
hadlth  in  question  is :  "  For  every  five  camels  one  sheep,  and 
for  the  surplus  (fafw)  nothing  until  ten  is  reached."  '  The 
Minhaj 3  is  at  one  with  Muhammad. 

So  far  we  have  been  examining  the  case  of  accidental 
destruction.  The  case  of  wilful  destruction  (istihlak)  is 
different  because,  if  the  property  on  which  a  year's  zakat 

lMajnta{,  p.  167. 

9  Ibid. 

5  P.  268;  WajH,  p.  89.  '   : 


236  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

fell  due  is  wilfully  destroyed,  whether  literally  or  leg- 
ally, e.  g.,  by  exchange,  its  zakat  must  be  paid  (daman)  x 
irrespective  of  whether  the  value  received  in  exchange  is 
still  in  the  hands  of  the  owner  or  whether  it  has  been  ac- 
cidentally destroyed.  This  is  because,  unlike  the  case  of 
accidental  destruction  where  the  zakat  debt  lapses,  in  wilful 
destruction  there  is  no  ground  for  such  leniency  to  the 
owner  since  he  has  wilfully  destroyed  a  property  in  which 
the  poor  had  a  right.  Besides  literal  destruction,  these 
acts  also  are  considered  by  the  law  as  wilful  destruc- 
tion :  Exchange  of  sawa'im  animals  against  sawa'im  animals 
of  the  same  or  a  different  genus,  or  against  gold  or  silver  or 
articles  of  trade;  and  exchange  of  articles  of  trade  against 
other  than  articles  of  trade.  The  ground  for  this  is  that  the 
zakat  of  sawa'im  animals  attaches  to  the  animals  themselves 
and  not  to  their  value  and  so  their  exchange  amounts  to 
their  literal  destruction.2  In  general,  exchange  of  wealth 
(mat)  on  which  a  year's  zakat  has  fallen  due  for  wealth 
that  is  not  subject  to  zakat,  such  as  slaves  intended  for  per- 
sonal use,  or  for  no  consideration  whatever,  as  in  the  case 
of  a  gift,  or  for  other  than  wealth  (mal),  such  as  marriage 
price,  is  considered  wilful  destruction.*  There  has  been 
dispute  as  to  whether  it  is  a  case  of  wilful  destruction  to 
keep  one's  sawa'im  animals  from  forage  and  water  until 
they  perish.* 

It  is  not  however  a  case  of  wilful  destruction  to  exchange 
one  article  of  trade  for  another,  even  if  the  articles  ex- 

1  Daman  legally  means  that  if  the  property  destroyed  is  of  the  class 
of  fungible  (mithli)  goods,  it  is  made  good  in  terms  of  its  like,  and  if 
it  is  of  the  class  of  non-fungible  (qimi)  goods,  in  terms  of  its  value 
(qimah}. 

*  Path,  p.  154;  Durr,  p.  136. 

8  Bahr,  p.  236. 

4  'Alatnkiriyyah,  p.  254. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  237 

changed  are  of  different  genera,  unless  the  price  received 
was  inordinately  low  (muhabat).  In  this  last  case  the 
owner  pays  the  zakat  for  the  reduction  made.  Thus,  if  one 
should  buy  a  trade  slave  with  a  1,000  dirhams  on  which  a 
year's  zakat  had  been  due,  and  the  slave  should  subse- 
quently die,  no  zakat  would  be  due  on  the  1,000  dirhams 
or  the  slave,  as  the  buying  of  the  trade  slave  is  not  a 
case  of  wilful  destruction,  and  the  death  of  the  slave  is  a 
case  of  accidental  destruction.  It  would  be  a  different  case, 
however,  if  one  bought  a  personal  slave,  instead  of  a  trade 
slave,  or  if  the  trade  slave  he  received  in  exchange  was 
worth,  say,  500  dirhams  only.  In  such  case,  one  would 
have  to  pay  the  zakat  for  the  i  ,000  dirhams,  or  in  the  second 
case,  for  the  500  dirhams  of  reduction,  such  reduction  being 
inordinately  great  and  subject  to  the  suspicion  that  it  was 
intended  for  a  present.  In  the  exchange  of  articles  of  trade 
the  rule  is  that  unless  a  definite  intention  is  adopted  the 
article  received  in  exchange  is  considered  an  article  of  trade 
if  the  article  given  away  in  exchange  was  such.  Thus,  if  a 
person  should  exchange  1,000  dirhams  against  a  slave — 
because  silver  and  gold  are  always  articles  of  trade — the 
slave  is  considered  a  trade  slave,  unless  he  was  actually  in- 
tended for  personal  use.1  Likewise  it  is  not  a  case  of  wilful 
destruction  if  one  should  discharge  (ibra)  one's  debtor 
from  his  debt,  or  should  lend  an  article  (i'arah),  or  give  a 
loan  (iqrad)  and  the  property  be  destroyed  in  the  hands  of 
the  borrower.2 

What  has  been  said  above  applies  only  in  case  the  de- 
struction has  occurred  after  the  lapse  of  the  year,  namely, 
after  the  zakat  fell  due.  Destruction  before  the  lapse  of 
the  year,  even  though  wilful,  does  not  entail  any  liability 
for  the  zakat  that  was  yet  to  fall  due  on  the  part  destroyed, 

1  Path,  p.  154.  '  Bahr,  pp.  235-6. 


238  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

and  the  zakat  is  paid  only  for  the  part  that  will  be  on  hand 
at  the  end  of  the  year,  provided  the  other  conditions  have 
been  met.  However,  according  to  the  Malikites,1  if  a  per- 
son wilfully  destroys  (ibdal)  his  cattle  before  the  lapse  of 
the  year  in  order  to  escape  paying  their  zakat  he  neverthe- 
less pays  it  if  there  is  presumptive  evidence  of  his  intention, 
e.  g.,  if  he  destroyed  the  cattle  within  a  month  from  the 
completion  of  the  year. 

A  second  way  in  which  the  zakat  may  lapse  after  it  be- 
comes due  is  by  the  death  of  the  property  owner  without  a 
will  directing  the  settlement  of  the  zakat  from  the  third  of 
his  estate.  This  is  the  Hanifite  doctrine.  The  view  of  al- 
Shafi'i  is  that  the  zakat  debt  of  the  deceased  person  may  be 
collected  from  the  entire  estate  whether  or  not  he  left  a 
will  to  that  effect.2 

Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,*  the  zakat  of  cattle 
as  well  as  of  crops,  i.  e.,  apparent  property,  is  collected  from 
the  whole  estate  even  if  the  deceased  left  no  will  to  that 
effect,  but  the  zakat  of  non-apparent  property  is  not  col- 
lected from  the  estate,  because,  unless  there  is  evidence  to 
the  contrary,  the  presumption  is  that  the  deceased  paid  it 
himself.  If,  however,  the  deceased  acknowledged  his  debt 
of  zakat  during  the  last  year  of  his  life  and  willed  its  pay- 
ment, then  it  is  paid  from  the  entire  estate ;  if ,  without  such 
acknowledgment,  he  willed  its  payment,  it  is  paid  after  the 
payment  of  the  three  more  preferential  debts  for  funeral, 
etc.,  from  the  one-third  of  the  estate  as  to  which  according 
to  Mohamedan  law  a  will  is  valid;  finally,  if  he  acknowl- 
edged but  did  not  will  it,  the  heirs  are  advised  to  pay  the 
zakat  but  may  not  be  forced  to  do  it. 

1  Kharashi,  pp.  57-8. 

2  Kasani,  p.  53 ;  Mabsu},  p.  185 ;  Minhdj,  p.  262. 

'  Kharashi,  p.  130;  vol.  v,  pp.  425-6;  'Adawi,  vol.  v,  p.  425. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  239 

Al-ShafiTs  argument  is  that  the  Prophet  in  one  of  his 
sayings  likened  the  claim  of  God  to  the  claim  of  a  fellow- 
man;  and  since  the  latter  may  be  collected  from  the  estate 
of  a  deceased  person,  the  zakat  debt  may  also  be  col- 
lected. Moreover,  after  one's  death  his  personal  obligations 
devolve  upon  his  property  and  they  must  be  discharged 
by  the  heirs  from  the  estate.  Al-Sarakhsi,  on  the  other 
hand,  argues  that  there  is  a  hadith  to  the  effect  that  a  per- 
son's property,  outside  of  such  part  of  it  as  has  been  con- 
sumed or  disposed  of  by  will  by  the  deceased  in  a  charitable 
way,  becomes  the  property  of  his  heirs;  that  in  a  case  of 
conflict  between  a  claim  of  God  and  a  claim  of  a  fellow-man, 
the  latter  is  given  precedence;  furthermore,  that  the  wajib 
consists  in  the  act  of  giving,  not  in  the  thing  given,  and 
therefore  cannot  be  discharged  by  the  heirs ;  moreover,  that 
the  giving  of  zakat  is  an  act  of  worship  and  as  such  must 
be  accompanied  by  the  intention  of  the  worshiper,  which 
in  this  case  is  impossible,  since  the  intention  of  the  heirs 
cannot  replace  that  of  the  deceased,  unless  the  deceased 
willed  to  that  effect ;  for  the  heirship  of  the  heir  is  not  based 
on  his  consent  but  is  enforced  on  him  by  the  law. 

If  the  death  occurred  during  the  year,  the  year  is  dis- 
solved, and  a  new  year  must  elapse  before  a  zakat  is  due  on 
the  property  inherited.  According  to  al-Shafi'i,  the  year  is 
not  dissolved,  and,  therefore,  the  time  passed  before  the 
death  is  taken  into  account  by  the  heirs  in  determining  the 
completion  of  the  year  in  the  discharge  of  the  zakat  dues  of 
the  inherited  property. 

According  to  al-Kasani,1  a  third  cause  for  the  lapse  of 
the  zakat  debt,  after  it  becomes  due,  is  apostasy  (riddah). 
This  is  the  Hanifite  and  Malikite 2  view.  Al-Shafi'i  holds 
that  apostasy  is  not  a  cause  of  lapse.  In  other  words,  if 

1  Kasani,  p.  53.  *  Wajiz,  p.  87. 


240 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


the  apostate  should  return  to  Islam,  according  to  the  Hani- 
fites  he  is  not  obliged  to  pay  the  zakat }  but  according  to  al- 
Shafi'i  he  must  pay  it.  Al-ShafiTs  argument  is  that  the 
apostate  is  able  (qadir)  to  perform  (ada)  the  obligation 
but  that  because  a  condition  of  performance  is  his  being  a 
Moslem  he  is  not  held  to  perform  it  until  after  he  returns 
to  Islam.  He  bases  this  on  the  analogy  of  the  person  who, 
though  unclean,  is  able  to  perform  the  obligation  of  prayer, 
but  may  not  do  so  until  after  he  has  purified  himself.  The 
Hanifite  argument  is  that  Islam  effaces  what  was  before  it, 
and  that  the  apostate  is  not  fit  (ahl)  to  perform  an  act 
of  worship  or  to  be  subject  to  an  obligation  of  worship, 
and  hence  upon  his  apostasy  the  obligation  lapses  forthwith. 
May  the  owner  sell  his  sawa'im  animals  after  a  year's 
zakat  has  fallen  due  on  them?  The  Hanifite  answer  is 
"Yes".  The  argument  is  that  the  fact  that  a  property  is  af- 
fected with  a  divine  right  (haqq  allah)  constitutes  no  bar  to 
its  sale ;  that  an  act  of  sale  is  valid  so  long  as  the  seller  owns 
the  thing  he  sold  and  is  able  to  deliver  it  to  the  purchaser, 
and  that  both  these  conditions  are  fulfilled  in  the  present 
case;  that  finally,  the  zakat  due  on  a  property  need  not  be 
paid  out  of  that  very  property,  since  the  owner  may  dis- 
charge it  otherwise.  When  therefore  the  collector  presents 
himself  after  the  sale,  analogy  requires  that  he  should  col- 
lect the  zakat  from  the  seller  and  have  no  lien  on  the  ani- 
mals, since  by  sale  they  have  become  the  property  of  the  pur- 
chaser and  no  zakat  is  due  on  them  as  yet.  Moreover,  the 
seller  is  obliged  to  pay  the  zakat  because  by  selling  the  ani- 
mals he  has  destroyed  the  right  of  the  poor.  Although 
analogy  requires  the  above,  this  case  is  judged  according 
to  istihsan  which  requires  as  follows :  If  the  collector  comes 
before  the  two  parties  to  the  sale  have  parted,  he  has  the 
option  either  of  collecting  the  zakat  from  the  very  animals 
in  question  (and  in  that  case  the  purchaser  has  action 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


241 


against  the  seller  for  the  zakat's  share  of  the  price)  or  of 
collecting  the  sakat  from  the  seller  and  letting  the  buyer 
keep  the  animals.  However,  according  to  Muhammad  Ibn 
al-Hasan,  the  question  turns  on  whether  or  not  the  animals 
have  been  taken  away  before  the  collector  appeared.  If  the 
collector  appeared  after  the  animals  have  been  carried  away, 
he  does  not  collect  anything  from  the  animals  but  applies  to 
the  seller.  If  he  comes  before,  he  may  collect  the  tax  in 
kind  from  the  animals,  for  the  purchaser  begins  to  be  re- 
sponsible (d&min)  l  for  (losses  affecting)  the  things  bought 
only  after  he  has  carried  them  away.  As  regards  prop- 
erty subject  to  tithe,  it  is  immaterial  whether  or  not 
the  parties  have  parted  or  carried  the  thing  sold  away, 
because  tithe  attaches  to  the  produce  of  the  earth  in- 
dependently of  its  ownership,  whereas  the  sakat  attaches  to 
the  owner,  not  the  thing  owned.2  According  to  the  Sha- 
fiites,8  the  sale  is  null  and  void  to  the  amount  of  the  sakat, 
though  valid  as  regards  the  balance. 

The  tribe  of  Taglib,  notwithstanding  that  they  were 
Christians,  were  treated  in  a  preferential  way  in  that  they 
were  subject,  like  Moslems,  to  sakat,  though  at  a  double 
rate.  In  all  other  respects  their  sakat  is  subject  to  the  same 
rules  as  that  of  the  Moslems.  Thus  their  minor  children 
are  exempt  from  the  sakat  and  their  women  pay  the  same 
sakat  as  their  men.  There  is,  however,  a  report  from  Abu 
Hanifah  through  Hasan  according  to  which  their  women 
are  not  subject  to  sakat  because  the  tax  paid  by  the  Taglib 
tribe,  although  named  sakat  in  deference  to  their  Arab 
blood,  is  in  reality  jizyah,  and  women  do  not  pay  jizyah. 

The  doctors  all  agree  in  considering  the  sakat  paid  by 

1  In  other  words,  while  the  goods  sold  continue  to  be  at  the  seller's 
risk,  they  are  legally  considered  to  be  his  property,  and  consequently 
the  zakdt  due  on  them  may  be  collected  from  them  in  kind. 

1  Mabsuf,  p.  173.  *  Minhdj,  p.  269. 


242  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

this  tribe  as  a  kind  of  jizyah  and  in  fact  it  is  appropriated 
like  the  jizyah.  One  reason  for  this  is  that  when  this  tribe 
was  required  by  the  calif  Omar  to  pay  the  jizyah  as  a 
tribute,  they  prevailed  on  him  by  invoking  their  Arab  blood 
and  got  his  consent  instead  of  the  jizyah  to  pay  the  zakat 
at  a  double  rate.  Omar  is  said  to  have  told  them :  "  This 
is  your  jizyaht  but  call  it  what  you  will;  its  meaning  is 
jizyah  in  our  regard  and  we  shall  place  it  with  the  jizyah."  x 
Another  reason  is  that  the  tax  paid  by  them  is  not  in 
reality  zakat  because  the  giving  of  zakat  is  an  act  of  wor- 
ship which  the  Taglib  race  is  not  fit  to  perform.  A  third 
reason  is  that  jizyah  is  a  fine  for  infidelity,  and  this  is  what 
happens  here.  When  the  Taglib  tribesmen  become  Moslems 
they  cease  to  pay  the  double  rate.  The  clients  (mawali)  of 
the  Taglib  tribe,  like  other  infidels,  pay  the  jizyah  and  do 
not  share  in  the  privilege  extended  to  the  tribesmen  them- 
selves. 

According  to  the  Mabsut,  the  compact  made  with  the 
Taglib  tribe  may  not  be  broken  by  any  Moslem  state.  In- 
deed, the  calif  'AH,  at  one  time  when  the  tribe  had  lost  its 
power,  desired  to  break  the  compact,  but  the  Companions, 
'Ali  being  among  them,  agreed  in  a  council  that  it  is  not  in 
the  power  of  any  one  to  break  it.  According  to  Muham- 
mad Ibn  al-Hasan  the  compact  derives  its  main  strength 
from  the  fact  of  ijmaf.  Moreover  the  Prophet  said  that 
whatever  the  calif  Omar  did  is  well  done. 

The  persons  who  became  converts  to  Islam  while  they 
were  in  the  enemy  land  (dar  al-harb)  and  remained  there 
for  years  before  they  came  to  the  Moslem  country  are  not 
held  to  the  payment  of  their  zakat  debt  for  past  years,  even 
if  they  should  have  known  that  as  Moslems  they  were  under 
obligation  to  pay  zakat.  The  reason  for  this  is  that  during 

1  Mabsut,  p.  176;  Majma',  p.  170. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  243 

that  time  they  were  not  under  the  protection  of  the  Moslem 
state.  However,  as  between  them  and  God,  such  persons 
are  recommended  to  settle  their  zak&t  obligation.  If,  how- 
ever, they  did  not  know  of  the  obligation  of  zakctt,  they  are 
not  under  any  obligation  to  settle  it,  although  Zufar  holds 
the  contrary  view.  Indeed  Zufar  has  analogy  on  his  side, 
since  by  conversion  to  Islam  one  accepts  all  the  obligations 
of  Islam  and  one's  ignorance  of  these  obligations  is  an  ex- 
cuse only  as  regards  sins,  but  may  not  in  any  way  operate 
to  remove  an  obligation  which  has  been  contracted  owing 
to  the  fact  that  its  cause  (sabab)  was  present. 

We  have,  however,  judged  by  istihsftn  and  said,  "  The 
contraction  of  a  sharfah  obligation  depends  upon  the  com- 
munication of  the  same.  Does  he  not  see  that  the  people  of 
Quba  [a  suburb  of  Medina]  continued  to  say  their  prayers 
facing  Jerusalem  after  the  direction  in  prayer  (qiblah)  had 
been  changed  towards  the  Ka'bah,  and  this  was  allowed  to 
them  because  they  had  not  been  informed  of  the  change. 
Indeed  one  is  subject  to  the  divine  obligations  in  the  degree 
of  possibility  only,  and  there  is  no  possibility  of  carrying 
out  an  obligation  before  it  has  been  communicated,  and  so 
it  is  as  if  the  divine  commandment  did  not  exist  so  far  as 
he  is  concerned."  * 

It  cannot  be  said  that  the  fact  of  the  diffusion  (shuytf)  of 
a  sharVah  prescription  may  be  considered  as  tantamount  to 
its  actual  communication,  for  in  the  enemy  world  the  law 
of  Islam  does  not  spread.1 

The  persons  who  have  belonged  in  the  camp  of  Khari  jitea 
for  years  and  have  later  returned  to  the  fold  of  Islam  like- 
wise are  not  held  to  the  payment  of  zak&t  for  past  years, 
even  as  regards  their  apparent  property.  However,  as  be- 
tween them  and  God,  they  are  enjoined  to  settle  an  obliga- 
tion which  has  fallen  upon  them. 

p.  181. 


244  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

SECTION  II 
The  Zakat  of  Sawa'im  or  Flocks  and  Herds * 

According  to  al-Sarakhsi,2  the  zakat  of  animals  is  treated 
first,  because  the  Prophet  in  his  letters  referred  to  them  first, 
and  cattle  were  considered  by  the  Arabs,  who  were  cattle 
raisers,  as  the  most  honored  property,  and  because  the  legal 
provisions  concerning  the  zakat  of  cattle  are  unanimously 
agreed  upon. 

Sawa'im,  plural  of  stfimah,  literally  means  any  animal 
that  is  pasturing.  Technically,  however,  the  word  sawa'im 
does  not  apply  to  animals  that  are  pastured  in  order  later 
to  be  used  for  riding  (rukub)  or  carrying  loads  (haml), 
because  such  animals  never  pay  zakat.  Thus  animals  used  as 
beasts  of  burden  are  not  considered  sawtfim  even  if  they  are 
actually  pastured  every  eight  out  of  twelve  months ;  neither 
does  sawa'im  apply  to  animals  pastured  in  order  to  be  later 
sold  for  profit  (tijarah),  because  such  animals  pay  zakat 
as  articles  of  trade  but  not  as  sawa'im  animals,  the  rules 
concerning  the  two  being  very  different.  The  term  sawa'im 
then  applies  to  animals  pastured  for  some  other  purpose, 
for  instance,  for  their  milk  (darr)  and  offspring  (nasl) 
or  in  order  that  they  may  grow  fatter.  Al-Kasani,  how- 
ever, does  not  consider  animals  pastured  for  flesh  (lahm) 
to  be  sarwtfim,  on  the  ground  that  they  do  not  bear  any  off- 
spring which  is  the  very  quality  in  virtue  of  which  sawa'im 
animals  are  considered  to  be  "  productive  ".  The  Jami'  in 
this  connection  remarks  that  as  productivity  is  a  concealed 
(khafi)  matter  the  short  ah  substitutes  the  fact  of  pasture 

lMajma',  p.  161;  Hiddyah,  p.  126;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  248;  Mabsut,  p. 
150;  Minhdj,  p.  228;  Mudaivivanah,  p.  66;  Zarqdni,  p.  54;  Muwatta, 
p.  109. 

a  Mabsut,  p.  150. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  245 

in  its  stead  and  whenever  the  latter  is  present  considers  the 
former  to  be  also  present.1 

Only  animals  pastured  for  at  least  more  than  half  of  the 
year  are  considered  sawa'im.  They  need  not  be  pastured 
through  the  entire  year,  for  cattle  owners  cannot  avoid 
feeding  their  cattle  on  provender  ('a/a/)  during  the  days 
of  snow  and  cold.  If,  therefore,  an  animal  is  fed  on  pro- 
vender during  half  or  more  of  the  year  it  is  not  a  sawa'im 
animal  and  is  exempt  from  zakat  unless  it  is  subject  to  it  as 
an  article  of  trade.  If  an  animal  intended  for  trade  is  pas- 
tured for  six  or  more  months  during  a  year  it  does  not 
become  sawa'im  unless  it  was  also  intended  to  be  made 
sawa'im.  On  the  other  hand,  if  the  owner  of  sawa'im 
animals  intends  to  use  them  at  work  or  feed  them  on  pro- 
vender, they  do  not  cease  to  be  sawa'im  until  he  actually 
carries  out  his  intention.  If,  therefore,  the  year  should 
pass  by  before  he  did  so  the  animals  pay  zakat  as  sawa'im. 
If  a  person  buys  animals  for  trade  and  afterwards  turns 
them  into  sawa'im,  the  year  is  considered  to  run  from  the 
time  they  became  sawa'im* 

Al-Shafi'i 8  says  that  an  animal  is  sawa'im  if  it  subsists 
on  pasture  and  does  not  involve  for  the  owner  expense  for 
provender.  According  to  him,  beasts  carrying  water  (na- 
wadih)  or  oxen  used  for  ploughing  or  camels  used  for 
transportation  purposes  are  not  sawa'im  and  do  not  pay 
zakat,  even  if  they  are  kept  idle  and  pastured  for  the  greater 
part  of  the  year,  because  sawa'im  are  the  animals  pastured 
all  their  lifetime  (dahrahu).  Likewise,  beasts  of  burden 
((awamil),  even  if  they  are  sometimes  pastured  and  some- 

i-Babr,  Minbah,  p.  229;  Kasani,  p.  30;  Jdmi',  pp.  299,  307;  Mabs&t,  p. 
165;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  248;  Hiddyah,  p.  147;  Majma',  p.  161. 
2  For  the  relation  of  intention  to  act,  cf.  infra,  pp.  271,  272. 
8  Untm,  p.  20;  Muzani,  p.  217. 


246  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

times  used  as  work  animals,  or  sheep  sometimes  fed  on 
provender  and  sometimes  pastured,  are  not  sawa'im  and 
"  I  would  not  take  anything  from  their  owners,  although 
if  the  animals  were  mine,  I  would  pay  their  sadaqah,  if  God 
will,  and  I  should  prefer  that  the  person  who  owns  them 
should  do  so." 

Both  the  Hanifites  and  the  Shafiites  are  agreed  that 
animals  are  subject  to  the  zakat  of  animals  only  when  they 
are  sawa'im,  although  they  differed  in  their  definition  of 
the  word  sawa'im.  Malik  and  al-Layth,  on  the  other  hand, 
held  that  animals  are  subject  to  zakat  even  if  they  are  used 
for  work,  whether  or  not  they  are  sawa'im.  According  to 
some  Malikites,  Malik  requires  animals  to  be  sawa'im  as  a 
condition  to  paying  zakat  only  in  the  case  of  sheep.  Malik's 
argument  is  that  whether  or  not  the  animals  are  actually 
pastured  they  are  by  quality  pasture  animals  and  the  fact 
of  their  prevention  from  being  so  does  not  take  them  out 
of  the  denomination  sawa'im.*-  Al-Sarakhsi,  however,  re- 
plies that  the  Prophet  explicitly  said  :  "  For  five  of  sawa'im 
camels,  .  .  ."  which  means  that  there  is  no  zakat  on  animals 
that  are  not  sawa'im.  Moreover,  according  to  a  hadith 
reported  by  Ibn  'Abbas,  the  Prophet  said  :  "  There  is  no 
sadaqah  on  the  animals  used  for  work  (fawamil)  and  as 
beasts  of  burden  (hawamil)."  Furthermore,  only  that 
property  is  subject  to  zakat  which  is  sought  for  its 
physical  produce,  not  its  use.  Is  it  not  true  in  fact  that 
dwelling-houses  and  personal  slaves  do  not  pay  zakat  }  and 
that  animals  used  at  work  are  sought  for  their  use  and  not 
for  their  physical  produce?  Again,  if  the  animal  is  fed 
on  forage  there  is  no  zakat  on  it  because  the  expense  is 
great  for  the  owner,  and  the  reason  why  sawa'im  animals 
are  subject  to  zakat  is  that  their  maintenance  is  so  inex- 


ani,  vol.  ii,  p.  56;  cf.  Ibn  Rushd,  M.t  p.  244;  Ibn  Rushd,  B.t  p. 
231,  1.  —  8;  Muwatta,  p.  no,  1.  6;  Mudawwanah,  p.  73,  1.  14. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  247 

pensive.  Therefore  no  zak&t  is  due  when  there  is  great  ex- 
pense because  evidence  in  the  sources  shows  that  the 
smallness  of  the  expense  is  an  "  effective  cause  "  (athar) 
of  the  obligation  of  sakat.  Thus  the  Prophet  said :  "  In 
what  has  been  watered  by  heaven  the  tenth,  and  in  what 
has  been  watered  by  buckets  or  water  wheels  half  of  one- 
tenth."1  On  the  other  side,  al-Shafi'i,  in  justifying  his  view 
against  the  Malikites,  says :  "  There  were  water-carrying 
animals  in  the  time  of  the  Prophet  and  his  successors  and  I 
have  not  heard  any  one  relate  that  the  Prophet  collected 
from  them  sadaqah,  or  that  any  one  of  his  successors  did 
so."  2 

The  blind,  the  emaciated,  the  young,  the  sick,  the  lame, 
etc.,  are  treated  like  the  sound  ones  in  reckoning  the  nisab 
of  the  sawaim  animals,  though  they  are  not  accepted  in 
payment  of  sakat.  There  is  a  hadlth  to  this  effect  from 
Omar.  People  had  complained  to  him  to  the  effect  that 
the  collectors  counted  the  weaklings  in  reckoning  the  nisab, 
but  refused  to  accept  the  same  in  payment  of  sakat.  Omar 
answered  that  the  collector  was  to  count  them  in  reckoning 
the  nisab  but  was  not  to  receive  them  in  payment, 
just  as  he  was  not  to  take  as  sakat  the  sawOJim  that  were 
nursing  their  young  (rubba),  those  fattened  for  their  flesh 
(akilah),  the  pregnant,  and  the  rams  of  the  sheep  (fahl 
al-ganam),  in  order  to  strike  a  happy  medium.  Al-Sar- 
akhsi  observes  that  the  last-mentioned  animals  are  the 
most  prized  ones  among  cattle  dealers  and  that  they  are 
not  taken  as  sakat  in  obedience  to  the  hadith :  "  Beware  of 
(taking)  the  best  part  of  people's  property ".  In  other 
words,  just  as  the  interest  of  the  property  owner  is  pro- 
tected by  not  taking  the  choice  animals,  so  is  the  interest 

1  Mabstt,  p.  165. 
1  Umtn,  p.  20. 


248  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

of  the  poor  considered  by  not  taking  the  young  and  the 
sickly,  although  they  are  all  counted  in  reckoning  up  the 
nisOb.1 

According  to  al-Zahidi,  only  domestic  animals  are  in- 
cluded in  reckoning  the  nisab,  the  wild  and  the  crass  be- 
tween the  two  being  disregarded.  This  view  is  approved 
of  in  the  Majma'.  However,  as  it  is  stated  in  the  Mukit, 
the  status  of  a  cross  depends  on  that  of  the  mother  and  if 
the  mother  was  domestic  the  offspring  is  considered  do- 
mestic. This  is  also  the  view  taken  by  the  author  of  the 
Durr.2  According  to  al-Shafi'i,  the  cross  between  domestic 
and  wild  do  not  pay  zakat  because,  while  one  side  requires 
the  payment  of  tax  the  other  exempts  from  it,  and  it  is  a 
principle  of  law  that  in  cases  of  conflict  one  must  construe 
in  favor  of  exemption.  The  Hanifite  reply  is  that  the  cross 
normally  is  like  its  mother  and  follows  its  status  so  much 
so  that  the  owner  of  the  mother  owns  its  offspring  also. 
This  is  because  the  sperm  of  the  father  legally  becomes 
destroyed  (mustahlak)  by  that  of  the  mother  and  so  the 
offspring  comes  from  her.8  According  to  the  Malikites,* 
the  cross  are  exempt  from  zakat  in  both  cases. 

While  an  animal  must  answer  the  description  of  sawa'im 
in  order  to  pay  the  zakat  of  sawa'im  animals,  every  sawa'im 
animal  is  not  subject  to  it,  since  it  is  only  the  sawa'im  ani- 
mals specified  in  the  sunnah  which  pay  the  zakat  of  sawa'im 
animals.  These  animals  are  treated  in  the  lawbooks  under 
the  following  heads. 

The  Zakat  of  Camels  (ibl).  The  lowest  nisab  in  camels 
being  5  camels,  no  zakat  is  due  on  fewer  than  5.  The 
zakat  on  5  camels  up  to  9  is  one  goat  (shat)  of  medium 

1  Mabsut,  p.  172;  Muwatta,  p.  113;  cf.  Minhdj,  pp.  234-5. 

1P.  135. 

8  Mabsut,  p.  183.  4Kharashi,  p.  52. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  249 

size.  All  the  hadlths  bearing  on  this  point  are  at  one,  and 
so  the  doctors  have  been  unanimous  on  it.1  The  proportion 
of  I  goat  on  5  camels  is  based  on  their  valuations  in  accord- 
ance with  the  rate  prescribed  in  the  hadlth :  "  Give  one- 
fourth  of  one-tenth  of  your  property  ",  for  in  those  days 
the  goat  sold  at  5  dirhams  and  the  bint  makliad  (a  camel) 
at  40  dirhams.  Consequently,  i  goat  for  5  camels  would 
be  in  the  proportion  of  5  for  200  dirhams.  The  Arabian 
and  the  cross  between  the  Arabian  and  the  foreign  camels 
are  alike  with  respect  to  zakat.  The  rates  for  more  than  9 
camels  are  as  follows : 

For  10  camels  and  more  up  to  14  inclusive,  2  goats. 

For  15  camels  and  more  up  to  19  inclusive,  3  goats. 

For  20  camels  and  more  up  to  24  inclusive,  4  goats. 

For  25  camels  and  more  up  to  35  inclusive,  i  bint 
makhad,  i.  e.,  a  female  camel  colt  in  her  second  year. 

For  36  camels  and  more  up  to  45  inclusive,  i  bint  labun, 
i.  e.,  a  female  camel  colt  in  her  third  year. 

For  46  camels  and  more  up  to  60  inclusive,  I  hiqqah, 
i.  e.,  a  female  camel  colt  in  her  fourth  year. 

For  6 1  camels  and  more  up  to  75  inclusive,  i  jadha'ah, 
i.  e.,  a  female  camel  in  her  fifth  year. 

For  76  camels  and  more  up  to  90  inclusive,  2  bint  labuns. 

For  91  camels  and  more  up  to  120  inclusive,  2  hiqqahs. 

From  120  up  to  144  the  process  is  started  over  again  ac- 
cording to  the  Hanifites,  namely,  one  goat  for  every  5 
camels  after  the  i2Oth  camel,  plus  the  2  hiqqahs  for  the  120. 
Thus  for  125  up  to  129,  2  hiqqahs  and  i  goat,  and  so  on 
up  to  144.  And  for  145  up  to  149,  2  hiqqahs  and  i  bint 
makhad,  and  for  150,  3  hiqqahs. 

After  150,  the  process  of  calculation  is  again  repeated 
from  the  beginning  as  follows : 

lMabs*t,  P.  150. 


250  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

From  150  up  to  174,  3  hiqqahs  plus  i  goat  for  every  5 
camels  after  the  i5Oth. 

From  175  up  to  185,  3  hiqqahs  plus  i  bint  makhad. 

From  1 86  up  to  195,  3  hiqqahs  plus  i  bint  labun. 

From  196  up  to  200,  4  hiqqahs  or,  if  the  owner  pleases, 
5  bint  labuns. 

The  same  applies  on  every  50  camels  after  the  i5Oth, 
namely,  for  205  up  to  209,  i  goat  together  with  the  4 
hiqqahs  or  5  bint  labuns,  etc.1 

The  above  is  according  to  the  Hanifites.  Al-Shafi'i  held 
that  as  soon  as  120  is  reached,  the  zakat  is  computed  at  the 
rate  of  i  hiqqah  for  every  50,  and  i  bint  labun  for  every 
40,  the  fractions  being  neglected.  Thus  from  121  to  129 
the  zakat  would  be  3  bint  labuns,  and  for  130  camels,  I 
hiqqah  and  2  bint  labuns  up  to  139,  and  for  140,  2  hiqqahs 
and  i  bint  labun,  and  so  on  accordingly.  Malik,  on  the 
other  hand,  claimed  that  as  soon  as  120  is  exceeded  by  at 
least  10,  the  zakat  is  computed  at  the  rate  of  i  "bint  labun 
for  every  40  and  i  hiqqah  for  every  50,  the  intervals  being 
omitted.  Thus,  according  to  him,  after  120,  nothing  is  due 
for  the  excess  until  130  is  reached,  the  zakat  on  130  being 
i  hiqqah  and  2  bint  labuns.  The  ground  for  the  Shafiite 
and  Malikite  views  as  against  that  of  the  Hanifites  is  a  letter 
of  the  Prophet  on  the  sadaqah  related  by  Ibn  Omar,  where 
it  was  written :  "  When  the  number  of  the  camels  exceeds 
1 20,  then  for  every  40  a  bint  labun,  and  for  every  50  a 
hiqqah".  Malik,  however,  construed  the  excess  over  120 
referred  to  in  the  hadith  to  mean  such  a  number  only  as 
would  just  bring  the  total  number  of  camels  under  one  or 
the  other  or  both  of  the  two  rates,  that  is,  just  result  in  the 
total  number  of  camels  being  a  multiple  of  40  or  50  or  both. 
Malik  consequently  considered  free  from  zakat  any  excess 

lMajnta',  p.  162. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  251 

which  fell  short  of  such  a  number,  that  is,  an  excess  of  from 
i  to  9,  in  other  words  the  interval  from  120  to  129.  Al- 
Shafi'i,  on  his  side,  construed  the  excess  to  mean  any  num- 
ber after  120.  The  ground  for  the  Hanifite  view,  on  the 
other  hand,  is  among  others  the  following  hadlth  of  Qays : 
"  I  said  to  Abu  Bakr  Ibn  Muhammad  Ibn  'Amr  Ibn  Hazm : 
'Show  me  the  letter  on  the  sadaqah  which  the  Prophet  wrote 
to  'Amr  Ibn  Hazm ',  and  he  showed  a  letter  written  on  a 
leaf  (waraqah)  reading: '  When  the  camels  exceed  120,  the 
rates  are  started  over  again,  and  for  what  is  below  25  the 
zakat  is  in  sheep,  one  sheep  for  every  5  camels/  "  x  More- 
over there  are  reports  of  the  mash-Mr  type  from  'Ali  and 
Ibn  ' Abbas  to  the  effect  that  after  120  the  process  is  re- 
peated. Therefore  as  regards  the  excess  after  120,  the 
process  is  repeated  according  to  the  hadlth  of  'Amr  Ibn 
Hazm  and  the  hadlth  of  Ibn  Omar  invoked  by  the  others 
is  applied  to  the  greater  excess  which  brings  the  number  up 
to  200.  As  between  the  unit  of  fifties  (khamslnat),  in- 
cluding the  sub-units  of  one  sheep  for  every  five  camels, 
etc.,  provided  for  in  the  hadlth  of  'Amr  Ibn  Hazm  and  the 
units  of  forties  and  fifties  suggested  in  the  hadlth  of  Ibn 
Omar,  the  former  has  been  chosen  because  it  is  an  essential 
principle  in  sakat  that  in  dealing  with  large  numbers  the 
nisab  should  be  one  and  definite. 

From  the  fact  that  the  names  bint  makhad,  bint  labiin, 
etc.,  mentioned  in  the  hadlths  are  names  of  female  animals, 
it  has  been  inferred  that  only  females  can  lawfully  be  ac- 
cepted for  the  sakat  of  camels  and  that  males  are  only  taken 
at  their  market  value.* 

The  Zakat  of  Oxen  or  Bulls  and  Cows  (baqr).*    Baqr  is 

1  Mabstt,  p.  152;  cf.  Fatb,  p.  131. 
1  Majma',  p.  162. 

•Wo/mo',  p.  163;  Hiddyah,  p.  133;  Minhdj,  pp.  233-3;  Miwardi,  p.  198; 
Kharashi,  p.  55. 


252 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


a  generic  term  meaning  the  whole  bovine  genus,  both  male 
and  female.  Buffaloes  (famus)  are  considered  a  species 
of  baqr.  The  fact  that  a  person  who  swore  not  to  eat 
baqr  flesh,  upon  eating  buffalo  flesh  does  not  become  a 
perjurer  must  not  lead  one  to  think  that  buffaloes  are  a  dif- 
erent  genus.  It  is  simply  owing  to  the  fact  that  buffaloes, 
being  rare,  do  not  occur  to  the  mind.  If,  therefore,  they 
were  not  rare  it  would  be  a  case  of  perjury.  In  the  case  of 
baqr  the  male  as  well  as  the  female  are  accepted  in  payment 
of  the  zakat  because,  unlike  the  case  of  camels,  where  the 
females  are  prized  more,  in  baqr,  as  well  as  in  sheep,  there 
is  no  premium  on  females. 

1  No  zakat  is  due  upon  fewer  than  30  heads  of  baqr  and 
upon  30  and  more  up  to  39,  the  zakat  is  i  tabi'  or  i  tabi'ah, 
i.  e.,  i  male  or  female  calf  in  the  second  year,  and  according 
to  Khalil,  in  the  third  year.  And  upon  40,  i  musinn  or  i 
musinnah,  i.  e.,  a  male  or  female  calf  in  the  third  year,  and, 
according  to  Khalil,  in  the  fourth  year.  This  is  based  on  a 
hadith  according  to  which  the  Prophet  ordered  Mu'adh  to 
collect  the  zakat  of  the  baqr  in  the  way  mentioned.  However, 
this  hadith  does  not  mention  how  many  heads  of  baqr  are 
free  from  the  tax  after  40  is  reached.  Therefore  there  is 
dispute  on  this  point.  According  to  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muham- 
mad Ibn  al-Hasan,  and  also  a  report  from  Abu  Hanifah, 
there  is  no  zakat  on  the  excess  until  60  is  reached.  The 
Shafiite  and  Malikite  views  are  to  the  same  effect.  Accord- 
ing to  another  report  from  Abu  Hanifah,  through  Hasan, 
after  40  up  to  49  there  is  no  zakat,  and  for  50,  i  musinn 
and  y$.  of  a  musinn  or  %  of  a  tabf.  However,  according 
to  a  third  report  from  Abu  Hanifah,  cited  in  a  Zahir-al- 
riwayah  source  (riwdyat  al-asl),1  the  excess  over  40  until 
59  pays  zakat  proportionally,  i.  e.,  2.^/2.  per  cent  of  a  musinn 

lMabsut,  p.  186.  *  Cf.  Ibn  'Abidin,  p.  16. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  253 

per  head.  Thus  41  heads  of  baqr  would  pay  a  zakat  of  i 
musinn  plus  2l/2  per  cent  of  a  musinn.  The  ground  for  this 
view  is  that  the  exemption  of  the  'afw  from  zakat  is  based 
on  a  provision  (nass)  which  is  contrary  to  analogy  and  ex- 
ceptional and  therefore  limited  to  the  case  concerning  which 
it  was  made.  Consequently  in  this  case  the  decision  is  ren- 
dered according  to  analogy  and  so  the  excess  over  40  up  to 
59  pays  zakat  at  a  proportionate  rate.  The  two  disciples, 
on  the  other  hand,  based  their  view  on  the  hadlth  according 
to  which  the  Prophet  ordered  Mu'adh  not  to  collect  any 
zakat  from  the  intervals  (awqas)  between  nisabs,  and  so 
they  have  interpreted  the  interval  between  40  and  60  as  the 
one  referred  to  in  the  hadlth.  Some  interpreted  the  word 
awqas  to  mean  the  young. 

For  60  up  to  69  the  zakat  is  2  tabfs  or  tabfahs. 

For  70  up  to  79  the  zakat  is  i  musinn  or  musinnah  and 

1  tab!'  or  tabi'ah. 

For  80  up  to  89  the  zakat  is  2  musinns  or  musinnahs. 

For  90  up  to  99  the  zakat  is  3  tabfs  or  tabi'ahs. 

For  100  up  to  109  the  zakat  is  i  musinn  or  musinnah  and 

2  tab'is  or  tabfahs. 

For  no  up  to  119  the  zakat  is  2  musinns  or  musinnahs 
and  i  tabl'  or  tabfah. 

For  1 20  up  to  129  the  zakat  is  3  musinns  or  musinnahs 
or  4  tabl's  or  tabi'ahs. 

And  so  on,  after  60,  at  the  rate  of  i  tab?  or  tabfah  for 
every  30  and  i  musinn  or  musinnah  for  every  40  heads  of 
baqr,  in  the  intervals  between  successive  multiples  of  30 
or  40  or  both,  for  every  additional  10  heads  a  musinn  or 
musinnah  being  substituted  for  the  tabi'  or  tabfah. 

The  Zakat  of  Sheep  and  Goats   (ganam).*  Ganam  in- 

1  Ma/ma',  p.  163;  Mabsut,  p.  182;  Hiddyah,  p.  135;  Minhdj,  p.  233; 
Mawardi,  p.  199;  Kharashi,  p.  56. 


254  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

eludes  sheep  (da'n)  and  goats  (ma'az)  of  both  sexes.  The 
ground  for  the  zakat  of  ganam  is  the  hadlth :  "  There  is  no 
owner  of  ganam  who  did  not  give  its  zakat  but  that  he  will 
be  knocked  down  for  it  on  a  level  ground  the  Day  of  Judg- 
ment and  the  ganam  will  trample  over  him  with  his  hoofs 
and  will  strike  him  with  his  horns,"  and  "  Let  me  not  find 
any  one  of  you  come  on  the  Day  of  Judgment  with  a  sheep 
(shat)  on  his  shoulder  that  is  bleating  and  say :  '  Oh  Mo- 
hammed, Oh  Mohammed ! '  for  I  will  say  to  him :  '  I  will 
not  let  you  have  from  God  any  thing.  Did  you  not  hear  it 
when  we  told  you  about  it  ?  '  "  x 

According  to  the  Hanifites,  as  well  as  the  Shafiites  and 
the  Malikites,  there  is  no  zakat  on  fewer  than  40  heads  of 
ganam.  And  upon  40  and  more  up  to  120  heads,  the  zakat 
is  i  shat.2 

Upon  121  and  more  up  to  200,  the  zakat  is  2  shats. 
Upon  201  and  more  up  to  399  the  zakat  is  3  shuts. 
Upon  400  and  more  up  to  499  the  zakat  is  4  shats. 
Upon  500  and  more  up  to  599  the  zakat  is  5  shats. 

And  so  on,  at  the  rate  of  one  shat  for  every  additional  100 
heads  after  500,  fractions  being  neglected.  The  above  rates 
are  based  on  letters  concerning  the  sadaqah  rates  written  by 
the  Prophet  and  the  calif  Abu  Bakr,  and  there  is  ijmaf  on 
these  rates.* 

In  reckoning  up  the  nisab  of  ganam,  the  sheep  and  goats 
are  counted  alike,  but  in  the  payment  of  their  zakat  there 
is  some  difference  between  the  two.  The  youngest  ganam 
which  are  subject  to  zakat  and  are  accepted  as  lawful  pay- 
ment for  it  are  the  thanis,  i.  e.f  one  year  old  ganams,  not 

lMabsut,  p.  182. 

8  Shdt  is  a  generic  term  applying  to  sheep  as  well  as  to  goats,  al- 
though in  common  usage  it  means  sheep. 
1  Hiddyah,  p.  135. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  255 

the  jadha' s,  i.  e.f  young  ganam  under  one  year  and  above 
six  months  old.  This  is  the  Zahir-al-riwftyah  view.  How- 
ever there  is  a  report  from  Abu  Hanifah  through  al-Hasan 
to  the  effect  that,  although  only  the  thanis  of  goats  are  ac- 
cepted in  payment  of  zakat,  in  the  case  of  sheep  both  the 
thanis  and  the  jadha's  are  accepted.  This  is  the  gayr  Zahir- 
al-riwayah  view.  This  is  also  the  view  of  Abu  Yusuf  and 
Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan.  The  ground  for  this  view  is 
the  hadith :  "  We  have  a  right  on  the  jadlia'  and  the  thani." 
Moreover  the  jadha's  of  the  sheep  are  lawful  for  sacrifice, 
and  hence  for  zakat  also.  The  ground  for  the  first  view  is 
a  hadith  of  the  calif  'Ali,  to  wit:  "  In  zakat  only  the  thanis 
and  what  is  older  is  taken  ".  Furthermore  the  lawfulness 
of  the  jadhaf  in  sacrifice  is  not  to  the  point,  because  there 
it  is  based  on  a  special  prescription  (nass)  which  is  against 
analogy  and  therefore  cannot  be  extended  to  the  case  of 
zakat.  Besides,  the  jadhae  mentioned  in  the  hadith  in  regard 
to  sacrifice  refers  to  the  jadha'  of  camels.  The  author  of 
the  Path  *  observes  that  although  the  first  view  is  Zahir-al- 
riwayah,  the  second  view  which  allows  the  acceptance  of 
the  jadha'  is  to  be  preferred.  According  to  the  Durrt*  the 
jadha'  may  be  accepted  at  its  appraised  value. 

According  to  the  prevalent  Shafiite  view,8  the  zakat  of 
ganam  is  paid  in  terms  of  one-year-old  sheep  (jadha' ah)  or 
two-year-old  goats  (thaniyyah).  On  the  other  hand,  ac- 
cording to  the  Malikites,4  it  is  paid  in  terms  of  one-year-old 
sheep  or  goats. 

According  to  the  Hanifites,  as  well  as  the  Malikites,  in 
ganam  both  sexes  are  acceptable  for  payment  as  zakat,  but 

1  P.  136. 

1  P.  136. 

•  Minhdj,  pp.  229,  233;  Wajiz,  p.  80. 

4Kharashi,  p.  56. 


256  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

in  al-ShafiTs  opinion,  males  are  lawful  payment  only  when 
the  entire  nisab  consists  of  males,  because  males  alone  can- 
not procreate  but  are  acceptable  in  the  latter  case  because 
the  zakat  must  be  a  part  of  the  nisab.  The  Hanifite  argu- 
ment is  that  the  word  shat  occurring  in  the  hadith  applies 
to  both  sexes.1 

When  the  sheep  and  goats  are  mixed  together,  it  is  unani- 
mously agreed  that  they  are  to  be  counted  indiscriminately 
in  reckoning  the  nisab.  This  is  also  true  when  buffaloes 
and  baqr  are  mixed  together.  According  to  the  Hanifites, 
the  zakat  is  taken  from  animals  of  average  value  when  the 
two  species  are  mixed.  There  are  two  views  on  this  point 
by  al-Shafi'i.  One  view  is  that  the  zakat  is  taken  from  the 
size  that  predominates  because  importance  always  attaches 
to  the  predominant.  The  other  view  is  that  one  of  large 
size  and  one  of  small  size  are  appraised  and  their  average 
is  computed ;  then  an  animal  of  that  value  is  taken  as  zakat ; 
both  sides  being  thus  considered.2 

The  Zakat  of  Horses  (khayl).3"  Horses,  when  males  and 
females  are  together,  pay  zakat,  according  to  Abu  Hanif  ah, 
if  they  are  sawa'im.  The  owner  has  the  option  of  paying  a 
dinar  for  each  horse  without  regard  to  the  requirement  of 
nisab,  or  of  appraising  them  and,  if  their  value  amounts  to 
a  nisab,  of  paying  at  the  rate  of  5  dirhams  for  every  200 
dirhams.  This  view  has  been  preferred  by  the  authors  of 
the  Majma' ,  Hidayah,  Mabsut,  Bada'i'  and  by  al-Quduri. 
However,  according  to  Abu  Yusuf,  and  Muhammad  Ibn 
al-Hasan,  as  well  as  al-Shafi'i,  there  is  no  zakat  on  horses. 
In  the  fatwa  collection  of  Qadikhan  the  opinion  of  the  latter 
has  been  recommended.  It  must  be  remarked  here  that 

1  Mabsut,  p.  183 ;  cf.  Minhdj,  p.  234. 

*Ibid. 

8  Majma',  p.  164;  Mabsut,  p.  188;  Path,  p.  137. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 

although  Abu  Hanifah  favors  zakat  on  horses,  he  leaves 
the  payment  to  the  voluntary  choice  of  the  owner,  the  state 
having  no  right  to  collect  it  by  force.  According  to  the 
Mabsut,  the  ground  for  this  is  the  fact  that  horses  are 
objects  of  great  desire  and  instruments  of  warfare  and  that 
therefore  greedy  persons  would  wrest  them  from  their 
owners  if  they  knew  of  their  existence. 

If  there  are  only  male  horses  they  are,  by  unanimous 
opinion,  exempt  from  tax,  although  a  report  from  Abu 
Hanifah  points  to  the  contrary.  If,  however,  they  are  all 
female,  there  are  two  views  on  the  matter  from  Abu  Hani- 
fah ;  according  to  one,  they  pay  zakat,  but  according  to  the 
other  they  do  not. 

It  is  stated  in  the  Majma'  that  Abu  Hanifah's  view  to  the 
effect  that  horses  are  subject  to  zakat  applies  only  in  case 
the  horses  have  been  pastured  for  their  offspring  (nasl), 
for  if  they  were  pastured  for  riding  or  transportation  or 
the  conduct  of  holy  war,  they  are  exempt  from  the  tax,  and 
if  they  are  pastured  for  trade,  they  pay  the  zakat  of  trade, 
not  that  of  sawa'im  animals.  This  last  point  is  agreed  to 
also  by  al-Shafi'i.1  The  ground  for  the  view  of  the  dis- 
ciples and  al-Shafi'i  are  the  hadiths :  "  There  is  no  sadaqah 
on  the  Moslem  for  his  slave  and  his  horse  (faros)  ",  and, 
"  I  have  pardoned  my  community  (ummah)  from  the  sada- 
qah of  the  horse  and  the  slave  ".  Moreover,  there  is  ijmtif 
to  the  effect  that  the  imam  cannot  collect  the  zakat  of  horses 
by  force.  Then,  too,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah  himself  the 
zakat  of  horses  is  in  terms  of  value  and  not  in  kind,  but  it 
is  a  well-known  principle  that  the  zakat  of  sawa'im  animals 
is  in  kind.  Al-Shafi'i  further  adds  that  the  Prophet  never 
collected  zakat  from  horses.  Abu  Hanifah's  argument,  on 
the  other  hand,  is  that  according  to  Ibn  al-Zubayr,  quoting 

1  Umm,  p.  22. 


258  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Jabir,  the  Prophet  said :  "For  every  sawa'im  horse  (faros)  *• 
idlnar  or  10  dirhams,  and  there  is  nothing  on  horses  sta- 
tioned in  forts  (murabatah)  ".  Furthermore,  the  calif 
Omar  wrote  to  Abu  'Ubaydah  ordering  him  to  collect 
sakat  from  the  sawaim  horses  at  the  rate  mentioned. 
Again,  in  the  time  of  Marwan  a  council  of  the  Companions 
was  held  on  this  matter  and  in  it  Abu  Hurayrah  said: 
"  There  is  no  sadaqah  on  a  man  for  his  horses  and  slaves  ". 
Marwan  then  said  to  Zayd  Ibn  Thabit :  "  What  do  you  say, 
oh,  Father  of  Sa'id  ?  "  and  Abu  Hurayrah,  wondering  at 
Marwan,  said :  "  I  am  relating  a  hadlth  of  the  Prophet,  and 
he  says :  '  What  do  you  say,  oh  father  of  Sa'id  ?'  "  Zayd, 
thereupon,  observed  that  Abu  Hurayrah  was  telling  the 
truth  but  that  the  Prophet  only  meant  the  horses  of  the 
warriors,  and  that  horses  kept  for  their  offspring  were  sub- 
ject to  sakat  at  the  rate  above  mentioned.  Al-Sarakhsi  says 
that  the  reason  why  the  hadlths  concerning  horses  are  not 
widespread  is  because  horses  in  those  days  were  very  much 
honored  and  used  in  war  only;  and  that  the  sakat  is  col- 
lected in  value  because  the  poor  cannot  use  it  as  such  since 
according  to  Abu  Hanifah  the  flesh  of  horse  is  not  lawful 
for  eating. 

As  regards  the  two  views  of  Abu  Hanifah  concerning 
mares  when  they  are  alone,  the  ground  for  one  is  that  the 
productivity  of  horses  consists  in  their  offspring  and  is 
therefore  absent  when  the  mares  are  alone.  The  ground  for 
the  other  view  is  that  mares  may  produce  offspring  by  the 
use  of  a  borrowed  stallion  (fahl).  Finally,  the  ground  for 
Abu  Hanifah's  view  that  male  horses  when  they  are  alone 
do  not  pay  sakat  is  the  fact  that  male  horses  by  themselves 
cannot  produce  offspring,  and  their  value  does  not  increase 
with  age  as  is  the  case  in  other  animals,  neither  is  their 

1  Faras  is  a  generic  term  applying  to  male  and  female  as  well  as  to 
Arabian  and  foreign  horses. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


259 


growth  in  flesh  of  any  account  since  their  flesh  may  not  be 
eaten. 

As  regards  the  option  of  the  owner  between  the  two 
rates,  it  is  based  on  a  hadlth  from  the  Prophet  as  well  as 
the  practices  of  Omar  and  Zayd  Ibn  Thabit.  Some  said  that 
this  applies  only  to  the  Arab  horses  because  they  all  have 
about  the  same  value,  that  consequently  in  other  horses  the 
zakat  is  paid  at  the  rate  of  five  for  two  hundred  on  the  basis 
of  their  appraised  value.  However,  the  author  of  the 
Majma'  observes  that  if  this  applies  to  the  Arab  horses 
which  are  higher  in  price  it  ought  to  apply  a  -fortiori  to  non- 
Arab  horses.  Still  others  say,  that  it  applies  only  to  horses 
having  the  same  value,  and  that  horses  varying  in  value 
pay  the  zakat  on  the  basis  of  their  appraised  value. 

Mules  (bigal)  and  asses  (hamir)  do  not  pay  the  zakat  of 
sawa'im  animals  even  if  they  are  sawa'im,  but  they  pay  like 
other  things  the  zakat  of  trade  if  they  are  intended  for  trade. 
The  ground  for  this  is  the  fact  that  asses  and  mules  in  spite 
of  their  large  numbers  are  not  pastured  in  most  of  the 
cities,  and,  in  law,  importance  attaches  only  to  the  predomi- 
nant and  the  general.  "  Therefore  there  is  no  zakat  on 
them  but  God,  may  he  be  praised  and  exalted !  knows  better 
the  right."  x 

According  to  the  Majma',  there  is  a  hadlth  to  the  effect 
that  asses  do  not  pay  zakat ,  and  that  if  asses  do  not  pay 
mules  also  must  not  pay,  since  they  are  the  offspring  of 
asses. 

The  Zakat  of  the  Young.2  There  is  no  zakat  on  the 
young  of  camels  (fasil,  plural  fuslan)  and  the  young  of 
sheep  and  goats  (hamal,  plural  hiimlan)  *  and  of  cows 
('ijjawl,  plural  'ajajil)  which  are  under  one  year  of  age. 


1  Mabsut,  p.  189. 

1  Durr,  p.  136, 1.  — 12. 


*  Majma',  p.  165. 


26o  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

That  is  to  say,  if  a  man  were  to  purchase  twenty-five  camel 
colts  or  forty  kids  or  thirty  calves,  all  under  one  year  old, 
or  if  the  same  were  given  to  him  as  a  gift  and  one  complete 
year  passed  from  the  time  of  acquisition,  still  no  zakat 
would  be  due  on  them  until  a  year  passed  from  the  day 
they  became  one  year  old.1  This  is  according  to  Muham- 
mad Ibn  al-Hasan  and  the  last  opinion  of  Abu  Hanifah.  In 
this  connection  Abu  Yusuf  is  quoted  as  saying : 

I  went  to  see  Abu  Hanifah  and  said  to  him :  "  What  do 
you  say  concerning  a  person  who  owns  forty  lambs  (ha- 
mal)  ?"  He  said :  "  One  grown  sheep  (shat)  is  due  "on 
them."  Then  I  said :  "  Perhaps  the  value  of  that  one  sheep 
will  equal  that  of  most  of  the  lambs  or  of  all  of  them."  He 
reflected  for  a  while  and  said:  "  No,  one  of  the  lambs  is 
taken."  I  said:  "Are  then  lambs  taken  as  sakat?"  He 
thought  a  while  and  said :  "  No,  in  that  case  nothing  is  due 
on  them." 

Some  of  the  doctors  dismissed  this  story  as  too  childish  to 
be  true  of  Abu  Hanifah.  Others,  however,  objected  to  a 
similar  construction  claiming  that  the  report  was  too  wide- 
spread (of  the  mashhur  type)  to  be  set  aside  and  that  under 
the  circumstances  the  right  thing  to  do  was  to  explain  the 
matter  as  best  they  could.  And  so  they  said  that  Abu  Hani- 
fah was  merely  trying  to  see  if  Abu  Yusuf,  his  disciple,  had 
learned  the  art  of  discussion  and  when  he  saw  that  he  had, 
he  expressed  the  view  he  really  believed  in.  Zufar's  and 
Malik's  views  are  at  one  with  the  first  view  of  Abu  Hani- 
fah, but  the  views  of  Abu  Yusuf  and  al-Shafi'i  agree  with 
his  second  view,  namely,  that  the  young  pay  sakat,  but  that 
it  is  one  of  the  young  that  is  taken  as  such.2 

1  Path,  pp.  139-140. 

JC/.  Mawardi,  p.  199;  Wajiz,  p.  82;  Minhdj,  p.  235;  Muwatta,  pp. 
113-4;  Kharashi,  pp.  52,  56. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  26l 

Some  remark  that  the  foregoing  difference  in  reality 
turns  on  the  question  as  to  when  the  year  begins  to  run, 
not  whether  or  not  lambs  pay  zakat,  since  by  the  end  of 
the  year  when  zakat  is  due  they  cease  to  be  "  lambs  ". 
Others,  however,  observe  that  the  difference  turns  on  the 
question  of  the  continuation  of  the  year,  namely,  if  the 
sheep  should  bear  young  during  the  year  and  perish  before 
its  completion,  whether  or  not  their  year  continues  with 
respect  to  their  young.  If,  however,  among  the  young 
there  are  grown-ups,  be  it  only  one,  then  both  young  and 
old  are  counted  in  reckoning  up  the  nisdb,  although  the 
young  are  not  accepted  for  zakat,  and  if  the  nisdb  is  com- 
plete the  zakat  is  due.  Thus,  if  there  are  39  lambs  and  one 
grown-up  sheep,  the  sheep  is  taken  as  zakat  after  the  lapse 
of  a  year.  But  if  the  sheep  dies  after  the  completion  of  the 
year,  then  according  to  Abu  Hanifah  and  Muhammad,  the 
rest  are  exempt  from  zakat  since  it  became  due  by  virtue  of 
the  sheep,  but  according  to  Abu  Yusuf  there  is  due  on  them 
a  zakat  of  39/40  of  a  lamb.1 

SECTION  III 

The  Zakat  of  Gold  and  Silver  and  the  Articles  of  Trade  ' 
Some  texts  treat  this  section  under  the  general  caption  of 
"  zakat  of  commercial  capital  "  (zakat  al-mal)  as  distin- 
guished from  "  zakat  of  sawtfim  ".*  Other  texts  treat  it 
under  several  captions,  such  as  "  zakat  of  gold  and  silver  ", 
or  "  zakat  of  gold  "  and  "  zakat  of  silver  ",  and  "  zakat 
of  articles  of  trade  ".*  However,  they  all  agree  that  the 

1  Path,  p.  141. 

'Ma; wo',  p.  168;  Mabs&t,  p.  189;  Hiddyah,  p.  158;  Umm,  p.  33; 
Mawardi,  p.  206;  Kharashi,  p.  81 ;  Dardir,  p.  118. 

*C/.  Durar,  pp.  115,  118;  Durr,  p.  138;  Hiddyah,  p.  158;  Mabstt,  P. 
189- 

«  Quduri,  p.  22;  Umm,  pp.  33,  34,  39,  etc. 


262  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

zakat  of  sawa'im  animals  is  a  tax  on  the  animals  by  reason 
of  their  physical  identity  ((ayn),  while,  on  the  contrary, 
the  zakat  of  the  articles  of  trade,  and,  according  to  the 
Hanifites  only,  also  of  gold  and  silver,  is  due  by  reason  of 
their  commercial  value  (qimah).  Consequently  in  the 
articles  of  trade  the  meaning  of  productivity  is  considered 
with  reference  to  their  value  just  as  in  the  sawaim  it  is 
considered  with  reference  to  the  animals  as  such  ('ayn).** 
Notwithstanding  that  the  zakat  is  by  reason  of  the  value, 
not  the  physical  identity  ('ayn),  according  to  the  Hanifites, 
the  zakat  of  a  given  article  nevertheless  attaches  to  its  physi- 
cal identity.  With  respect  to  the  articles  of  trade  al-Shafi'i 
remarks  that  the  zakat  attaches  to  their  value  because  it 
became  due  by  reason  of  it.2  The  Hanifites  answer  that  al- 
though the  zakat  obligation  attaches  to  one's  trade  property 
by  reason  of  its  commercial  value  (sifat  al-maliyyah) ,  inas- 
much as  a  given  piece  of  property  has  a  physical  identity 
of  its  own,  the  zakat  which  fell  due  on  that  piece  of  prop- 
erty attaches  to  its  physical  identity.* 

According  to  the  Hanifites,  the  zakat  of  trade  is  given 
preference  in  case  of  conflict  between  the  zakat  of  trade 
and  the  zakat  of  sawa'im.  Thus  if  a  person  has  sawa'im 
camels  which  he  bought  for  trade,  the  camels  pay  the  zakat 
of  trade  only.  Al-Shafi'i  *  agrees  that  the  same  property 
pays  one  zakat  only  but  he  holds  that  in  such  case  it  is  the 
zakat  of  sawa'im  that  must  be  paid,  unless  the  nisab  of 
camels,  considered  as  sawa'im,  is  not  complete,  for  in  that 
case  they  pay  zakat  as  articles  of  trade  if  their  value  amounts 
to  a  nisab.  The  argument  of  al-Shafi'i  is  that  the  zakat  of 

lMabsut,  p.  190. 

1  Umm,  p.  33. 

1  Mabstt,  p.  191,  1.  —io. 

4  Cf.  Umm,  p.  41,  I.  20;  Minhdj,  p.  253;  Wajls,  p.  05. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  263 

sawaim  is  a  stronger  obligation  because  the  entire  commu- 
nity has  agreed  that  it  is  a  wdjib  and  because  it  is  based  on 
clear,  revealed  statements  (nass  zahir).  Since  the  weak 
may  not  conflict  with  the  strong,  when  a  property  is  subject 
to  zakat  both  as  sawaim  and  as  an  article  of  trade,  it  pays 
zakat  as  sawaim  only.  Moreover  in  the  preference  of  the 
zakat  of  sawaim  there  is  advantage  for  the  poor,  because 
the  zakat  of  sawa'im  is  collected  by  the  collector  whereas 
the  zakd,t  of  trade  property  is  paid  by  the  owners  themselves 
"  and  often  they  do  not  pay  it  ".  The  Hanifite  argument, 
on  the  other  hand,  is  that  as  soon  as  animals  are  intended 
for  trade,  the  purpose  of  pasture  and  the  cause  (sabab)  of 
the  zakat  of  sawa'im  cease  to  exist.  For  the  productivity 
of  the  sawa'im  is  physical  and  necessitates  that  the  animals 
be  permanently  retained  in  one's  ownership,  but  the  inten- 
tion of  trade  militates  against  this,  and  so  the  animals  in 
reality  cease  to  be  sawa'im.  On  the  contrary,  they  become 
trade  property  both  in  appearance  (siirah)  and  in  reality 
(ma'na)  and  therefore  the  zakat  of  trade  is  given  prefer- 
ence. However,  the  right  to  collect  this  zakat  of  animals 
still  belongs  to  the  state  collector,  irrespective  of  whether 
they  are  subject  to  the  zakat  of  sawa'im  or  of  trade  because 
they  are  always  apparent  property  and  stand  in  need  of  the 
imam's  protection.1  The  Malikite  2  view  on  this  point  is 
like  the  Shafiite,  for  according  to  the  Malikites  the  zakat  of 
trade  applies  to  such  articles  only  as  are  not  subject  to  sakat 
by  reason  of  their  physical  identity. 

The  classes  of  goods  subject  to  the  zakat  of  wealth  are  : 

(1)  Gold  (dhahab),  whether  bullion  or  wrought. 

(2)  Silver  (fiddah),  whether  bullion  or  wrought. 

(3)  Articles  of  trade  ('urud  al-tijarah). 


t,  p.  170. 
2  Kharashi,  p.  99;  'Adawi,  p.  99;  Dardlr,  p.  121. 


264  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Gold  and  Silver.  The  nisab  of  gold  is  20  mithqals  x  and 
the  nisab  of  silver  is  200  dirhams.  The  rate  of  zakat  both 
in  gold  and  silver  is  one-fourth  of  one-tenth  of  the  nisab, 
i.  e.}  one-half  mithqal  in  20  mithqals  of  gold  and  5  dirhams 
in  200  dirhams  of  silver. 

There  is  no  sakat  for  less  than  20  mithqals  of  gold  and 
200  dirhams  of  silver  because  of  the  hadtths  :  "  There  is  no 
sakat  on  gold  until  its  value  amounts  to  200  dirhams,"  and 
"  There  is  no  sakat  on  silver  until  it  reaches  200  dirhams 
and  when  it  reaches  200  dirhams  the  sakat  on  it  is  5  dir- 


*A mithqdl  literally  means  any  measure  of  weight.  In  general  usage 
it  denotes  the  weight  of  a  piece  of  gold  weighing  20  qirdts.  A  qirdt  is 
the  weight  of  5  medium-sized  grains  of  barley  whose  husk  has  not 
been  removed  but  whose  projecting  ends  have  been  cut  off.  The 
mithqdl  is  then  100  grains.  This  is  according  to  the  later  canonists 
and  to  the  weight  system  of  Hijaz  and  most  of  the  cities.  According 
to  the  earlier  writers  and  to  the  weight  system  of  Samarqand,  a  mithqdl 
is  6  ddniqs,  a  ddniq  4  tassiijs,  a  tassuj  2  habbahs,  and  a  habbah  2 
grains  ;  in  other  words,  a  mithqdl  is  96  grains,  or  19  qirdts  and  I  grain, 
instead  of  the  100  grains  or  20  qirdts  of  the  former  version.  Dindr 
literally  means  a  round  gold  coin,  and  technically  a  mithqdl's  weight 
of  such  coins.  Likewise  dirham  literally  means  a  round  silver  coin, 
and  technically  the  weight  of  such  a  coin.  There  have  been  various 
versions  concerning  the  weight  of  a  dirham  in  terms  of  a  mithqdl,  a 
dirham  being,  according  to  these  estimates,  1/2,  6/10,  9/10  of,  or  I 
mithqdl.  Later  in  the  time  of  the  calif  Omar  the  weight  of  the  dirham 
was  fixed  at  7/10  of  a  mithqdl.  This  last  ratio  is  called  the  septimal 
weight  (wazn  sab'ah)  and  is  the  weight  used  in  zakdt.  {Tech.  Diet., 
p.  500;  Majma',  p.  169.)  According  to  certain  doctors  in  zakdt  it  is 
the  weight  of  each  locality  that  is  taken  into  consideration,  (fdmi1,  p. 
311.)  For  the  Shafiite  and  Malikite  views  on  the  matter,  see  Minhdj 
(p.  244),  Mawardi  (p.  206)  and  Kharashi  (p.  81).  According  to  the 
Mabstit  (p.  100),  at  the  time  of  the  Prophet,  the  dinar  was  valued  at 
10  dirhams',  in  other  words,  I  mithqdl  of  gold  was  worth  10  dirhams 
of  silver.  There  are  various  versions  concerning  the  weight  of  a 
dirham  in  terms  of  a  mithqdl,  but  the  version  generally  accepted  is 
that  a  dirham  was  H  of  a  mithqdl.  The  value  of  gold,  then,  in  rela- 
tion to  that  of  silver  seems  to  have  been  as  i  to  5,  or,  according  to  the 
most  extreme  version,  as  i  to  10.  In  Hamilton's  English  translation 
of  the  Hiddyah,  the  dirham  is  valued  at  about  2  pence  sterling. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  26$ 

After  the  first  20  mithqals  and  200  dirhams,  the  zakat 
for  every  additional  4  mithqals  and  40  dirhanis  is  2  more 
qlrats  of  gold  and  i  more  dirham  of  silver  respectively.  If 
the  additional  amount  after  the  20  mithqals  or  200  dirhams 
is  below  the  above-mentioned  quantities,  according  to  Abu 
Hanifah  there  is  no  zakat  on  it.  According  to  Abu  Yusuf 
and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  as  well  as  al-Shafi'i,1  and 
the  Malikites,2  such  additional  quantity  even  if  less  than  4 
mithqals  and  40  dirhams  respectively  is  subject  to  a  propor- 
tional amount  of  zakat,  namely,  at  the  rate  of  one-fourth 
of  one-tenth.  The  ground  for  this  view  is  the  hadlth  of 
'Ali :  "  and  for  what  is  beyond  200,  accordingly,"  and  also 
the  fact  that  zakat  is  a  return  of  gratitude  for  the  blessing 
of  property,  and  therefore,  although  in  the  beginning  the 
nisab  is  necessary  in  order  that  the  state  of  wealthiness  may 
be  realized,  when  the  nisab  is  once  complete,  any  excess,  no 
matter  how  little,  operates  to  increase  the  state  of  wealthi- 
ness to  a  corresponding  degree  and  therefore  it  must  pay 
zakat  proportionally,  without  regard  to  nisab  requirements.3 
Abu  Hanifah,  on  the  other  hand,  in  support  of  his  view 
invokes  among  others  the  hadlth :  "  For  every  200  dirhams t 
5  dirhams,  and  for  every  40  dirhams,  I  dirham"  where  the 
nisab  of  40  dirhams  is  mentioned  after  that  of  200  and  ap- 
parently is  meant  as  a  secondary  nisab  which  is  to  come 
into  operation  after  the  first  nisab  of  200.  Moreover,  in 
the  case  of  sawa'im  animals  there  was  after  the  first  nisab 
an  interval  (waqs)  exempt  from  zakat  and  it  is  reasonable 
that  there  should  be  one  in  gold  and  silver  also.  Finally, 
the  hadlth  of  'Ali  invoked  by  the  opponents  has  never  been 
traced  (marfu')  to  the  Prophet.  Al-Shafi'i,  in  answer  to 
the  argument  derived  from  the  analogy  of  sawa'im  animals 

1  Cf.  Wajis,  p.  92.  *  Kharashi,  p.  81. 

8  Mabstt,  pp.  189-90. 


266  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

with  respect  to  the  intervals  which  do  not  pay  zakat,  says 
that  in  the  animals  this  must  necessarily  be  so  in  order  to 
avoid  forced  partnership  between  the  state  and  the  zakat 
payer  in  cases  where  the  sakat  would  be  a  fraction  of  an 
animal.  The  'Inayah,  on  the  other  hand,  retorts,  on  the 
ground  of  administrative  expediency,  that  if  in  silver,  for 
example,  an  excess  of  fewer  than  forty  dirhams  were  taken 
into  account  the  determination  of  the  zakat,  and  certainly 
its  payment,  would  be  very  difficult  and  often  impossible 
owing  to  the  incommensurate  numbers  and  the  minute  frac- 
tions that  would  result  from  such  a  procedure.1 

In  regard  to  the  zakat  of  gold  and  silver  the  following 
points  must  be  borne  in  mind : 

(i)  From  the  standpoint  of  zakat,  bullion  (tibr)  gold 
and  silver  is  like  wrought  or  coined  ('ayri)  gold  and 
silver,2  such  as  the  dirhams  and  dinars  or  the  ornaments, 
decorations,  and  plate  made  of  them.  Gold  and  silver 
wrought  for  purposes  of  decoration  and  personal  adorn- 
ment pay  zakat  as  bullion,  whether  or  not  they  are  used  by 
women,  whether  or  not  the  amount  used  is  excessive,  and 
finally,  whether  they  are  kept  for  purchase  of  necessaries 
(nafaqah),  for  personal  adornment  or  for  trade.  Accord- 
ing to  Malik,  gold  and  silver  do  not  pay  zakat  if  used  for 
lawful  purposes.  There  is  also  a  report  from  al-Shafi'i 
to  the  same  effect.  The  use  of  gold  and  silver  by 
women  for  personal  adornment  is  considered  lawful. 
On  the  other  hand,  men  as  a  rule  may  not  use  either  of  the 
two  metals  for  personal  adornment,  excepting  silver  seals, 
gold  nose  rings  and  silver-covered  arms.  Gold  and  silver 
plate,  however,  is  forbidden  for  both  sexes.3  The  ground 
for  the  Malikite  and  Shafiite  view  is  that  gold  or  silver  used 

1  Hiddyah  and  'Indyah,  p.  160.  *  Jdmi',  p.  311. 

8  For  details  see  Kharashi,  p.  86;  Dardir,  p.  119;  Mawardi,  p.  207; 
Minhdj,  p.  244;  Umm,  p.  355  Waji*.  P-  93- 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  26/ 

in  the  ways  mentioned,  is,  like  one's  personal  clothing,  in- 
tended for  everyday  use  which  is  a  lawful  purpose.  The 
Hanifite  argument  is  that  they  are  productive  property  and 
must  pay  zakat.  The  productivity  here  consists  in  the  fact 
that,  unlike  clothing,  gold  and  silver  are  by  nature  intended 
for  trade.1 

(2)  In  determining  whether  or  not  the  nisab  is  com- 
plete and  a  zakat  is  due  (wujub)  it  is  the  weight  and  not 
the  value  or  number  (fadad)  that  is  taken  into  account. 
Thus  if  one  should  have  a  golden  or  silver  pitcher  weighing 
ten  mithqals  or  one  hundred  dirhams  but  owing  to  its  artis- 
tic value  worth  twenty  mithqals  or  two  hundred  dirhams  it 
is  not  subject  to  zakat. *  This  point  is  agreed  upon  unani- 
mously. There  is,  however,  difference  of  opinion  as  td 
payment.  According  to  Abu  Hanifah  and  Abu  Yusuf  it 
is  still  the  weight  that  serves  as  basis.  Zufar  claims  that 
the  value  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  contends  that  the 
one  that  is  more  favorable  to  the  poor  serves  as  a  basis. 
Thus  if  one  should  give  in  payment  of  zakat,  instead  of 
five  good  dirhams,  five  spurious  ones  worth  four  good  ones, 
the  zakat  debt  is  discharged,  according  to  the  two  first  doc- 
tors, since  the  weight  in  both  cases  is  the  same,  but  ac- 
cording to  the  others  it  is  not.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  he 
should  give  four  good  dirhams  worth  five  bad  ones  in  the 
place  of  five  bad  ones,  there  is  still  due  a  fifth  dirham,  but 
according  to  Zufar,  who  takes  into  consideration  the 
value,  the  entire  debt  is  discharged.  The  above  ap- 
plies only  when  a  zakat  debt  is  paid  in  terms  of  its  own 
genus,  for  it  is  admitted  unanimously  that  when  the  zakat 
debt  is  paid  in  terms  of  another  genus,  it  is  the  value  that 
is  taken  into  consideration.  The  Shafiites  and  Malikites  * 

1  Majma",  p.  169. 

1  Babr,  p.  244;  /ami',  p.  311;  Afa/ma',  p.  168;  ' Alamkiriyyah,  p.  251. 

*  Cf.  Umm,  p.  34;  Kharashi,  p.  81. 


268  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

take  into  consideration  always  the  weight  only,  for  accord- 
ing to  them  gold  and  silver  pay  zakat  by  reason  of  their 
physical  identity  and  not  their  value. 

(3)  I*  Sold  ar  silver  be  mixed  with  an  alloy  (gishsh)* 
it  is  considered  as  pure  if  the  alloy  is  less  than  half  the  con- 
tent. For  instance,  if  one  should  possess  dinars  and  dir- 
hams  which  contained  more  than  fifty  per  cent  of  gold  and 
silver  respectively  they  would  pay  zakat  as  gold  and  silver 
at  the  full  rate.  If  the  alloy  just  equals  the  nobler  metal, 
it  does  not  then  pay  as  gold  and  silver,  although  some  say 
that  it  still  pays  the  full  rate,  and  others,  that  it  pays  only 
a  half  rate.  Finally,  if  the  alloy  predominates  over  the 
gold  or  silver,  the  article  is  considered  to  belong  in  the 
class  of  lurud  and  as  such  it  pays  zakat  according  to  value, 
if  it  comes  under  the  description  of  an  article  of  trade  or  is 
used  as  currency  (thaman  rafij).  This  is  in  case  the  gold 
or  silver  cannot  be  separated  to  pay  zakat  independently 
according  to  weight,  for  in  such  case  the  precious  metal  is 
legally  deemed  to  be  destroyed.  Consequently,  if  the  gold 
or  silver  can  be  separated,  according  to  most  doctors,  it 
pays  zakat  by  weight.  According  to  others,  however,  if 
the  article  was  intended  for  trade  it  pays  the  zakat  of 
trade  according  to  value,  even  if  the  gold  or  silver  can  be 
separated.2  According  to  one  view,  in  gold  and  silver 
coins  it  is  not  necessary  actually  to  separate  the  precious 
metal  and  it  is  sufficient  if  it  is  known  that  they  contain  a 
nisab  weight  of  the  metal  in  question.  According  to  the 
Shafiites,3  alloys  pay  zakat  for  the  precious  metal  they  con- 
tain only  in  case  the  latter  by  itself  amounts  to  a  nisab 
weight. 


1  Jam?,  p.  312. 

8  Path  al-Mu'in,  p.  390. 

*  Minhdj,  p.  244;  Umm,  p.  33;  Mugni,  p.  380. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  269 

When  gold  is  mixed  with  silver  instead  of  with  an  alloy, 
if  the  gold  predominates  over  the  silver,  then  the  entire  con- 
tents are  taxed  as  pure  gold.  If,  on  the  contrary,  the  silver 
predominates,  then  each  pays  zakat  separately  if  of  nisab 
weight.1  According  to  the  Shafiites,2  when  gold  and  silver 
are  mixed  together  it  is  not  allowed  to  pay  zakat  for  the 
whole  as  pure  gold,  since  the  zakat  of  silver  is  not  dis- 
charged unless  it  is  paid  in  silver.  If  the  weight  of  each 
metal  is  not  known,  e.  g.,  if  a  vase  is  made  of  silver  and 
gold,  600  dirhams  of  one  and  400  of  the  other,  but  it  is 
not  known  which,  then  the  zakat  payer  may  proceed  to  de- 
termine the  matter,  as  in  the  case  of  other  alloys,  by  melt- 
ing, etc.,  or  if  he  is  of  age  and  is  paying  his  own  zakat,  he 
may,  in  order  to  avoid  sin,  resort  to  extreme  precaution 
(ihtiyat)  and  pay  zakat  of  gold  for  600  dirhams,  and  also 
zakat  of  silver  for  600  dirhams. 

According  to  al-Haytami,3  in  case  of  alloys,  if  the  zakat 
payer  does  not  know  the  amount  of  zakat  which  he  must 
pay,  he  resorts  to  the  opinion  of  two  experts  or  determines 
it  by  the  method  of  water  displacement.  If  neither  way  is 
possible,  he  has  the  option  of  melting  the  article  and  paying 
the  zakat  of  the  precious  metal,  or  paying  the  zakat  for  the 
nisabs  of  which  he  is  sure  (tayaqqana)  and,  by  way  of  pre- 
caution and  in  order  to  avoid  committing  a  sin  (ihtiydt), 
also  for  the  nisabs  of  which  he  is  not  positive.  This,  how- 
ever, applies  only  in  case  the  zakat  payer  is  paying  his  own 
zakat,  for,  if  he  is  paying  the  zakat  of  his  ward  (mahjur 
'alayh),  he  has  no  right  to  resort  to  extreme  precaution  and 
pay  for  the  nisabs  of  which  he  is  not  positive.  In  fact  this 
is  the  way  of  procedure :  he  consults  two  experts  and  pays 

1  Durr,  p.  138;  'Alamkiriyyoh,  p.  251. 
*Mugni,  p.  380;  Angari,  p.  377;  Wajiz,  p.  93. 

*Al-l<atdwa  al-Kubra,  vol.  ii,  pp.  34-5;  cf.  Umm,  p.  34;  Wajls,  p.  93; 
Mugni,  p.  380;  An§ari,  p.  377. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

according  to  their  opinion ;  or  he  determines  the  proportion 
of  the  precious  metal  by  means  of  its  water  displacement. 
If  these  two  methods  are  not  possible,  he  melts  a  small  part 
of  the  article,  if  that  is  possible.  If,  however,  the  amount 
of  the  metal  can  only  be  determined  by  melting  the  whole 
of  the  article  or  an  important  part  of  it,  either  method  re- 
sulting in  a  decrease  of  the  value  of  the  article,  he  pays  the 
zakat  only  for  the  nisabs  of  which  he  is  positive  but  not  for 
those  about  which  he  is  doubtful. 

The  weight  of  the  precious  metal  is  determined  by  water 
in  two  ways:  (i)  The  article  in  question  is  immersed  in  a 
vessel  containing  water  and  the  level  of  the  water  is  marked. 
Then  equal  weights  of  the  precious  metal  and  of  the  alloy  in 
question  are  immersed  and  the  level  of  the  water  is  again 
marked  for  each.  If  the  mark  for  the  article  is,  for  in- 
stance, equally  distant  from  the  other  two  marks,  then  the 
alloy  and  the  precious  metal  are  half  and  half,  and  similarly 
for  other  proportions.  (2)  The  article  in  question,  which, 
for  example,  weighs  10  dirhams,  is  immersed  in  the  water 
and  the  level  is  marked.  Then  the  weight  of  the  precious 
metal  and  of  the  alloy  which  will  displace  the  water  to  the 
same  level  are  successively  determined.  If  then  the  weight 
of  the  precious  metal  is  12  and  of  the  alloy  8  dirhams,  it  is 
clear  that  the  proportion  is  half  and  half. 

Articles  of  Trade  (furud  al-tijarah).'1  The  Arabic  word 
for  article  is  'uriid,  plural  of  'arad,  or  'ard,  meaning  wealth 
in  general  except  gold  and  silver.  According  to  Abu 
'Ubayd,  'urild  applies  to  every  thing  which  is  not  meas- 
ured by  volume  or  weight  and  is  not  animal  or  real 
estate  (laqar).  The  author  of  the  Path2  approves  of  the 
first  definition  because  every  thing  except  gold  and  silver 
may  become  an  article  of  trade  and  pay  zakat  as  such.  This 

',  p.  169;  Utnm,  p.  39;  Zarqani,  p.  51.  2   P.  165. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  271 

is  also  the  Malikite  view.1  The  author  of  the  Majnta',  on 
the  other  hand,  finds  the  first  definition  too  broad  and  pre- 
fers the  second,  but  is  willing  to  allow  for  animals  and  in- 
clude them  in  the  definition,  since  animals  also,  even  when 
they  are  sawa'im,  may  become  articles  of  trade.  What- 
ever may  be  the  views  of  the  Mohammedan  doctors  on  the 
meaning  of  the  word  'uriid,  it  seems  clear  that  it  covers 
every  article  except  gold  and  silver,  since  every  article  ex- 
cept those  two  may  become  an  "  article  of  trade  "  and  pay 
zakat  as  such.  In  other  words,  even  real  estate  comes  under 
'urud,  for  as  the  author  of  the  Durr  2  rightly  remarks,  the 
fact  that  a  piece  of  land  subject  to  kharaj,  for  instance,  does 
not  pay  the  trade  zakat,  does  not  prevent  it  from  being  an 
article  of  trade,  since  it  is  merely  the  result  of  the  desire 
not  to  have  the  same  article  subject  to  two  taxes  at  the  same 
time. 

According  to  al-Shafi'i,  the  zakat  of  trade  articles  is  based 
on  the  practice  of  the  califs  Omar  I.  and  Omar  II.8 

All  articles  which  come  under  the  description  of  'wrudf 
whether  or  not  they  are  otherwise  subject  to  zakat,  as 
sawa'im  animals,  and  mules  and  asses,  are  subject  to  the 
sakat  of  trade  as  soon  as  they  become  "  articles  of  trade  ". 
An  article  technically  becomes  one  of  trade  if  there  ha$ 
been  with  regard  to  it  an  intention  of  trade  coupled  with  an 
act  to  bear  the  intention  out.  This  requirement  is  because 
of  the  general  legal  principle  that,  intentions,  in  order  to  be 
effective,  must  be  coupled  with  and,  so  to  say,  perfected  by 
an  act.  The  word  act  is  here  used  in  a  technical  sense, 
meaning  the  commission  of  an  act  as  well  as  its  omission. 
Either  one  of  these  two  kinds  of  acts  may  complete  the  in- 
tention. According  to  the  Path,4  the  rule  in  this  respect  is 

1  Kharashi,  p.  99.  »  P.  138. 

1  Um*t,  p.  39.  4  P.  124. 


272  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

that  in  the  acts  of  omission  (a'mal  al-turuk)  mere  intention 
is  sufficient,  but  that  in  acts  of  commission  (a'mal  al-ja- 
wdrih)  mere  intention  is  not  sufficient  for  the  act  to  be  con- 
sidered complete  but  that  the  intention  must  be  coupled 
with  an  act.  For  example,  a  person  who  is  resident  (mu- 
qim)  may  not  be  legally  considered  as  a  traveler  (musafir) 
if  he  merely  intends  to  undertake  a  journey,  while  a  person 
who  is  already  traveling  becomes  a  resident  by  merely  in- 
tending so.  There  has  been  a  difference  of  opinion  among 
the  Hanifite  doctors  as  to  whether  the  act  needed  to  com- 
plete the  intention  of  trade  may  be  any  act  or  whether  it 
must  be  exclusively  an  act  of  trade,  an  act  of  trade  being 
exchange  of  wealth  against  wealth  for  profit.  For  instance, 
if  a  person  acquires  some  property  through  gift  intending 
it  for  trade,  according  to  Abu  Yusuf  the  property  becomes 
an  article  of  trade,  because  the  intention  has  been  coupled 
with  an  act,  namely,  the  acceptance  of  the  gift.  According 
to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  however,  the  property  does 
not  become  an  article  of  trade  because  the  intention  has 
not  been  coupled  with  an  act  of  trade.  The  ground  for 
the  first  view  is  that,  properly  speaking,  intentions  should 
be  effective  by  themselves,  even  though  unaccompanied  by 
an  act,  because  the  Prophet  said :  "  The  intention  of  the 
believer  is  better  than  his  act ".  However,  as  intentions, 
being  mental,  are  concealed,  they  cannot  become  in  the  nature 
of  things  effective  unless  borne  out  by  an  act.  The  ground 
for  the  other  view  is  that  an  intention  of  trade,  for  example, 
does  not  become  evident  unless  the  act  which  is  to  bring  out 
the  intention  is  also  one  of  trade.  The  net  result  of  these 
differences  is  summarized  in  the  'Inayah  x  as  follows : 

(i)  What  is  inherited,  even  though  intended  for  trade, 
does  not  by  unanimous  opinion  become  an  article  of  trade, 

1  P.  125. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


273 


because  in  this  case  the  act  is  wanting.  This  becomes  clear 
when  it  is  remembered  that  in  Mohammadan  law  inheritance 
is  compulsory  and  takes  effect  without  and  in  spite  of  the 
will  of  the  heirs  who  cannot  refuse  to  be  heirs. 

(2)  What  is  acquired  against  a  consideration  of  wealth 
(nidi),  e.  g.,  through  purchase,  location  (ijarah)  or  loan.1 
Such  acquisitions  become  articles  of  trade  if  intended  for 
trade,  since  there  would  then  be  in  them  both  the  intention 
and  the  act  of  trade.  This  is  also  unanimously  agreed  upon. 

(3)  What  is  acquired  for  a  consideration  that  is  not 
wealth  (mdl),  such  as  the  prices  of  marriage  (mahr)  di- 
vorce (khul'),  and  composition  from  the  right  of  retaliation 
for  murder  (badal  al-sulh  fan  dam  al-'amd),  or  what  is  ac- 
quired for  no  consideration  at  all,  such  as  gifts,  alms  and 
legacies.    According  to  Abu  Yusuf  wealth  acquired  in  these 
ways  comes  under  the  description  of  articles  of  trade  if  in- 
tended  for  trade,  but  it  does  not  so  come  according  to 
Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan. 

According  to  the  Shafiites,2  only  property  acquired  for  a 
consideration,  even  though  one  of  a  non-financial  nature, 
such  as  marriage  and  divorce,  may  become  an  article  of 
trade  by  being  so  intended.  The  Malikite  view  is  like  the 
Shafiite  except  that  it  requires  the  consideration  to  be  finan- 
cial, /.  c.,  other  than  marriage,  etc.9 

According  to  the  Path?  the  above  applies  only  to  articles 
in  regard  to  which  an  intention  of  trade  is  valid,  namely, 
articles  other  than  land,  for  in  land  intention  of  trade  is 
not  valid.  If,  therefore,  a  person  should  buy  a  kharaj  or 
tithe  land  in  order  to  trade  in  it,  he  does  not  pay  for  this 
land  the  sakat  of  trade  but  only  tithe  or  kharaj  because  it 
is  not  lawful  to  tax  a  person  twice  by  reason  of  the  same 


1  Durr,  p.  134. 

1  Minhsj,  p.  251 ;  cf.  Utnm,  p.  40. 

*  Kharashi,  and  'Adawi,  p.  99. 

4   O       T  -.- 


274  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

cause, — ownership  of  land  in  this  instance.  However,  ac- 
cording to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  a  tithe  land  bought 
for  trade  pays  both  the  zakat  of  trade  and  the  tithe.  Ac- 
cording to  al-Shafi'i,1  land  may  become  an  "article  of  trade" 
and  pay  the  zakat  of  trade,  provided  there  is  not  grown 
on  it  a  crop  which  is  subject  to  tithe,  as  in  that  case  only 
tithe  is  levied  on  it. 

The  intention  2  must  be  present  at  the  time  of  the  act, 
otherwise  it  has  no  effect.  If  therefore  one  should  buy  a 
slave  and  later  intend  him  for  trade,  the  slave  does  not 
become  a  slave  of  trade  until  he  is  actually  traded  in  (tas- 
arruf),  because  only  then  will  the  intention  and  the  trade 
have  been  coupled  together. 

If  there  was  no  intention  whatever  at  the  time  of  pur- 
chase, the  article  is  considered  to  have  been  intended 
for  personal  use  (qunyah),  for  the  presumption  is  that  an 
article,  unless  expressly  intended  for  trade,  is  bought  for 
personal  use.3  On  the  other  hand,  an  article  intended  for 
trade  becomes  an  article  of  trade  even  if  it  was  also  in- 
tended to  be  used  personally,  or  rented  (gallah)  meanwhile 
before  its  sale. 

An  article  of  trade  continues  to  be  so  until  it  is  intended 
for  other  than  trade,  whereupon  it  at  once  ceases  to  be  an 
article  of  trade,  although  the  intention  to  trade  has  not 
been  confirmed  by  an  act,  because  in  this  case  the  act  is  one 
of  omission  (of  trade)  and  therefore  mere  intention  is  suf- 
ficient.4 If  afterwards  he  intends  again  to  trade  in  that 
article,  it  does  not  become  an  article  of  trade  until  after  it 
has  been  actually  disposed  of. 

The  intention  of  trade  may  also  be  implied.     For  ex- 

1  Umm,  p.  41 ;  Muzani,  p.  244 ;  cf.  Wajls,  p.  96. 

*  Jam?,  p.  312;  Durr,  p.  134;  Umm,  p.  40;  Kharashi,  p.  99. 

8  Kharashi,  p.  99.  4  Cf.  Umm,  p.  40. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  2?$ 

ample,  if  one  buys  an  article  with  a  trade  article,  or  if  one 
rents  his  house  which  was  intended  for  trade  for  an  article, 
the  articles  received  constitute  articles  of  trade  even  if  they 
have  not  been  intended  for  trade.1  Concerning  the  case  of 
articles  received  as  the  rental  of  articles  intended  for  trade, 
however,  there  is  also  a  report  to  the  contrary.  The  theory 
in  this  case  is  that  as  the  article  given  away  was  one  of 
trade  the  price  obtained  for  it  becomes  substituted  (boded) 
for  it  and  so  no  new  intention  of  trade  is  necessary. 

A  few  examples  from  the  ' 'Alamkiriyyah  2  will  make  clear 
what  is  meant  by  intention  of  trade.  Thus  if  one  should 
buy  brass  pots  in  order  to  rent  them  he  does  not  pay  sakat 

n  them  just  as  he  would  not  pay  sakat  on  houses  intended 
for  renting.  Similarly  if  a  spice  grocer  should  buy  glass 
bottles  or  sacks  in  order  to  rent  them  to  the  people  there  is 
no  zakat  on  them  because  they  are  bought  for  their  use 
and  not  for  trade.  Likewise  the  baker  by  buying  wood  or 
salt  for  baking  is  not  subject  to  zakat,  but  if  he  buys  sesame 
and  makes  it  into  bread  he  pays  zakat  for  it.  However,  if 
a  person  other  than  a  trader  buys  food  for  a  trade  slave 
he  owns,  he  does  not  pay  zakat  for  it.  A  trader  (mudarib), 
on  the  other  hand,  would  do  so. 

Malik,  unlike  the  Hanifites  and  al-Shafi'i,  distinguishes 
between  the  person  who  buys  things  for  speculation  (irti- 
sad  al-aswaq)  by  selling  them  when  he  thinks  the  price  is 
highest,  and  the  person  who,  like  the  store-keepers,  buys 
and  sells  (man  yudiru  mdlahu)  without  waiting  for  specu- 
lation.3 According  to  Malik  the  merchant  who  turns  over 
his  stock  without  waiting  (al-mudlr),  assigns  a  month  of 
the  year  as  the  time  for  the  payment  of  his  zakat  and  in 

1  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  244;  Durr,  p.  134. 
'P.  253. 

*Muwattd',  p.  109;  Mudawwanah,  pp.  u,  14;  Kharashi,  p.  101 ; 
Zarqani,  p.  52;  Mabsut,  p.  190,  1.  — 9;  Ibn  Rushd,  M.,  p.  212. 


276  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

this  month  he  appraises  his  trade  stock  and  adds  to  the  total 
the  claims  he  expects  to  collect  and  pays  zakat  for  the  whole. 
If  however  he  is  merely  a  speculator  (muhtakir),  he  does 
not  pay  zakat  for  the  articles  he  bought  with  the  intention 
of  selling  later  for  profit  every  year  but  only  once  for  all 
when  he  turns  them  into  cash  by  sale, — even  if  meanwhile 
many  years  should  have  passed  from  the  time  of  their  pur- 
chase. Just  as  in  the  case  of  merchandise  he  does  not  pay 
zakat  until  he  has  sold  them,  so  in  claims,  he  does  not  pay 
zakat  on  them  until  he  has  collected  them.  This  is  based 
on  the  hadith :  "  There  is  zakat  only  on  the  produce  of  the 
land  (harth),  on  gold  and  silver  ((ayn),  and  on  animals." 
In  other  words  there  is  no  zakat  on  the  articles  of  trade 
and  the  claims  until  they  have  become  gold  or  silver  by 
sale  and  collection,  respectively.  This  distinction  between 
the  two  kinds  of  trade,  however,  applies  only  to  the  zakat 
of  trade  articles  and  such  claims  as  have  not  arisen  in  con- 
sequence of  loans  (qard),  for  with  respect  to  the  zakat  of 
loans  (of  gold  and  silver),  traders  and  others  are  alike.1 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah  the  articles  of  trade  are  ap- 
praised in  gold  or  silver  coins  (naqd)  according  as  one  or 
the  other  way  is  the  more  profitable  to  the  poor,  that  is,  ac- 
cording as  the  nisab  is  attained  by  appraising  in  terms  of 
one  or  the  other.  Some  said  that  the  advantage  of  the  poor 
is  considered  even  when  the  nisab  is  reached  by  appraising 
in  terms  of  either,  namely,  that  it  is  appraised  in  terms  of 
the  more  current  (arwaj}  of  the  two,  and  that  if  both  have 
the  same  degree  of  currency,  the  owner  has  the  choice  of 
appraising  in  either.2 

According  to  Abu  Yusuf,  if  the  article  was  bought  for 
coins  (naqd}  it  is  appraised  in  terms  of  that  coin,  and  if  it 


1  Mudaitnvanah,  p.  n;  Kharashi,  p.  101,  1.  10. 
8  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  252. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


177 


was  bought  for  other  than  coin,  it  is  appraised  in  terms  of 
the  most  common  (aglab)  coin.  However,  according  to 
Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  it  is  appraised  in  terms  of  the 
most  predominant  (aglab)  currency  in  every  case.1 

According  to  the  Shafiites,2  articles  of  trade,  if  bought 
for  currency  (naqd),  are  appraised  in  terms  of  that  cur- 
rency, otherwise  they  are  appraised  in  terms  of  the  common 
(galib)  currency.  If  there  are  two  such  currencies,  the  ap- 
praisal is  made  in  terms  of  the  currency  which  results  in  a 
.iilfte  nisdb.  If  the  nisab  is  reached  in  either  case,  the 
appraisal  is  made  in  terms  of  the  more  profitable  of  the  two, 
or  at  the  owner's  choice. 

In  appraising  in  terms  of  coins,  the  appraisal  is  made  only 
in  terms  of  coins  which  themselves  are  subject  to  zakat, 
namely,  coins  in  which  the  precious  metal  predominates.3 
Furthermore,  the  appraisal  is  made  in  terms  of  the  currency 
of  the  town  where  the  property  subject  to  zakat  is  situated. 
If  such  property  is  situated  in  the  desert  the  appraisal  is 
made  in  terms  of  the  currency  of  the  nearest  town.4 

Claims  (duyun)*  According  to  Abu  Hanifah,  claims 
are  strong  (qawi),  medium  (ivasat),  or  weak  (da' if). 
Strong  claims  are  those  which  have  arisen  in  considera- 
tion of  an  article  of  trade  or  a  loan,  that  is,  property  which 
would  have  paid  zakat  at  the  end  of  the  year  if  left  in  the 
creditor's  ownership.  Medium  claims  are  those  that  arise 
in  consideration  of  property  which  would  not  have  paid 
zakat  if  left  in  the  creditor's  ownership,  c.  g.,  personal 
clothing  or  the  rental  derived  from  a  personal  slave.  Weak 

1  Majma',  p.  169. 

*Minhdj,  p.  252. 

8  'Alainkiriyyah,  p.  251,  1.  — 9. 

4  Majma',  p.  169. 

ra/fna',  p.  159;  Mabstit,  p.  194;  Jdnii',  p.  301. 


278  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

claims,  finally,  are  those  that  arise  in  consideration  of  other 
than  wealth  (mat),  such  as  the  price  of  marriage  or  divorce, 
or  arise  for  no  consideration  at  all,  such  as  inheritance  and 
bequests. 

In  strong  claims,  the  zakat  is  due  at  the  end  of  the  year, 
whether  or  not  collected,  but  its  payment  is  made  only  after 
every  collection  of  a  minimum  of  40  dirhams  or  more  at 
the  rate  of  i  dirham  for  every  40  dirhams  collected. 

In  medium  claims,  in  one  report  from  Abu  Hanifah,  the 
zakat  is  still  due  at  the  end  of  the  year  but  its  payment  be- 
comes obligatory  only  after  a  nisab  of  200  dirhams  has  been 
collected,  at  the  regular  rate  of  5  for  200  dirhams.  In  an- 
other report  from  him,  there  is  no  zakat  on  such  claims 
until  they  have  been  collected  and  a  year  has  passed. 

In  weak  claims  the  zakat  is  not  due  until  a  nisab  of  200 
has  been  collected  and  a  year  has  elapsed. 

According  to  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan, 
however,  all  claims  are  alike  excepting  those  consisting  of 
the  price  of  manumission  (badal  kitabah)  and  the  price  of 
blood  (al-diyat  fala  }l-aqilah).  If  they  are  of  nisab  quan- 
tity and  the  year  has  elapsed  the  zakat  becomes  due  on  them, 
but  it  is  not  paid  before  collection.  When,  however,  part  of 
it  is  collected,  no  matter  how  little,  its  zakat  is  paid.  As  re- 
gards the  two  claims  which  formed  an  exception  to  the 
rule,  their  zakat  is  due  only  after  a  nisab  has  been  collected 
and  a  year  has  elapsed.  This  difference  of  opinion  between 
the  disciples  and  Abu  Hanifah  arises  from  their  different 
method  of  classifying  claims.  The  disciples  classify  the 
claims  into  absolute  (mutlaq)  and  defective  (naqis),  and 
consider  as  absolute  all  but  the  two  claims  mentioned. 

The  above  controversy  applies  only  in  case  the  creditor 
does  not  have  in  his  possession  other  wealth  (mal)  when 
he  collects  the  claim,  for  in  that  case,  by  unanimous  opinion, 
he  adds  the  claims  collected  to  the  wealth  he  already  pos- 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  279 

sesses  and  pays  their  zakat  together  with  that  of  the  wealth 
in  question. 

According  to  al-Shafi'i  all  claims  are  alike  subject 
to  zakat  which  must  be  paid  when  the  year  has  elapsed, 
even  if  the  claims  have  not  been  as  yet  collected.  His 
argument  is  that  the  creditor's  property  became  a  claim  by 
his  will  and  through  an  act  of  his  and  therefore  there  is 
no  reason  for  delaying  the  right  of  the  poor,  by  requiring 
another  year  to  elapse  after  their  collection.  The  Hanifite 
reply  is  that  the  claims  before  collection  are  not  as  yet  in 
the  zakat  payer's  possession,  and  therefore  he  is  not  ob- 
liged to  pay  their  zakat  until  after  he  has  collected  them, 
just  as  the  wayfarer  is  not  required  to  discharge  the  zakat 
of  property  he  left  at  home,  except  as  he  gradually  receives 
it.  According  to  the  Minhaj,1  the  view  above  ascribed  to 
al-Shafi'i  is  his  more  recent  view,  and  applies  only  to  claims 
of  gold  and  silver  and  commodities  (fard),  but  not  to  claims 
of  animals,  nor  to  debts  which  may  be  repudiated  (gayr 
ICizim),  such  as  the  price  of  manumission.  The  zakat  of 
the  claims  in  question  is  paid  when  due  before  their  col- 
lection, provided  the  claims  are  already  due  and  their  col- 
lection is  possible,  for  if  their  collection  is  not  possible  by 
reason  of  the  debtor's  being  in  poverty  or  otherwise, 
they  are  like  usurped  property,  namely,  their  zakat  is  paid 
after  their  collection.  If  the  debts  have  not  yet  fallen  due 
(mu'ajjal),  the  prevalent  Shafiite  view  is  that  they  are  like 
usurped  property,  but  some  hold  that  their  zakat  is  paid  as 
soon  as  it  falls  due,  even  though  before  their  collection. 

Finally,  according  to  Malik  and  his  followers,2  there  are 
three  classes  of  claims:  (i)  Those  accruing  in  considera- 
tion of  property  which  is  not  trade  property,  such  as  prop- 

1  P.  261. 

*  Mudawwanah,  pp.  16,  18,  27-8;  Dardir,  pp.  121-3;  Kharashi,  pp.  93-9, 
IOT  ;  Tbn  Rushd,  B.,  p.  249. 


280  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

erty  bought  for  personal  use,  or  inherited  or  received  as 
gift,  or  such  as  the  price  of  manumission  or  blood.  These 
claims  are  not  subject  to  zakat,  since  the  original  property 
in  consideration  of  which  they  have  accrued  is  not  subject 
to  zakat.  But  if  a  nisab  of  these  claims  is  collected  and  re- 
mains in  the  possession  of  the  creditor  for  a  year,  it  pays 
zakat  as  any  other  property  would,  provided  the  claim  col- 
lected consists  of  gold  or  silver.  (2)  The  claims  accruing 
in  consideration  of  trade  property  or  in  consequence  of 
loans  of  gold  or  silver.  These  claims  are  subject  to  zakat 
for  one  year  only,  even  if  in  the  interim  before  their  col- 
lection, from  the  time  their  zakat  was  last  paid  on  the  origi- 
nal property,  or  from  the  time  such  property  was  acquired 
by  the  creditor,  there  elapsed  several  years.  But  this  zakat 
is  not  discharged  until  after  a  nisab  of  the  claim  has  been 
collected.  When  once  a  nisab  has  been  collected  and  its 
corresponding  zakat  paid,  the  zakat  of  later  collections,  no 
matter  how  little  they  are,  is  paid  as  they  are  collected, 
even  if  meanwhile  the  nisab  first  collected  should  have  been 
disposed  of  or  lost.  For  instance,  a  person  who  loaned  40 
dinars  after  possessing  them  for  6  months  pays  no  zakat 
on  the  20  dinars  which  he  recovers  after  5  months,  until 
after  he  has  possessed  them  for  another  month  to  complete 
the  year.  If  he  should  recover  them  after  5  years,  he  at 
once  pays  the  zakat  of  the  20  dinars.  If,  on  the  contrary, 
he. should  recover  after  5  years,  first  5,  then  5,  which  he 
spends  and  then  10,  he  pays  immediately  zakat  for  the  20 
for  one  year  only,  and  if  later  he  should  recover  another 
dinar,  he  at  once  pays  its  zakat,  even  if  meanwhile  the  20 
dinars  should  have  been  spent.  In  the  same  case,  if  instead 
of  loaning  the  entire  40  dinars  he  had  only  loaned  20,  and 
meanwhile  paid  zakat  on  the  remaining  20,  he  would  then 
have  to  pay  zakat  for  any  collection  he  made,  even  if  it  be 
one  dinar,  and  even  if  the  20  dinars  he  had  kept  were  mean- 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  28l 

while  destroyed.  The  same  would  be  true  if  he  had  loaned 
the  entire  40  dinars,  but  had  meanwhile  acquired  20  dinars 
which  he  had  in  his  possession  for  one  year  and  had  paid 
zakat  on  them.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  he  had  acquired  only 
10  instead  of  20  dinars,  he  would  not  pay  zakat  on  his  collec- 
tions until  after  he  had  collected  10  dinars  from  his  claim, 
and  paid  zakat  on  the  20.  In  other  words,  the  principle 
here  is  that  before  he  begins  to  pay  zakat  on  his  collections, 
he  must  have  had  in  his  ownership  at  least  20  dinars,  for 
an  entire  year,  whether  all  of  these  20  dinars  have  been  c  1- 
lected  from  the  claim  or  whether  they  have  come  into  his 
possession  otherwise.  It  must  be  stated  that  the  above 
applies  only  if  the  receipts  were  in  gold  or  silver.  (3)  The 
claims  of  the  second  class,  excepting  those  arising  from 
loans  of  gold  and  silver,  when  they  have  accrued  to  mer- 
chants, such  as  the  storekeepers  (mudlr),  who  buy  and 
sell  their  stock  without  waiting  for  a  rise  in  price  in  order 
to  speculate.  Such  persons  pay  the  zakat  of  their  claims 
yearly  together  with  the  zakat  of  their  stock  in  trade,  irre- 
spective of  whether  or  not  they  have  collected  them,  pro- 
vided, however,  that  these  claims  are  already  due  and  their 
collection  is  possible.  If  the  claims  are  not  yet  due,  or  if 
they  are  due  but  consist  of  commodities,  their  zakat  is  paid 
on  the  basis  of  their  market  value. 

If  the  creditor  delays  the  collection  of  his  claims  in  order 
to  avoid  the  payment  of  zakat  he  pays  zakat  for  every  year 
which  elapsed  before  its  collection,  unless  the  claim  arose  in 
consideration  of  no  property  or  property  that  is  not  con- 
sidered wealth  (mat),  such  as  the  price  of  manumission. 

According  to  the  Durr,1  if  the  creditor,  after  the  lapse  of 
a  year,  waives  his  claim  he  does  not  pay  zakat  for  it, 
whether  it  was  strong  or  weak. 

1  P.  139. 


282  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Rentals  and  Wages  (ujrah).  There  are  three  reports 
from  Abu  Hanifah  concerning  the  zakat  of  rentals  and 
wages.  According  to  one  report,  he  likened  them  to  the 
marriage  price,  in  that  both  are  not  the  price  of  wealth 
itself,  but  of  its  use.  In  a  second  report,  he  likened  them 
to  the  price  of  every-day  clothing,  in  that,  like  it,  they  are 
not  subject  to  zakat.  In  a  third  report,  the  most  reliable  of 
all,  the  rental  of  a  business  office  or  the  wages  of  a  trade 
slave  have  been  likened  to  the  prices  of  the  same.  Conse- 
quently, according  to  this  report,  whenever  40  dirhams  are 
collected  on  account  of  the  rental  or  the  wages,  their  cor- 
responding zakat  is  paid,  just  as  in  the  case  of  the  price  of 
trade  articles.  In  other  words,  Abu  Hanifah  considered 
the  price  for  the  use  of  a  thing  similar  to  the  price  for  the 
thing  itself.1  If,  however,  the  rental  is  derived  from  a 
house  which  is  not  intended  for  trade,  and  the  wages  from 
a  slave  who  is  not  intended  for  trade,  then  no  zakat  is  paid 
on  them  until  a  year  has  passed  after  their  collection. 

According  to  the  Shafiites,2  the  zakat  is  paid  on  such  part 
of  the  rental  collected  as  has  already  accrued.  For  instance, 
if  a  person  should  rent  a  house  for  two  years  for  40  dinars 
and  receive  them,  he  pays  zakat  at  the  end  of  the  first  year 
for  the  20  dinars  only,  because  the  other  20  dinars  have  not 
accrued  to  him  yet  and  might  be  reclaimed  by  the  tenant  if, 
for  example,  the  house  should  be  destroyed  at  the  end  of 
the  first  year.3 

SECTION  IV 

The  Zakat  of  the  Produce  of  the  Earth  or  the  Tithe  4 

1  Mabsiit,  p.  196;  Path,  p.  123. 

1  Minhdj,  p.  263 ;  Ansari,  p.  357. 

3  For  the  Malikite  view  on  the  matter,  see  supra,  pp.  223-5. 

*  Majma',  p.  175;  Path,  p.  186;  Jdmi',  p.  325;  Durr,  p.  142;  Durar,  p. 
122;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  260;  Umm,  p.  29;  Mawardi,  pp.  202-6;  Minhdj, 
p.  238;  Zarqani,  p.  67;  Mudawwanah,  p.  105;  Dardir,  p.  116. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  283 

The  Hanifite  doctors  treat  tithe  under  zakat l  because 
they  consider  tithe  as  the  zakat  of  the  produce  of  the  earth. 
Some  of  them  have  nevertheless  raised  the  question  as  to 
whether  tithe  is  really  a  kind  of  zakat.  A  few  maintain 
that  tithe  was  called  zakat  because,  in  the  opinion  of  Abu 
Yusuf  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  as  in  zakat  so  in  tithe 
also,  the  conditions  of  nisab  and  lapse  of  year  are  required.3 
The  author  of  the  Majma'  objects  to  this  construction 
and  claims  that  the  tithe  was  called  zakat  because  it  was 
disbursed  like  zakat.  The  author  of  the  'Inayah  says  that 
the  extension  of  the  name  cakCit  to  tithe  is  by  way  of  meta- 
ph<  T.8  The  author  of  the  Path,*  on  the  other  hand,  puts  a 
strong  plea  for  the  identity  of  zakat  and  tithe.  He  remarks 
that  tithe  is  zakat ;  so  much  so  that  it  is  disbursed  the  same 
way  as  zakat,  and  that  the  most  that  can  be  said  concerning 
the  controversy  over  the  nature  of  zakat  is  that  it  turns  on 
the  question  whether  or  not  certain  of  the  conditions  of 
zakat  apply  to  certain  kinds  of  zakat.  But  he  adds  that 
whatever  the  answer  to  that  question  may  be,  it  evidently 
does  not  prevent  tithe  from  being  a  kind  of  zakat.  The 
Hanifite  doctors  are  nevertheless  unanimous  in  saying  that 

1  Some  Hanifite  texts  treat  tithe  under  the  caption  of  Zakdt  of  the 
Produce  of  the  Earth  (sakdt  al-khdrij),  while  others  treat  it  under 
that  of  Zakdt  of  the  Crops  and  Fruits  (sakdt  al-suru  wa  'l-thimdr). 
Aside  from  cases  like  the  foregoing,  the  Hanifites,  even  those  who 
consider  tithe  as  identical  with  zakdt,  use  the  word  'ushr  (tithe)  in 
order  to  refer  to  the  tithe;  and,  on  the  other  hand,  when  they  use  the 
word  sakdt  they  mean  by  it  the  sakdt  of  animals,  gold  and  silver,  and 
articles  of  trade  only.  The  Shafiites  and  Matikites,  on  the  contrary, 
denote  by  sakdt  the  tithe,  as  well  as  the  other  kinds  of  sakdt;  and  so, 
when  they  want  to  distinguish  the  tithe  from  the  others  they  use  some 
such  expression  as  sakdt  of  crops  and  fruits,  or  sakdt  of  produce 
(harth). 

1  Majma',  p.  175. 

s  'Indyah,  p.  186;  Path  al-Mu'in,  p.  401. 

4  P.  186. 


284  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

there  is  a  difference  between  the  two,  namely,  that  while 
zakat, — that  is,  the  kinds  of  zakat  so  far  treated, — is  an  act 
of  worship  pure  and  simple,  tithe  is  primarily  a  financial 
charge  (ma'ilnah)  although  it  participates  in  a  way  in  the 
nature  of  worship ;  and  that  this  is  the  reason  why  tithe  was 
treated  last  of  all.  From  this  rather  important  difference 
follow  certain  minor  ones,  such  as,  that  unlike  zakat,  tithe 
is  levied  on  property  owned  by  minors,  insane  persons, 
waqfs,  etc.  In  many  respects,  however,  the  tithe  is  like  the 
sakat.  It  might  be  advanced  as  a  general  proposition  that 
unless  the  doctors  indicate  the  contrary,  the  presumption  is 
that  tithe  is  like  zakat,  especially  as  regards  its  religious 
aspects,  and  that  the  differences  between  the  two  are  practi- 
cally limited  to  the  political  and  financial  field,  such  as  the 
state's  right  of  collection.1  The  Shafiites  and  Malikites,  on 
the  contrary,  both  treat  and  consider  the  tithe  as  an  integral 
part  of,  and  identical  with,  the  zakat.  Consequently,  what 
they  say  on  "  zakat "  applies  equally  to  the  tithe  and  to 
the  other  kinds  of  zakat.2 

The  tithe  is  a  fard  by  reason  of  evidence  found  in  the 
Koran,  the  sunnah,  the  ijma' ,  and  reason,  (i)  In  the 
Koran :  there  are  the  verses :  "  and  on  the  day  of  its  har- 
vest give  its  right  (i.  e.,  the  right  that  attaches  to  it)  ",3 
and :  "Bestow  alms  from  the  choice  part  of  what  you  have 
earned  and  we  have  made  grow  for  you  from  the  ground." 
Although  some  claim  that  the  zakat  is  collected  after  the 
harvest  and  therefore  the  right  mentioned  in  the  verse  refers 

1  Path  al-Mu'in,  p.  401;  Bahr,  p.  255;  Kifdyah,  p.  172;  Kasani,  p.  37; 
cf.  also  Defteri  Muqtasid  (p.  54)  on  nature  of  "tithe"  paid  by  dhim- 
mis. 

2  Cf.  Mawardi,  pp.  204-5 ;  Minhdj,  p.  238 ;   Wajiz,  p.  go ;  Kharashi, 
p.  71. 

8  Koran,  chap.  6,  verse  142. 
4  Koran,  chap.  2,  verse  269. 


THE  Z4KAT  TAXES  285 

to  the  alms  given  to  the  poor  at  harvest,  the  majority  have 
agreed  '  that  it  refers  to  the  zakat.  The  ground  advanced 
by  those  who  hold  the  opposite  view  is  the  fact  that 
the  verse  in  question  was  revealed  in  Mecca  before  the 
zakat  was  yet  made  a  fard.  (2)  In  the  sunnah  :  there  is  the 
had'ith :  "  In  what  has  been  irrigated  by  Heaven,  one-tenth, 
and  in  what  has  been  watered  with  buckets  or  waterwheels, 
one-half  of  one-tenth."  (3)  In  the  ijma' :  the  entire  Mos- 
lem community  has  agreed  on  tithe's  being  a  fard.  (4) 
It  follows  from  reason:  as  in  the  case  of  zakat,  the 
giving  of  tithe  to  the  poor  is  an  act  of  gratitude  for  the 
blessing  of  property,  and,  furthermore,  it  enables  the  poor  to 
perform  their  religious  obligations  and  inculcates  in  the 
giver  habits  of  generosity  while  it  destroys  those  of  nig- 
gardliness.2 Al-SharVi 3  bases  the  tithe  on  the  practice  of 
the  Prophet,  who  took  sadaqah  from  wheat,  barley,  and 
maize  ( dhurah ) . 

The  cause  of  tithe  being  a  wdjib  is  the  actually  productive 
land — unlike  the  kharaj  whose  cause  is  the  absolutely  pro- 
ductive land,  whether  actually  or  only  potentially  so.  There- 
fore the  tithe  is  due  only  when  there  is  a  produce,  so  much 
so  that  when  the  produce  is  destroyed  by  an  act  of  God,  the 
tithe  lapses. 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah,  the  produce  of  the  earth  as 
well  as  the  fruits  of  wild  trees  are  subject  to  tithe,  no 
matter  what  their  quantity  is  and  irrespective  of  whether 
the  requirements  of  nisab,  durability,  and  lapse  of  a  year 
have  been  met.  Hence  green  vegetables  pay  tithe  though 
they  may  not  be  preserved  for  a  year.4  According  to  Abu 

1  Cf.  Baydawi :  Yahya,  pp.  88  et  seq. 

3  Kasani.  p.  53. 
s  Umm,  p.  29. 

4  Durr,  p.  142. 


286  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Yfisuf  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  however,  the  tithe  is 
levied  only  on  such  produce  of  the  earth  as  may  be  con- 
served for  at  least  a  year  without  much  care  and  manage- 
ment, and  amounts  to  at  least  a  nisab.  Therefore,  in  the 
opinion  of  the  disciples,  garlic,  onions,  apples,  plums,  green 
vegetables  and  other  produce  which  cannot  be  preserved 
for  a  year,  do  not  pay  tithe  at  all.  On  the  other  hand,  pro- 
duce that  may  be  preserved  for  a  year,  such  as  dates,  grapes, 
grains,  etc.,  pays  tithe  only  in  case  it  amounts  to  5  wasqs,1 
— if  it  is  the  kind  of  produce  measured  by  wasqs.  For 
if  it  is  the  kind  of  produce  that  is  not  measured  by  wasqs f 
such  as  cotton,  saffron  and  sugar,  it  pays  tithe,  according  to 
Abu  Yusuf,  if  its  value  amounts  to  the  value  of  5  wasqs 
of  the  least  valuable  produce  measured  by  wasqs,  e.  g., 
millet,  and  according  to  Muhammad,  if  its  quantity  amounts 
to  five  times  the  highest  unit  of  measure  by  which  produce 
of  its  kind  is  measured.  Thus  cotton  pays  tithe  when  it 
amounts  to  5  himls,  and  saffron  when  it  amounts  to  5  manns, 
the  himl  and  the  mann  being  the  highest  units  of  measure 
by  which  cotton  and  saffron  are  respectively  measured. 
The  ground  for  Abu  Yusuf 's  view  is  that  since  the  shari'ah 
specifications  in  regard  to  quantity  cannot  be  applied  here 
literally,  one  figures  out  on  the  basis  of  value,  as  was  done 
in  the  case  of  articles  of  trade,  and  the  value  of  the  least 
valuable  produce  is  taken  into  consideration  in  order  to 
benefit  the  poor.  The  ground  for  Muhammad's  view,  on 

1  The  wasq  (also  wisq)  is  a  measure  of  capacity,  about  a  camel's 
load,  holding  60  sd's,  of  the  kind  used  by  the  Prophet,  each  sa  being  4 
mudds.  The  mudd  being,  according  to  the  people  of  'Iraq  and  Abu 
Hanifah,  2,  and,  according  to  the  people  of  Hijaz  and  al-Shafi'i,  i^ 
rails  (or  ritls),  the  wasq  is  480  and  320  rails,  respectively.  Himl,  a 
measure  of  weight,  is  300  manns  (plural:  amndn).  The  mann  (also 
mana,  plural:  amna)  is  2  rails  (rail  also  being  a  measure  of  weight), 
the  rail  12  uqiyyahs  (plural:  awdqi},  or  20  istdrs,  or  128  dirhams  (sep- 
timal  weight).  The  uqiyyah  used  in  hadiths  is  40  dirhams.  (Cf.  Ma- 
wardi,  p.  203;  Minhdj.  p.  238;  Kharashi,  p.  71). 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  287 

the  other  hand,  is  that  the  wasq  was  considered  a  basis  for 
produce  measured  by  wasq,  because  the  zvasq  was  the  high- 
est unit  of  measure  in  that  produce,  and  therefore  the  spirit 
of  the  law  requires  that  for  produce  that  is  not  measured 
by  wasqs  the  highest  unit  of  measure  applicable  to  it  be 
considered. 

There  is  no  tithe  on  firewood,  Persian  cane  and  dry 
herbage  (hashish),  because  ordinarily  they  are  not  grown 
as  a  means  of  deriving  profit  from  the  ground.  They 
would  therefore  be  subject  to  tithe  if  the  land  were  specially 
used  for  growing  them.  Sweet  rush  and  sugar  cane  are, 
however,  subject  to  tithe.  Palmboughs  and  straw,  grains 
that  are  not  sown  for  their  own  sake,  such  as  the  seeds  of 
cucumbers  and  melons,  and  secretions  from  trees,  such  as 
resin  and  tar,  are  likewise  exempt  from  tithe.  Olives  and 
safflower  and  their  seeds  however  pay  tithe. 

Of  fruits,  according  to  the  Shafiites,1  only  dates  and 
grapes,  and  of  crops,  only  those  grown  by  men  and  stored 
away  as  food  pay  tithe,  provided  they  amount  to  at  least 
5  wasqs,  excepting  rice,  etc.,  where  the  nisab  is  10  wasqs 
in  order  to  allow  for  the  husk.  The  crops  which  pay  tithe 
are  wheat  (hintah),  barley  (sha'tr),  rice,  lentils  ('ados), 
millet  (dukhn),  beans  (baqila  or  lubiya'),  peas  (himmas), 
maize  (dhurah),  and  their  varieties,  and  according  to  the 
older  view  of  al-Shafi'i,  also  olives,  saffron,  honey,  etc. 
According  to  the  Malikites,2  the  tithe  is  levied  only  on  dates 
and  grapes,  the  grains  (habb),  and  the  oil-bearers  (dhawal 
al-suyut),  provided  they  amount  to  at  least  5  wasqs,  no  al- 
lowance being  made  for  the  husk  (qishr).  The  grains  in- 
clude 14  kinds,  the  7  so-called  sheath-bearers  (qatani), 

1  Minhdj,  p.  238;  Wajis,  p.  90;  Mawardi,  pp.  202,  204;  Mugni,  p.  372; 
Ansari,  p.  367;  Umm,  p.  29. 
'Kharashi,  p.  71;  Dardlr,  p.  116. 


MOHAMMEDAN-  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

such  as  beans,  peas,  and  lentils,  as  well  as  wheat  (qamh), 
barley,  rice,  millet,  maize,  and  their  varieties.  The  oil- 
bearers  include  olives,  sesame,  etc. 

According  to  the  Shafiites  and  the  Malikites,1  following 
the  Prophet's  precedent,  dates  and  grapes  are  appraised  by 
the  state  as  soon  as  they  become  ripe  and  proper  for  eating ; 
and  the  owners  are  required  to  pay  their  tithe  later  in  dry 
dates  (tamr)  and  raisins  (zabib}.  The  Hanifites  and  others 
opposed  this  practice  on  the  ground  that  it  is  a  curtailment 
of  the  owner's  rights  and  because  the  precedent  of  the 
Prophet  concerned  the  dates  of  the  people  of  Khaybar 
wrho  were  Hebrews  and  could  not  therefore  apply  to  the 
zakat  of  Moslems,  the  only  hadlth  that  might  support  such 
a  construction  being  open  to  impeachment.  Moreover,  ap- 
praisal is  in  reality  an  exchange  of  fresh  dates  which  are 
yet  on  the  trees  against  dry  dates  to  be  delivered  in  the 
future  and  involves  a  difference  of  quantity  (tafadul)  as 
well  as  a  term  sale  (nastfoh),  both  of  which  are  forbidden 
as  usurious  (riba).2  Al-Shafi'i  justifies  this  practice  on  the 

1  Umm,  p.  27 ;  Minhdj,  p.  241 ;  Wajiz,  p.  92 ;  Mawardi,  p.  203 ;  Khara- 
shi,  p.  78;  Ibn  Rushd,  B.,  p.  244;  Dardir,  p.  117;  Muwatta,  p.  117. 

2  Riba    (surplus)    is  technically  defined  as  the  excess  stipulated  in 
favor  of  only  one  of  the  two  parties  to  an  exchange  of  wealth  (mdl) 
for  wealth  without  a  consideration  ('iwad).    This  excess  may  consist 
in  the  granting  of  a  term  for  delivery  (nasl'ah)   or,  in  the  exchange 
of  homogeneous  goods  only,  in  an  excess  of  volume  (kayl}  or  weight 
(wasn).    Thus  exchange  of  gold  for  gold  or  silver  to  be  delivered  in 
the  future,  and  exchange  of  gold  for  gold,  or  of  silver  for  silver  in 
unequal  quantities  are  usurious  acts.    Usury  is  forbidden  in  the  sunnah 
with  regard  to  6  definite  articles,  which  are  interpreted  variously.    The 
Hanifites  interpret  them   as  the  articles  sold  by  volume    (makil)    or 
weight  (mawsun}.    The  Shafiites  take  them  to  mean  gold  and  silver 
and  foodstuffs   (mat'umdf).     Finally,  according  to  the   Malikites,  in- 
equality in  quantity  is  forbidden  with  respect  to  gold  and  silver  and 
sustaining  foodstuffs    (muqtdt)    that  are  stored  away  for  future  use 
(mudakhkhar),  and  future  delivery,  with  respect  to  gold  and  silver  and 
foodstuffs.     (Tech.  Diet.,  p.  593;  Qudiiri,  p.  45;  Path  al-Qarib,  p.  314; 
Tbn  Rushd,  B.,  vol.  ii,  p.  106;  Dardir,  vol.  ii,  p.  14.) 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  289 

ground  that  it  inures  to  the  interests  of  both  sides,  since  by 
it  the  owners  are  allowed  to  eat  their  fruits  when  they  are 
fresh  yet  or  to  sell  them  and  fetch  higher  prices,  and,  on  the 
other  hand,  the  beneficiaries  are  secured  a  tithe  on  the  entire 
produce.  According  to  al-Mawardi,  the  owner  after  the 
appraisal  may  assume  responsibility  for  the  tithe  on 
the  basis  of  the  appraisal  and  be  free  to  dispose  of 
his  fruits  as  he  pleases  or  he  may  refrain  from  doing  so 
and  in  that  case  the  produce  is  a  sort  of  trust  which  he  may 
not  touch  until  he  has  paid  its  tithe.  According  to  the 
prevalent  Shafiite  view  the  owner  is  not  responsible  for  the 
tithe  on  the  basis  of  the  appraisal,  unless  he  has  expressly 
assumed  this  responsibility,  but  certain  Shafiites  expressed 
the  view  that  it  is  not  necessary  expressly  to  stipulate  this 
and  that  by  the  very  fact  of  appraisal  the  owner  becomes 
responsible  for  the  tithe.  The  Malikite  view  seems  to  agree 
with  the  latter  view.  No  allowance  is  made  in  the  appraisal 
for  the  fruits  that  may  be  eaten  by  the  owner  or  by  birds 
and  animals  and  a  single  appraiser  is  sufficient. 

For  produce  which  was  irrigated  by  rain  or  running 
water,  and  for  wild  fruits,  the  rate  of  tithe  is  one-tenth  of 
the  produce.  On  the  contrary,  for  crops  watered  by  water- 
buckets  or  waterwheels,  the  rate  is  one-half  of  one-tenth.1 
In  either  case  the  rate  applies  before  deduction  of  the  ex- 
penses of  production,  for  the  hadith  on  which  the  rate  of 
tithe  is  based  does  not  allow  for  any  such  deduction. 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah,  the  amount  eaten  from  the 
produce  before  the  deduction  of  the  tithe  is  also  taxed,  but 
according  to  another  report  from  him,  no  tithe  is  received 
for  the  amount  consumed  by  the  owner  if  the  amount  was 
reasonable.  According  to  Abu  Yusuf  the  amount  necessary 
for  one's  own  and  one's  family's  food  is  exempt  from 

1  Cf.  Minhdj.  p.  240;  Kharashi,  p.  71. 


290  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

tithe,  but,  according  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  nine- 
tenths  of  what  he  consumed  is  taxed.  Finally,  according 
to  al-Timirtashi,  one  is  not  allowed  to  consume  anything 
at  all  before  paying  his  tithe,  but  others  say  that  this  ap- 
plies only  when  he  is  determined  not  to  pay  his  tithe,  for 
if  he  sincerely  intends  to  pay  his  tithe,  he  may  consume 
nine-tenths  of  the  crop,  although  it  is  preferable  that  he 
should  not.1 

It  is  not  necessary  that  the  produce  should  have  been 
attended  to  in  order  that  it  may  be  subject  to  tithe,  there- 
fore the  tithe  is  due  on  the  produce  of  land  that  is  not 
owned  by  any  one,  and  also  on  fruits  that  have  grown  in 
the  wilderness  without  any  one's  having  cared  for  them. 
However,  according  to  Abu  Yusuf  and  al-Hasan,  no  tithe 
is  due  on  them,  because  they  constitute  free  goods  and  be- 
come the  property  of  the  first  comer.  Al-Timirtashi  says 
that  such  produce  and  fruits  pay  tithe  if  they  have  enjoyed 
the  protection  of  the  imam.2 

The  tithe  is  due  on  the  produce  of  waqf  lands  as  well  as 
on  the  lands  of  the  minors,  the  insane,  the  mukatabs,  the 
slaves  who  have  permission  to  trade  (ma'dhun),  and  the 
persons  who  are  indebted;  but  according  to  al-Shafi'i,  the 
land  of  the  mukatab  and  waqf  lands  whose  beneficiaries  are 
not  definite  persons  are  exempt  from  zakat.  His  reason  for 
this  is  that  tithe  is  a  kind  of  zakat  and  is  levied  with  respect 
to  the  owner  of  the  property.  The  Hanifite  argument  is 
that  like  kharaj  (land-tax)  tithe  is  a  charge  on  the  produc- 
tive land  and  that  therefore  it  strikes  the  produce,  no  matter 
who  the  owner  is.3 

Honey,  like  the  produce  of  the  earth,  is  subject  to  tithe, 

1  Jdmi',  p.  325. 

*  Jdmi't  ibid.;  Majma",  p.  176;  Durr,  p.  142. 

zMabsut,  part  iii,  p.  4;  cj.  Ansari,  p.  349. 


THE  ZAKAT  T. 


291 


according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  no  matter  how  small  or  how 
large  its  quantity.  There  are  many  had'iths  from  the 
Companions  to  show  that  the  Prophet,  and  later  the  califs, 
levied  the  tithe  on  honey.  There  is  also  a  hadith  from  the 
Prophet,  reading.  "In  honey  one-tenth  ".  Al-Shafi'i,  in  his 
more  recent  view,  and  Malik  exempted  honey  from  tithe 
the  analogy  of  silk.  The  Hanifite  reply  is  that  silk- 
worms eat  leaves  which  are  not  subject  to  tithe,  unlike  the 
bees  which  collect  the  honey  from  flowers  and  fruits  on 
which  there  is  a  tithe.  However,  the  author  of  the  Majma' 
remarks  that  flowers  are  not  subject  to  tithe. 

Aco-rding  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  honey  pays  tithe 
.  -nly  when  it  amounts  at  least  to  5  faraqs,  because  the  faraq 
is  the  highest  unit  of  measure  used  for  measuring  honey. 
On  the  other  hand,  in  Abu  Yusuf's  opinion  honey  pays 
tithe  when  it  amounts  to  10  qirbahs,  because  of  a  hadith  to 
that  effect.1 

Crops  and  fruits  as  well  as  honey  are  subject  to  tithe  only 
if  they  have  grown  or  have  been  collected  on  tithe  land  or 
tithe  mountain,  or,  as  the  Durr  observes  with  respect  to 
honey  and  wild  fruits,  even  on  land  that  is  not  tithe  land, 
provided  it  is  not  also  kharaj  land,  such  as  mountains  and 
deserts,  but  in  no  case  may  the  land  be  kharaj  land. 
Honey  collected  in  kharaj  lands  pays  neither  tithe  nor 
kharaj,2  because  the  produce  of  kharaj  lands  is  subject  to 
kharaj,  and  were  the  tithe  also  levied,  it  would  be  subject 
to  two  taxes  at  the  same  time.3 

According  to  al-Shafi'i,  the  tithe  is  due  even  on  produce 
grown  en  kharaj  land,  because  in  his  view  there  is  no  in- 
convenience in  the  collection  of  two  taxes  from  the  same 

1  A  faraq    (plural,  afrdq)    is  36  rails    (cf.  al-Mugrib").     A   qirbah 
(water-skin)  is  50  manns. 
*'Indyah,  p.  191. 
8  Kasani.  p.  57 ;  Majma1,  p.  1/7. 


292  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

object  at  the  same  time.  His  ground  for  this  view  is  that 
kharaj  and  tithe  are  different  charges  as  regards  nature, 
cause,  and  object,  and  therefore  there  is  no  incompatibility 
between  them.  Indeed  the  difference  of  their  natures  needs 
no  special  mention  and  as  regards  their  cause,  the  cause  of 
tithe  is  the  produce  and  that  of  kharaj,  the  productive  land, 
and  finally,  the  object  of  tithe  is  the  produce  and  that  of  the 
kharaj,  the  legal  personality  (dhimmah)  of  the  owner.  The 
Hanifite  reply  is  that  the  Prophet  said :  "  The  tithe  and 
the  kharaj  are  not  combined  on  the  land  of  the  Moslem  " 
and  that  none  of  the  Moslem  imams,  whether  just  or  tyran- 
nical, ever  levied  other  than  the  kharaj  on  the  lands  of 
Sawad.  Moreover,  the  cause  of  the  tax  in  both  cases  is  the 
same,  namely,  the  productivity  of  the  land;  and  just  as  the 
zakat  of  sawaim  and  trade  may  not  be  levied  on  the  same 
object  so  the  kharaj  and  tithe  may  not  be  levied  on  the 
same  piece  of  land.1  Malik's  view  of  the  matter  is  like  that 
of  al-Shafi'i.2 

There  is  no  tax  on  the  habitations  (dar)  and  the  ceme- 
teries even  if  they  should  belong  to  the  dhimmis,  because 
the  calif  Omar  exempted  them  from  taxation.  If,  however, 
a  person,  whether  a  Moslem  or  a  dhimmi,  transforms  his 
habitation  into  a  garden,  he  pays  kharaj  in  every  case  if  he 
is  a  dhimmi,  and  if  he  is  a  Moslem,  he  pays  tithe  if  he 
waters  his  garden  with  tithe  water,  and  kharaj  if  he  waters 
with  kharaj  water. 

There  is  no  tithe  on  springs  of  tar  and  naphtha,  and  on 
salt  found  in  tithe  land,  nor  is  there  a  kharaj  on  them 
when  they  are  found  in  kharaj  lands,  since  they  may  not 
properly  be  called  the  produce  of  land.  Some  hold  that 
springs  legally  are  the  dependency  (tabaf)  of  their  imme- 

1  Kasani,  ibid. 

1  Mudawwanah,  p.  105 ;  cf.  Kharashi,  p.  71. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  293 

diate  vicinity  (harim)  as  regards  payment  of  kharaj.  The 
immediate  vicinity  of  springs,  if  the  land  is  one  of  tithe 
and  produce  is  actually  grown  on  it,  pays  tithe,  and  if  it  is 
kharaj  land,  and  fit  for  cultivation,  pays  kharaj,  whether  or 
not  it  is  actually  cultivated,  since  the  cause  of  kharaj  is 
potential  rather  than  actual  productivity. 

As  in  the  case  of  zakat,  the  obligation  of  tithe  lapses 
when  the  produce  is  destroyed  accidentally.  When  part  of 
the  produce  is  destroyed,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  the 
rest  pays  tithe  proportionately.  According  to  his  two  dis- 
ciples, if  the  part  destroyed  together  with  the  remaining 
part  amounts  to  a  nisab,  the  tithe  is  collected,  otherwise  it 
is  not.  According  to  a  report  from  Abu  Yusuf,  the  re- 
maining part  by  itself  must  amount  to  a  nisab ,  otherwise  it 
does  not  pay  tithe.  If  a  part  or  the  whole  of  the  produce 
has  been  destroyed  by  the  owner  wilfully,  then  he  pays  its 
tithe.  In  this  matter  the  Shafiites  *  and  the  Malikites  make 
no  distinction  between  the  tithe  and  the  zakat  in  general. 
Apostasy,  as  in  zakat,  is  another  cause  for  the  lapse  of  the 
tithe  obligation  although  al-ShafVi  held  the  opposite.  Con- 
trary to  al-ShafVi,  death  of  the  owner,  according  to  the 
Hanifites,  is  a  third  cause  for  the  lapse  of  the  tithe,  unless 
the  deceased  had  willed  its  payment,  provided,  however,  that 
the  produce  was  destroyed  by  him  already.  For  if  the 
produce  is  still  in  existence,  as  mentioned  before,  the  tithe 
is  collected  from  it  according  to  the  Zahir-al-riwayah  re- 
port.2 The  ground  for  this  view  is  the  fact  that  the  produce 
is  owned  jointly  by  the  poor  and  the  heirs  and  that  the 
death  of  the  owner  is  no  reason  for  the  lapse  of  the  tithe. 
There  is,  however,  a  report  from  Abu  Hanifah  through  Ibn 
al-Mubarak  to  the  contrary.8 

1  Minhdj.  p.  268.  'Kasani,  p.  65. 

*  Mabsut,  part  Hi,  p.  50. 


294  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

If  a  person  rents  a  tithe  land  and  cultivates  it,  according 
to  Abu  Hanifah,  the  tithe  is  upon  the  landowner,  whether  it 
be  more  or  less  than  the  rental.  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muham- 
mad Ibn  al-Hasan,  on  the  contrary,  hold  that  the  tithe  is 
paid  out  of  the  produce  by  the  tenant.  Their  argument  is 
that  tithe  is  a  charge  on  the  produce  and  the  produce  in  this 
instance  belongs  to  the  tenant,  the  person  who  rented  a 
land  without  a  consideration  (musta'ir}  being  in  this  re- 
spect like  the  tenant.  Abu  Hanifah  replies  that  the  tax  is  a 
charge  for  the  use  of  the  land,  and  the  use  here  belongs  to 
the  landowner,  since  he  is  entitled  to  the  rental,  which  is  the 
price  of  the  use  of  the  land.  In  other  words,  the  tenant 
enjoys  the  use  of  the  land  in  consideration  of  the  rental  he 
has  paid,  and  so  he  is  not  subject  to  tithe  any  more  than  the 
purchaser  of  the  produce  is.  Moreover,  tithe  is  a  charge 
on  productive  land,  and  the  land  here  does  not  belong 
to  the  tenant.  It  is  however  a  different  case  if  the  land 
was  leased  to  a  Moslem  for  no  consideration,  because  the 
tenant  in  that  case  enjoys  the  use  of  the  land  for  no  con- 
sideration whatsoever,  and  because  the  tithe,  being  due  only 
when  there  is  a  real  benefit  (manfafah),  is  not  to  be  paid 
when  there  is  no  produce.  If,  however,  the  land  was 
leased  without  a  rental  to  a  dhimmi,  the  tithe  is  paid 
by  the  landowner,  because  tithe  is  a  kind  of  sadaqah  and 
may  not  be  paid  by  an  unbeliever,  and  because  the  land- 
owner by  renting  his  land  to  a  dhimmi  has  destroyed  the 
right  of  the  poor  and  must  be  responsible  (damin)  for  it. 
Zufar,  following  the  analogy  of  kharaj  lands,  said  that  the 
tithe  is  always  paid  by  the  landowner  even  when  the  use  of 
the  land  is  allowed  without  a  rental  to  a  Moslem.1 

The  members  of  the  Taglib  tribe,  men,  women  and 
children,  pay  a  double  rate,  i.  e.,  two-tenths  for  the  tithe 

1  Mabsiit,  part  iii,  p.  5 ;  cf.  Mawardi.  p.  206. 


THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


295 


lands  they  own,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah  and  Abu  Yusuf , 
but  in  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan's  opinion,  only  one-tenth 
is  collected  from  them  if  the  lands  were  bought  from  Mos- 
lems, because,  in  his  view,  the  tithe  is  a  charge  on  the  land 
and  its  amount  does  not  change  with  the  owner.1 

lMajmo',  p.  177. 


CHAPTER  III 
COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT 

SECTION    I 

The  Collectors 

IN  the  earliest  period  of  Islam,  according  to  the  Hanifite 
doctors,  there  was  no  distinction  between  the  different  kinds 
of  property  as  regards  the  jurisdiction  of  the  state  tax  col- 
lector to  demand  the  settlement  of  their  zakat.  This  state  of 
affairs  is  said  to  have  continued  from  the  time  of  the 
Prophet  until  the  califship  of  'Uthman  who  "  delegated  the 
matter  of  payment  (ada)  to  the  property  owners  because 
he  feared  that  they  would  be  subjected  to  inconvenience 
and  trouble  in  the  inspection  of  their  property  by  evil  col- 
lectors." Since  then  property  subject  to  zakat  has  been  dis- 
tinguished into  the  two  classes  of  apparent  (amwal  zahirah) 
and  non-apparent  property  (amwal  batinah).  Apparent 
property  consists  of  the  animals  *  and  of  such  "  non-appar- 
ent "  property  as  has  become  "  apparent ".  Non-apparent 
property,  on  the  other  hand,  consists  of  the  remaining 
classes  of  property  subject  to  zakat,  namely  gold  and  silver 
and  the  articles  of  trade,  so  long  as  they  have  not  become 

1  Although  later  doctors  (cf.  'Indyah,  p.  171;  Majma',  p.  172,  etc.} 
in  this  connection  use  the  word  sawaim,  implying  thereby  that  animals 
other  than  sawd'im,  for  instance,  animals  kept  for  trade,  are  not  ap- 
parent property,  al-Sarakhsi  (Mabsut,  p.  170)  expressly  states  that  such 
animals  -are  apparent  property.  Al-Kasani  (p.  35),  by  using  in  this 
connection  the  word  mawdshi  (animals),  seems  to  hold  the  same  view; 
on  the  Shafiite  side,  al-Mawardi  (p.  195)  and  the  Mugni  (p.  401)  do- 
likewise  use  nawdshi,  and  na'm  (animals)  respectively. 
296 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     297 

"  apparent ".  It  will  be  noticed  that  no  mention  is  made 
here  of  the  tithe.  This  is  because,  as  already  explained  in 
the  section  on  Tithe,  the  Hanifites  *  consider  tithe  more 
or  less  different  from  zakat  proper,  using  zakat  to  denote 
in  particular  the  zakat  of  animals,  gold  and  silver,  and  ar- 
ticles of  trade.  The  Hanifites  do  nevertheless  assimilate 
tithe,  so  far  as  the  owner's  right  to  disburse  it  himself  and 
the  state's  right  to  collect  it  are  concerned,  with  the  zakat 
of  apparent  property.2  Thus  the  Kifayah  quoting  from  the 
Tafariq  says  that  the  owner  may  himself  disburse  his  tithe 
and  the  zakat  of  his  apparent  property  to  the  poor,  as  be- 
tween him  and  God,  although  the  imam  in  both  cases  col- 
lects the  tax  from  him  again.  There  is,  however,  a  differ- 
ence between  the  two,  namely,  that  while  the  imam  may  not 
collect  the  zakat  by  force,  he  may  do  so  with  the  tithe.  In 
such  case  the  tithe  obligation  is  discharged  both  as  towards 
God  and  the  state  but  the  owner  earns  no  religious  merit  for 
having  failed  to  pay  his  tithe  of  his  own  free-will.  In  the 
case  of  zakat,  however,  the  imam  has  no  right  to  collect  by 
force,  for  should  he  do  so,  the  zakat  obligation  of  the  owner 
remains  nevertheless  undischarged. 

According  to  the  Shafiites,3  apparent  property  consists  of 
animals  (na'm),  crops  and  fruits  (mu'ash-sharat),  and 
mines;  non-apparent  property,  on  the  other  hand,  consists 
of  gold  and  silver  (naqd&n),  articles  of  trade,  and  treasure- 
trove.4 

1  Bahr,  p.  255;  Kasani,  p.  371  Path  al-Mu'in,  p.  401.  The  last  work, 
however,  in  another  passage  (p.  373)  quotes  Nuh  Efendi  to  the  conr 
trary,  namely  that  crops  and  fruits  are  apparent  property. 

1  Kifdyah,  p.  172;  Kasani,  p.  37. 

8  Mugni,  p.  401 ;  Mawardi,  p.  195. 

4  The  discrepancy  between  the  two  schools  is  due  to  their  different 
interpretations  of  the  meaning  of  zakdt  as  explained  in  the  chapter  on 
Public  Treasury. 


298  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

The  zakat  of  the  animals  is  collected  by  special  collectors 
called  safi  (plural  su(at).  The  zakat  of  non-apparent  prop- 
erty, on  the  other  hand,  is  disbursed  by  the  owners  them- 
selves directly  to  the  zakat  beneficiaries,  unless  the  non- 
apparent  property  has  become  "  apparent "  by  being  taken 
out  of  the  cities  into  the  country,  in  which  case  their  zakat 
may  no  more  be  disbursed  by  the  owners  themselves  to  the 
beneficiaries  but  must  be  paid  to  the  public  collectors  sta- 
tioned on  the  highways,  the  'ashirs,  who  have  equal  jurisdic- 
tion over  both  apparent  and  non-apparent  property  which 
passes  under  their  inspection. 

The  right  of  the  state  itself  to  collect  the  zakat  in  order 
later  to  disburse  it  to  its  lawful  beneficiaries,  according  to 
the  Hanifite  doctors,  is  based  on  the  protection  (himayah) 
afforded  by  the  state  to  the  property.  In  the  case  of  ani- 
mals, state  protection  is  needed  all  the  time  and  therefore 
their  zakat  must  be  always  paid  to  the  collector.  As  re- 
gards articles  of  trade  and  other  non-apparent  property, 
"  when  the  Moslem  takes  his  stock  of  trade  out  into  the 
country  he  needs  the  protection  of  the  imam  and  therefore 
the  latter  has  the  right  to  collect  the  zakat  from  him  ".1 

According  to  al-Mawardi,2  the  jurisdiction  of  the  col- 
lector of  sadaqah  taxes  (wali  al-sadaqa),  although  he  ac- 
cepts the  zakat  of  "  non-apparent  "  property  when  the  prop- 
erty owners  pay  it  to  him  of  their  own  accord,  and  assists 
them  in  setting  it  apart,  is  limited  to  the  zakat  of  apparent 
property  which  the  property  owners  are  ordered  to  pay  him. 
There  are  two  views  concerning  the  meaning  of  this  order, 
if  it  is  issued  justly.  One  view  is  that  the  order  constitutes 
for  the  property  owners  a  wajib  obligation  and  that  there- 
fore they  may  not  themselves  pay  the  zakat  directly  to  the 

1  Mabsut,  p.  199. 

2  Mawardi,  pp.  195,  196. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     299 

poor,  and  if  they  do  so,  their  zakat  obligation  is  not  settled. 
According  to  the  author  of  the  Mugni,1  the  owner,  when 
ordered,  should  for  the  sake  of  loyalty  pay  the  zakat  of  his 
apparent  property  to  the  imam  even  if  the  latter  should  be 
tyrannical,  for  the  author  adds  that  by  being  tyrannical  the 
imam  does  not  forfeit  his  rule.  The  second  view  is  that 
the  order  constitutes  only  a  mustahabb  obligation  an  : 
merely  meant  to  exhort  the  owner  to  loyalty  (ishara  li 
'l-td'ah).  If,  therefore,  he  himself  pays  the  zakat  directly 
to  the  poor,  his  zakat  obligation  is  discharged. 

In  short,  according  to  the  Hanifites,  within  the  cities,  the 
zakat  of  non-apparent  property  is  disbursed  by  the  owner 
himself  directly  to  the  beneficiaries  of  zakat,  or,  if  he  so 
chooses,  to  the  collector.  If  non-apparent  propert\ 
taken  outside  of  the  city  into  the  country,  it  becomes 
apparent  and,  as  in  the  case  of  other  apparent  prop- 
erty, its  zakat  must  then  be  paid  to  the  public  col- 
lector and  may  not  be  disbursed  by  the  owners  directly 
to  the  beneficiaries.  Finally,  the  zakat  of  animals  must 
always  be  paid  to  the  collector.  Al-ShafVi,  in  his  more 
recent  view,2  contends  that  the  zakat  of  animals  may 
be  paid  by  the  owners  directly  to  the  beneficiaries,  for 
instance,  to  the  poor,  because  the  poor  for  whom  the 
zakat  is  paid  have  a  right  in  property  subject  to  zakat, 
and  when  the  zakat  has  been  given  directly  to  them  this 
right  (haqq)  will  have  reached  its  destination;  under 
these  conditions  the  zakat  debt  must  therefore  be  considered 
settled  exactly  as  the  price  of  a  thing  bought  would  have 
been  settled  if  the  buyer  gave  the  price  to  the  principal  of 
the  agent  rather  than  to  the  agent  from  whom  he  bought  it. 
Moreover,  since  the  collector  collects  the  zakat  in  order 
later  to  disburse  it  to  the  poor,  and  the  owner  by  himself 
disbursing  it  to  the  poor  has  spared  the  collector  that 

1  P.  402.  *  Minhdj,  p.  264. 


300  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

trouble,  no  action  would  lie  against  the  owner  on  that 
score.1  Moreover,  according  to  al-Shafi'i,  as  quoted  in  the 
Umm,2  the  disbursement  of  zakat  by  the  owner  himself 
is  even  to  be  recommended  on  the  ground  that  the  owner 
in  this  way  can  better  assure  himself  that  his  zakat  obli- 
gation is  "  discharged  "  as  between  him  and  God.  How- 
ever, according  to  the  Mugni,3  it  is  preferable  that  the 
owner  pay  his  zakat  to  the  imam  if  the  latter  is  just,  rather 
than  that  he  disburse  it  himself  or  through  an  agent,  be- 
cause by  paying  his  zakat  to  a  just  imam  he  is  positively 
freed  from  his  obligation,  whereas  by  disbursing  it  himself 
he  incurs  a  risk,  for  should  he  disburse  it  to  the  wrong  per- 
son his  zakat  obligation  would  remain  "  undischarged  ". 
Then,  too,  by  paying  the  zakat  to  the  imam  he  makes  it  pos- 
sible to  distribute  the  zakat  among  a  larger  number  of  bene- 
ficiaries. Some  Shafiites  hold  that  the  zakat  must  be  dis- 
bursed to  the  imam  in  every  case,  even  if  the  imam  is  tyran- 
nical. Still  others  hold  that  it  must  in  every  case  be  dis- 
bursed by  the  owner  himself,  not  only  because  in  this  way 
the  owner  may  disburse  his  zakat  to  his  kin  and  neighbors, 
but  also  because  he  earns  additional  merit  for  disbursing  it 
himself.  Al-Sarakhsi,  in  reply  to  al-Shafi'i,  says  that  the 
property  owner  has  no  more  right  to  invalidate  the  right  of 
collection  which  belongs  to  the  imam  by  the  authority  be- 
stowed on  him  by  the  shan'ah,  than  has  the  person  who  is 
subject  to  the  poll-tax  to  settle  it  himself  to  the  warriors 
who  are  the  beneficiaries  of  that  tax.  There  are  two  grounds 
for  this.  One  ground  is  that  the  zakat  is  a  divine  right 
(haqq  allah)  pure  and  simple,  that  its  collection  belongs 
only  to  the  person  whom  God  appoints  as  His  vicar  for  the 

1  Mabsitt,  p.  161-2. 

2  P.  19. 

3  P.  402. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT      301 

collection  of  divine  rights,  namely,  the  im&m,  and  that 
therefore  the  owner's  debt  is  not  canceled  until  he  has  paid 
his  zakat  to  the  imam.  Therefore,  even  if  it  should  be 
known  that  he  settled  his  zakat  debt  once  to  the  poor,  he  is 
required  to  pay  it  again.  Moreover,  in  this  case  the  zakat 
obligation  is  not  settled  even  as  between  him  and  God,  for 
the  imam  has  a  voice  in  the  disbursement  of  the  zakat  t> 
its  beneficiaries  and  the  property  owner,  by  himself  paying 
it  to  them,  has  rendered  void  the  imam's  right  in  this  re- 
spect. The  other  ground  is  that  although  the  collector  is  an 
agent  of  the  poor  and  the  latter  have  a  right  in  the  zakat 
collected,  yet  with  respect  to  the  collection  of  zakat  the  col- 
lector is  so  much  their  master  (mawla),  that  the  poor  do 
not  have  the  right  themselves  to  demand  the  payment  of 
zakat  by  the  owners,  and  the  owners  are  not  obliged  to  settle 
their  zakat  debts  to  them  if  they  so  demand.  Should  they 
do  so  in  fact,  their  position  would  be  like  that  of  a  person 
who  paid  his  debt  to  a  minor  himself  rather  than  to  his 
guardian.  According  to  this  second  ground  the  owner's  ob- 
ligation of  zakat  is  settled  as  between  God  and  himself,  if 
he  pays  it  to  the  poor.  Therefore  if  it  should  be  known  that 
he  actually  paid  his  zakat  debt  to  the  poor,  he  is  not  re- 
quired to  pay  it  again,  unlike  the  person  who  paid  his  debt 
to  the  minor  himself,  for  the  minor  is  not  legally  fit  to  re- 
ceive payments  while  the  poor  are  fit  to  receive  the  zakat 
even  though  they  may  not  demand  its  payment.1 

The  distinction  in  theory  between  apparent  and  non- 
apparent  property  is  recognized  also  by  the  Malikites.  How- 
ever, as  regards  collection,  the  Malikites  virtually  consider 
all  zakat  property  as  apparent  in  contrast  with  the  Shafiites 
who  almost  go  to  the  other  extreme.  Thus,  unlike  al-Shafi'i 
who,  as  we  saw,  recommends  the  disbursement  of  zakat 

lMabsut.  p.  162. 


302  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

to  its  beneficiaries  by  the  owners  themselves,  the  Malikites,1 
with  a  view  to  avoiding  praise  and  insuring  secrecy,  recom- 
mend the  disbursement  of  zakat  through  an  agent  (naib), 
that  is,  the  state,  especially  if  the  zakat  payer  is  ignorant 
of  the  law  or  the  imam  is  just.  In  fact  the  Malikites  require 
the  owners  to  disburse  to  the  imam  when  he  is  just  even  the 
zakat  of  their  non-apparent  property. 

The  person  who  fails  to  pay  his  zakat  (tarik  al-zakat) 
is  not  killed  for  it,  but  his  zakat  is  collected  from  his  prop- 
erty by  force.  If,  however,  the  collection  of  the  zakat  by 
force  is  not  possible,  then  he  may  be  proceeded  against  by 
military  force  until  the  zakat  is  collected,  even  if  that  should 
eventually  lead  to  his  being  killed.2  This  was  done  by  the 
calif  Abu  Bakr  with  the  tribes  which  had  refused  to  pay 
the  zakat  after  the  Prophet's  death.  The  fighting  of  the 
"  refusers  "  (mani()  of  zakat  is  lawful  according  to  either 
of  the  two  constructions  put  on  the  "  order  "  to  pay  the 
zakat  above  mentioned,  because  by  refusing  to  submit  to  the 
just  orders  of  the  authorities  they  have  committed  treason. 
Abu  Hanifah  disapproves  of  fighting  in  case  the  property 
owners  undertake  themselves  to  settle  the  zakat  to  the  poor 
directly. 

The  above  applies  as  regards  the  zakat  of  apparent  prop- 
erty only,3  for  in  the  case  of  non-apparent  property,  the 
owners  may  themselves  settle  their  zakat  dues.  They  are 
nevertheless  rebuked  (ankara  falayhi)  if  they  fail  to  do 
this,  the  right  of  censure  in  this  case  belonging  to  the  public 
inspector  (muhtasib),  since  the  collector  has  no  jurisdiction 
over  non-apparent  property.  It  might,  however,  be  argued 
that  this  right  belongs  to  the  collector  because,  although  he 

1  Kharashi,  pp.  124,  130. 

2  Mawardi,  p.  380. 

3  Mawardi,  pp.  415-6. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT      303 

has  no  jurisdiction  in  this  case,  the  obligation  of  the  prop- 
erty owners  is  discharged  should  they  pay  the  zakat  to  him. 
The  punishment  (tadlb)  of  the  property  owner  depends 
upon  the  peculiar  circumstances  of  the  case,  for  if  he  claims 
that  he  settles  his  zakat  in  secret  he  is  believed. 

According  to  the  Hanifites,1  the  state  may  resort  even  to 
war  in  order  to  collect  the  zakat  of  apparent  property. 
Moreover,  according  to  a  quotation  from  the  Tafariq  in  the 
Kifdyah,2  if  it  is  understood  that  the  people  of  a  city  do  not 
pay  the  zakat  of  their  non-apparent  property,  they  are 
ordered  to  do  so,  and  those  among  them  who  are  known  to 
fail  in  settling  their  dues  are  beaten  and,  according  to  the 
Ishdrat,  put  in  prison  until  they  pay  them.  Finally,  ac- 
cording to  Malik,  the  owners  should  make  no  distinction 
between  the  zakat  of  their  gold  and  silver  (nadd)  for  which 
the  imam  does  not  send  and  the  zakat  of  their  cattle  and 
crops  and  fruits  for  which  the  imam  does  send ;  but  should 
settle  both  when  the  imam  is  just.  Consequently  if  the 
imam  knows  positively  that  they  are  not  paying  the  zakat 
of  gold  and  silver,  he  may  take  it  from  them.8  According 
to  later  Malikites,4  the  zakat  of  both  apparent  and  non- 
apparent  property  is  paid  (dufi'at)  to  the  imam,  who  collects 
it  by  force  and  even  by  war.  If  no  property  of  the  person 
who  refuses  to  pay  his  zakat  can  be  found,  the  imam  may 
put  him  in  prison  if  he  is  known  to  possess  wealth. 

5  If  the  collector  is  unjust  and  tyrannical  in  the  collec- 
tion of  zakat  but  just  in  its  distribution  among  its  bene- 
ficiaries, the  concealment  of  property  from  him  is  allowed. 
If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  collector  is  just  in  the  collection 

'Yusuf,  p.  45-  'R  l'2- 

1  Mudaivwanoh,  pp.  44-5. 
4  Kharashi,  p.  130. 
8  Mawardi,  p.  209. 


304 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


of  zakat  but  unjust  in  its  distribution,  the  concealment  of 
property  from  him  is  then  a  wajib  obligation,  and  the  pay- 
ment of  zakat  to  him  is  not  allowed. 

If  a  person  conceals  1  the  zakat  of  his  property  from  a 
just  collector,  he  collects  it  later  when  he  discovers  it,  and 
he  then  inquires  into  the  cause  of  concealment.  If  the 
zakat  was  concealed  because  the  property  owner  wanted 
himself  to  pay  his  zakat  to  the  poor,  the  collector  does 
not  punish  (ta'zlr)  him.  If,  on  the  contrary,  he  hid  it  in 
order  to  defraud  God,  the  collector  punishes  him,  but  he 
does  not  fine  him  by  charging  him  a  higher  rate  of  zakat. 
Malik  says  that  the  collector  in  such  case  receives  half  of 
the  property  as  fine  because  of  the  hadith :  "If  a  person 
fraudulently  withholds  his  zakat,  I  will  receive  the  zakat 
and  half  of  his  property  as  a  fine  of  God."  However,  the 
hadith:  "  There  is  no  other  right  against  the  property  (of 
the  Moslem)  except  zakat "  indicates  that  the  other  hadith 
is  not  to  be  taken  literally  and  that  it  is  merely  meant  to 
warn  against  defrauding. 

In  the  appointment  of  a  collector  there  are  three  pos- 
sible cases:  (i)  The  collector  may  be  empowered  both  to 
collect  and  to  disburse;  (2)  He  may  be  empowered  to  col- 
lect the  zakat  but  forbidden  to  distribute  it  among  its  bene- 
ficiaries. The  person,  however,  who  appointed  the  col- 
lector becomes  a  sinner  by  causing  a  delay  in  the  distribu- 
tion of  the  zakat,  unless  he  appoints  another  person  for  dis- 
tributing the  same.  (3)  His  power  may  be  indefinite,  that 
is,  he  may  be  neither  specifically  empowered  to  distribute 
the  zakat  nor  forbidden  to  do  so.  He  is  then  entitled  both 
to  collect  and  to  distribute  the  zakat. 

2  The  collector,  to  be  a  full-powered  collector  ('amil  al- 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  208,  380. 
8  Mawardi,  p.  196. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     305 

tafwid),  must  be  a  free  man,  a  Moslem,  just,  and  conver- 
sant with  the  law  on  the  zakat ,  but,  if  he  is  to  be  only  an 
"  executive  "  (munaffidh)  collector  who  is  directed  by  the 
imam  how  much  he  is  to  collect,  he  need  not  be  conversant 
with  the  law  concerning  the  zakat.  It  is  permissible  to 
appoint  as  collector  a  person  who  may  not  lawfully  receive 
a  share  from  the  proceeds  of  zakat,  namely,  a  person  from 
the  Prophet's  relations,  but  such  persons  receive  their  pay 
from  the  share  of  masalih. 

1  The  full-powered  collector  in  collecting  the  zakat  follows 
his  own  judgment  (ijtihad)  on  disputed  points  of  law.  He 
does  not  follow  the  judgment  of  the  imam  or  of  the  prop- 
erty owner.  Neither  is  the  imam  allowed  to  prescribe 
the  amount  he  is  to  collect.  If,  however,  he  is  an  executive 
collector,  he  follows  on  disputed  points  the  judgment  of 
the  imam,  but  not  of  the  owners,  and  it  is  the  duty  of 
the  imam  to  tell  him  what  he  is  to  collect.  Such  a  collector 
is  in  reality  a  messenger  (rasul)  of  the  imam  for  carrying 
out  his  judgments.  Therefore  he  may  be  a  slave  or  a 
dhimmi,  subject  however  to  these  conditions:  He  may 
not  be  appointed  for  the  collection  of  zakat  in  general,  be- 
cause slavery  and  unbelief  are  incompatible  with  the  ex- 
ercise of  authority,  but  he  may  be  appointed  for  the  collec- 
tion of  zakat  as  regards  a  particular  piece  of  property  whose 
amount  and  zakat  liability  are  known.  If,  however,  the 
amount  of  the  property  whose  zakat  is  to  be  collected  or 
the  amount  of  the  zakat  due  on  it  is  not  known,  then  it  is 
not  permissible  to  appoint  as  collector  a  dhimmi,  because 
he  would  have  been  entrusted  with  a  property  concerning 
which  his  report  (khabar)  is  not  valid.  However,  in  this 
case  it  is  permissible  to  appoint  a  slave  as  a  collector  be- 
cause the  report  of  a  slave  is  valid. 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  200-2. 


306  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

If  the  collector  is  late  in  presenting  himself  for  the  col- 
lection of  zakat  which  has  already  fallen  due,  the  property 
owners  wait  for  him  in  case  they  have  heard  that  he  is  com- 
ing and  that  he  is  occupied  for  the  moment  with  others, 
because  the  collector  cannot  possibly  attend  to  every  one  at 
the  same  time.  However,  the  property  owners  themselves 
settle  their  zakat  if  the  collector  is  late  with  respect  to  all 
of  them  and  exceeds  the  usual  delay  limit,  because  the  obli- 
gation of  the  owners  to  pay  the  zakat  to  the  collector  is 
conditioned  upon  the  possibility  of  so  doing  and  lapses  when 
this  is  impossible.  In  this  last  case,  namely,  when  the  owner 
himself  pays  his  sakat  to  the  poor,  he  acts  according  to  his 
own  judgment  if  he  is  a  mujtahid-,  but  if  he  is  not  one,  he 
asks  for  the  opinion  of  the  faqih,  in  whom  he  trusts,  for 
he  is  not  obliged  to  ask  for  the  opinion  of  a  faqih  whom  he 
does  not  trust.  If  he  asks  two  faqihs  for  their  opinions 
and  one  of  them  expresses  the  opinion  that  he  must  pay  the 
zakat,  and  the  other,  that  he  is  not  under  obligation  to  pay 
it,  or  one  holds  the  view  that  he  must  pay  more  than  the 
other  advises  him,  the  Shafiite  doctors  have  disagreed  as 
to  which  of  the  two  opinions  should  be  followed,  some 
holding  that  the  more  unfavorable  of  the  two  must  be  ap- 
plied, others  contending  that  the  person  who  asks  for  the 
advice  may  follow  whichever  opinion  he  chooses. 

When  the  collector  presents  himself  after  the  property 
owner  has  acted  upon  his  own  judgment  or  upon  another's 
view,  and  the  collector's  opinion  happens  to  be  different  in 
that  it  requires  the  payment  of  zakat  or  of  more  of  it,  the 
opinion  of  the  colector  is  followed  if  it  is  still  possible  to 
do  so,  otherwise  the  view  of  the  property  owner  is  accepted. 
If,  on  the  contrary,  the  property  owner's  judgment  requires 
more  than  that  of  the  collector,  the  owner  as  between  him 
and  God  is  obliged  to  pay  the  zakat  according  to  his  own 
judgment,  since  by  his  judgment  he  has  confessed  the  right 
of  the  poor  in  his  property. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     307 

If  the  property  owner  contends  that  the  property  was 
destroyed  before  he  had  become  responsible  for  its  zak&t^ 
he  is  believed,  but  the  collector  may,  if  doubting  his  honesty, 
put  him  on  oath. 

With  respect  to  grapes  or  dates  which  were  appraised,' 
if  the  owner  contends  that  they  were  destroyed,  he  is  be- 
lieved upon  oath  if  the  cause  of  destruction  he  invokes 
is  concealed  (khafi),  as  theft,  or  open  (zOhir)  and  well- 
known;  but,  according  to  the  more  prevalent  view,  he  is 
required  to  produce  evidence  if  it  is  not  well-known.  If, 
on  the  other  hand,  he  claims  that  the  appraiser  was  unjust 
or  that  he  made  a  mistake,  his  plea  is  rejected  if  the  in- 
justice or  mistake  claimed  is  too  great  to  be  true,  such  as 
one- fourth  of  the  entire  amount;  otherwise,  according  to 
the  more  general  view,  he  is  believed. 

H  the  property  owner  admits  to  the  collector  the  amount 
of  his  zakat  dues  but  does  not  tell  him  about  the  amount  of 
his  entire  property,  the  collector  may  take  the  owner's  word 
and  collect  accordingly  without  requiring  him  to  exhibit  his 
property. 

If  *  the  owner  of  cattle  fixes  their  number  at  a  figure,  he 
is  believed,  if  trustworthy;  otherwise  the  animals  are 
counted  by  being  made  to  pass  through  a  narrow  passage. 
The  owner  is  likewise  believed  if  he  contends  that  the 
young  were  born  after  the  year  and  should  not  pay  zakQt. 
In  such  cases  he  may  also  be  sworn  by  way  of  precaution 
though  not  as  a  matter  of  law  (istihbaba) .  In  other  words, 
should  he  refuse  to  swear  he  is  nevertheless  excused. 

According  to  al-Haytami,4  the  word  of  the  property 

1  According  to  the  Shafiites,  as  we  already  saw  (Minhdj,  p.  268),  the 
owner  becomes  responsible  for  the  sakdt  by  not  disbursing  it  as  soon 
as  it  became  possible  ( tamakkun}  to  do  so. 

1  Minhdj,  p.  242 ;  Mugni,  p.  378. 

»  Minhdj,  pp.  236,  237;  Mugni,  pp.  370,  371. 

*Al-Fatdwa  al-Kubra,  vol.  ii,  p.  34. 


3o8  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

owner  as  to  the  amount  of  his  zakat  is  taken  only  in  case 
he  is  himself  positive  about  it,  and  in  such  case  it  is  well  to 
put  him  on  oath  if  there  is  ground  for  suspicion.  If,  how- 
ever, the  property  owner  is  only  guessing,  his  conjecture  is 
not  taken  into  account,  the  amount  being  determined  other- 
wise. 

1  If  the  property  owner  contends  that  he  paid  (ikhrdjaha) 
his  zakat  directly  to  the  poor,  his  word  is  accepted,  if  the 
collector  had  not  arrived  on  time  when  the  zakat 's  payment 
became  possible;  but  the  collector,  if  he  has  suspicions,  may 
require  him  to  take  oath.    According  to  one  view,  the  zakat 
is  collected  from  the  owner  if  he  refuses  to  take  the  oath, 
but  according  to  another  view,  it  is  not.    If,  however,  the 
owner  contends  having  himself  disbursed  his  zakat  notwith- 
standing the  arrival  of  the  collector  on  time,  his  word  is  not 
accepted  if  it  is  said  that  the  owner  is  obliged  to  pay  his 
zakat  to  the  collector,  but  his  word  is  accepted  if  it  is  said 
that  the  payment  of  zakat  to  the  collector  is  only  a  musta- 
habb. 

If  the  property  owners  claim  to  have  paid  the  collector 
their  zakat ,  and  the  collector  denies  it,  the  disbursed  owners 
are  sworn  to  the  truth  of  their  claim  and  released  from  their 
dues. 

2  If  the  collector,  whether  of  the  full-powered  or  the  ex- 
ecutive type,  confesses  having  received  the  zakat  from  the 
owners,  his  word  is  accepted  during  his  tenure  of  office, 
but  there  are  two  views  concerning  the  acceptance  of  his 
word  after  his  dismissal  from  office.    Those  who  hold  that 
the  payment  of  zakat  to  the  collector  is  a  mustahabb  say 
that  his  word  is  still  accepted,  but  those  who  hold  that  the 
payment  of  zakat  to  the  collector  is  a  wajib  obligation  say 
that  his  word  after  dismissal  from  office  is  not  accepted, 
and  that  independent  evidence  must  be  presented  to  prove 

1  Mawardi,  p.  209.  *  Mawardi,  p.  209. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     309 

the  point;  that  furthermore,  even  though  he  be  just,  he  is 
not  also  allowed  to  bear  witness  to  the  payment  of  the  zakat. 

1  If  the  property  owner  has  suspicion  about  the  proper 
disbursement  of  his  zakat  and  asks  to  watch  the  collector 
disburse  it,  the  collector  is  not  obliged  to  grant  his  request, 
because  by  paying  it  to  the  collector  the  property  owner  be- 
comes free  from  his  sakat  obligation,  and  therefore  should 
the  collector  ask  him  to  be  present  at  the  disbursement  of 
the  zakat  he  is  not  obliged  to  do  so. 

The  collector  is  not  allowed  to  receive  bribes  or  gifts 
from  the  property  owners,  for  the  Prophet  said :  "The  gifts 
of  the  collectors  are  a  case  of  fraud  ". 

If  the  collector  appears  to  have  been  unfaithful  (khv- 
ydnah)  the  right  to  remedy  the  evil  belongs  to  the  imam 
and  not  to  the  property  owners.  In  this  case  the  bene- 
ficiaries do  not  have  a  right  of  action,  but  as  "  persons  in 
need  "  (tasallum  dhawu  al-hajat)  they  may  lodge  a  com- 
plaint with  the  proper  authorities.  They  are,  however, 
barred  from  testifying  against  the  collector  because  of  the 
suspicion  attaching  to  them.  As  regards  the  testimony  of 
the  property  owners  against  the  collector,  if  it  relates  to  the 
collection  of  sakat  from  them  it  is  not  admissible,  but  if  it 
relates  to  the  disbursement  of  zakat  to  others  than  its  bene- 
ficiaries it  is  admitted. 

According  to  the  Hanifites,  if  the  Moslem  or  dhimmi* 
traders  who  pass  the  'ashirs  claim  that  they  do  not  owe 
zakat  or  toll  on  their  goods,  either  because  the  year  has  not 
elapsed  or  the  goods  are  not  articles  of  trade,  or  because 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  214-7. 

2  The  dhimmi  traders  are  treated  by  the  'dshirs  exactly  like  the  Mos- 
lem traders,  excepting  the  case  where  the  dhimmis  claim  themselves 
to  have  disbursed  the  tax  to  its  beneficiaries.    This  is  because  the  toll 
levied  on  the  dhimmis  is  not  sakdt  but  a  regular  tax  disbursed  by  the 
state  itself.    The  harbi  traders  are  treated  in  a  different  way,  as  will  be 
explained  in  the  next  section  on  the  'Ashirs. 


3io  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

they  are  in  debt  or  have  already  settled  their  dues  to  another 
'ashir, — provided  however  there  was  another  'ashir  during 
the  year, — or  if  the  Moslem  traders  claim  that  they  settled 
in  the  city  directly  to  the  poor  the  zakat  of  their  non-appar- 
ent property,  they  are  believed  if  they  support  these  state- 
ments by  taking  oath  and  they  consequently  do  not  pay 
zakat.  For  they  are  trustees  in  regard  to  their  zakat  debt 
and,  as  such,  their  word  is  taken  if  supported  by  an  oath. 
Abu  Yusuf  claims  that,  as  in  the  case  of  other  acts  of  wor- 
ship, their  statements  are  taken  to  be  true  and  they  need 
not  be  sworn  to.  Some  say  that  a  claim  of  indebtedness 
is  not  accepted  unless  the  debt  covers  the  entire  property, 
but  the  author  of  the  Majma'  observes  that  it  is  immaterial 
whether  the  debt  covers  the  entire  property  or  a  part  of  it 
provided  only  it  affects  the  nisab.1 

Likewise,  if  the  trader  claims  that  his  goods  are  from 
Marw  (marwi)  or  from  Harat  (harawi),  the  'ashir  may 
not  open  the  goods  in  order  to  inspect  them,  if  by  so  doing 
he  is  likely  to  injure  them.  In  such  case  he  collects  the  tax 
in  accordance  with  the  sworn  statement  of  the  trader.  This 
is  based  on  a  hadlth  of  the  calif  Omar  to  that  effect.2 

The  Moslem  trader  has  to  pay  the  zakat  again  if  he 
claims  that  he  settled  the  zakat  of  his  trade  goods  to  the 
poor  outside  of  the  cities,  because  he  is  entitled  to  do  this 
only  within  the  cities,  not  in  the  country,  since  there  the 
property  needs  the  protection  of  the  state  and  the  right 
of  collection  therefore  belongs  to  the  state.  For  the 
same  reason,  the  zakat  has  to  be  paid  over  again  if  the 
Moslem  trader  claims  that  he  settled  the  zakat  of  his 
sawtfim  animals  to  the  poor,  no  matter  where,  because  the 
collection  of  the  zakat  of  sawa'im  animals  both  in  the  cities 
and  in  the  country  belongs  to  the  state. 

1  Majma',  p.  172.  *Mabsitt,  p.  200. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT 

All  the  above  applies  also  as  between  the  owner  of 
sawa'im  animals  and  the  collector  (sa'i)  who  calls  at  his 
residence  for  their  zakat',  namely,  the  owner  is  believed 
upon  oath  if  he  says  that  the  year  has  not  elapsed  or  that 
the  animals  are  covered  by  debt,  or  if  he  says  that  the 
animals  are  not  his  or  that  he  settled  the  zakat  to  an- 
other collector;  but  his  claim  is  rejected  if  it  is  to  the  effect 
that  he  gave  his  zakat  to  the  poor  directly.  Al-Shafi'i  dif- 
fers on  the  last  point.1 

According  to  the  Zahir-al-riwayah  view,  when  the  owner 
claims  to  have  settled  his  zakat  dues  to  another  collector, 
it  is  not  necessary  for  him  to  present  a  written  receipt 
from  the  other  collector,  but  his  sworn  statement  is  con- 
sidered sufficient;  provided  that  there  was  in  fact  another 
collector  during  that  year.  However,  according  to  a  report 
from  Abu  Hani  f ah  through  Hasan  Ibn  Ziyad,  the  tax 
payer  must  prove  his  statement  by  presenting  the  respec- 
tive receipt  (baraah).  The  ground  for  this  second  view 
is  that  the  custom  of  collectors  is  to  give  a  receipt  when 
they  collect  the  zakat  and  therefore  unless  the  owner  pre- 
sents this  receipt  the  presumption  is  against  him  and  his 
word  is  not  accepted;  just  as  the  claim  of  the  mother  to 
have  borne  a  child  is  not  accepted  even  if  sworn  to  by  her, 
unless  testified  to  by  the  midwife.  The  ground  for  the 
other  view,  which  is  the  one  generally  accepted  by  the  doc- 
tors, is  that  although  the  receipt  is  a  written  instrument, 
people's  writings  look  similar,  and  sometimes  it  happens 
that  the  tax  payer  forgets  to  take  the  receipt  along,  or  loses 
it,  and  that  therefore  the  decision  may  not  be  made  to  de- 
pend on  the  receipt. 

When  the  tax  payer  is  obliged  to  pay  the  tax  over  again 
for  one  reason  or  another,  it  is  the  second  payment  that 
constitutes  a  payment  of  the  zakat,  the  first  payment  being 

lMabsul  p.  161. 


312  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

a  nail.     Some  say  that  the  zakat  is  the  first  sum  paid,  and 
that  the  second  is  a  fine.1 

Finally,  according  to  Malik,2  both  the  practice  and  the 
opinion  of  the  doctors  of  his  time  is  to  the  effect  that  people 
should  not  be  oppressed  in  the  matter  of  sadaqah  but  that 
whatever  they  give  should  be  accepted.  According  to  later 
Malikites,  when  the  owner  claims  to  have  disbursed  his 
zakat  directly  to  the  poor,  or  contends  that  he  is  exempt 
from  it  by  reason  of  indebtedness,  he  is  believed  only  as 
regards  the  zakat  of  non-apparent  property,  the  settlement 
of  which  is  entrusted  to  his  loyalty,  but  his  plea  is  rejected 
as  regards  the  zakat  of  apparent  property.  However,  fol- 
lowing a  statement  of  Malik,  the  owners  are  believed  in 
their  statements  to  the  effect  that  they  do  not  have  other 
property  and  are  not  put  on  oath,  even  as  regards  apparent 
property. 

According  to  Khalil,3  if  the  number  of  one's  cattle,  when 
they  are  actually  counted,  turns  out  to  be  different  from 
the  number  previously  reported  to  the  collector  (safi),  the 
latter  collects  the  zakat  on  the  basis  of  the  actual  number 
if  he  had  not  previously  believed  (saddaqa)  the  cattle 
owner's  report.  If,  however,  he  had  believed  his  report, 
he  still  collects  on  the  basis  of  the  actual  number  if  that 
number  is  lower  than  the  one  reported.  If,  on  the  con- 
trary, it  is  higher,  according  to  one  view  of  the  matter 
the  actual  number,  but  according  to  another  view,  the 
number  reported  is  taken  as  basis.  This  difference  of 
view  is  a  consequence  of  the  difference  of  view  on  the 
question  whether  or  not  the  fact  of  the  collector's  believ- 
ing the  cattle  owner's  report  has  the  legal  force  of  judg- 
ment by  a  judge  and  may  therefore  replace  the  facts 

1  Jdmi',  p.  319. 

2Kharashi,  p.  130,  also  pp.  80,  106;  Muwattd',  p.  115;  Zarqani,  vol.  ii, 
p<  62.  *Kharashi,  p.  70. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT 

themselves.  Al-Kharashi  thinks  that  the  tax  should  still 
be  collected  on  the  basis  of  the  actual  number.  If  the  grapes 
or  dates  which  were  appraised  are  later  destroyed  by  acci- 
dent (jaihah)  this  fact  is  taken  into  consideration.  If  the 
appraisal  turns  out  to  be  too  high,  no  reduction  is  made 
unless  this  is  proved  by  the  owner.  If,  on  the  contrary,  it 
turns  out  to  be  too  low,  the  owner  is  advised  to  pay  tithe 
on  the  basis  of  the  actual  produce,  but  he  may  not  be  forced 
to  do  so.1 

"  If  the  collector  admits  having  received  the  zakat  but 
claims  to  have  disbursed  it  to  the  beneficiaries,  while  the 
latter  deny  it,  the  collector's  word  is  accepted  because  he  is 
a  trustee  with  regard  to  zakat ;  but  the  denial  of  the  bene- 
ficiaries is  likewise  accepted  to  the  extent  that  they  are  con- 
sidered still  to  be  "  poor  "  and  entitled  to  sak&t  as  bene- 
ficiaries. 

If  the  collector  denies  that  he  has  received  the  zakat 
he  is  released  upon  making  oath.  If  in  such  case  some  of 
the  property  owners  testify  in  favor  of  those  claiming  the 
payment  of  their  zakat  dues  to  the  collector,  their  testimony 
is  not  admitted  if  it  is  after  the  collector's  denial,  and  the 
institution  of  legal  proceedings  between  them ;  but  if  it  hap- 
pens before,  their  testimony  is  heard  and  the  collector  is 
sentenced  to  make  restitution  of  the  amount  claimed  to 
have  been  paid  to  him.  If  in  such  case  the  collector  after 
the  testimony  claims  to  have  disbursed  the  zakat  to  its  bene- 
ficiaries he  is  not  listened  to,  because  he  has  belied  his  claim 
by  his  previous  denial ;  and,  on  the  other  hand,  if  the  bene- 
ficiaries testify  in  his  favor,  saying  that  they  received  it 
from  him,  they  are  likewise  disregarded. 

If  the  zakat  is  destroyed  in  the  hands  of  the  collector 
before  its  disbursement  to  its  beneficiaries,  the  collector  is 
not  liable  to  damages  unless  it  is  due  to  his  neglect  or  fault. 

iRharashi,  p.  80.  2  Mawardi,  pp.  215-7. 


314  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

If  the  collector  by  mistake  disburses  the  zakat  to  other 
than  its  beneficiaries  he  is  not  liable  for  damages  if  he  dis- 
burses it  to  persons  whose  status  is  concealed,  such  as  well- 
to-do  persons ;  but  if  he  disburses  it  to  persons  whose  status 
he  might  have  known,  such  as  slaves  and  the  Relations, 
opinion  varies.  If  it  is  the  property  owner  who  makes  this 
mistake,  opinion  varies  as  regards  disbursement  to  those 
whose  status  is  not  apparent,  but  as  regards  persons  whose 
status  is  apparent,  he  is  universally  held  to  be  liable  for 
damages.  The  collector  is  treated  with  greater  leniency 
because  he  is  occupied  with  so  many  more  people.1 

SECTION  II 

The  'Ashirs  or  Collectors  on  the  Public  Road 
The  'ashirs  are  the  collectors  stationed  by  the  imam  on 
the  public  road  in  order  to  collect  the  zakat  of  Moslem 
traders,  as  well  as  the  tolls  imposed  on  the  dhimmi  and 
harbi  traders  who  pass  him.  The  institution  of  'ashirs  and 
the  rules  pertaining  to  their  authority  are  based  on  the  pre- 
cedent established  by  the  calif  Omar,  who  appointed  ( ashirs 
and  instructed  them  to  collect  from  Moslem  traders  two 
and  one-half  per  cent  and  from  dhimmi  traders  five  per 
cent,  and  who  when  asked  "  How  much  shall  we  collect 
from  the  harbis?  ",  said:  "  How  much  do  the  harbis  collect 
from  us  ?  "  When  he  was  told  that  they  collected  ten  per 
cent,  he  said :  "  Collect  from  them  ten  per  cent."  Accord- 
ing to  another  report,  he  said :  "  Collect  from  them  the  rate 
that  they  collect  from  us  " ;  and  when  further  asked,  "  If 
it  is  not  known  what  rate  they  collect?",  he  answered: 
"  Collect  from  them  ten  per  cent."  a 

1  Concerning  the  proper  authorities  invested  with  the  right  of  ap- 
pointing the  collectors  and  other  officials,  the  persons  who  may  be  so 
appointed,  the  duration  of  their  tenure  of  office,  the  determination  of 
their  salaries,  the  manner  in  which  they  are  appointed,  and  their  right 
to  appoint  substitutes,  see  Mawardi,  pp.  360-6.  For  the  audit  of  their 
accounts,  see  infra,  pp.  49&-Q. 

s  Mabstit,  p.  199 ;  Yusuf ,  p.  76. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT 

The  Shafiites  l  condemn  the  institution  of  4a  shirs,  as  ap- 
plied to  traffic  within  the  Moslem  world,  as  unjust  and  un- 
lawful. They  consequently  do  not  allow  the  levy  of  tolls 
('ushr,  plural,  'ushur)  from  dhimmi  traders  who  travel 
within  a  Moslem  country  from  one  city  to  another,  unless  it 
is  so  stipulated.  Likewise  it  is  not  allowed  to  levy  tolls 
on  the  harbi  traders  unless  it  is  so  stipulated.  The  rate 
of  the  toll  is  fixed  by  the  imam  who  may,  and  should,  en- 
tirely remit  it  if  that  would  induce  the  importation  of  com- 
modities which  are  greatly  needed  by  the  Moslems.  How- 
ever, both  the  dhimmi  and  the  harbi  traders  may  not  be  al- 
lowed to  enter  the  Hijaz  territory  for  trade  purposes  unless 
their  trade  is  needed  or  a  toll  is  stipulated.  If  the  toll  is 
based  on  the  price,  it  is  not  collected  until  after  the  sale. 
When  it  is  collected,  a  receipt  is  given,  and  it  is  not  collected 
again  during  that  year.  Non-traders  do  not  pay  a  toll,  even 
when  they  enter  the  Hijaz. 

According  to  the  Malikites,3  the  levy  of  tolls  from  infidel 
traders  is  justified  by  the  practice  of  Omar.  Thus  Malik 
says  that  if  a  dhimmi  of  Egypt  goes  to  Syria  for  trade,  or 
if  a  Syrian  goes  to  'Iraq,  or  a  trader  of  'Iraq  to  Medina  or 
Yaman,  he  is  subject  to  a  toll  when  he  sells  or  buys  wares; 
but  that  when  once  he  has  paid  a  toll  he  is  not  taxed  further 
should  he  buy  or  sell  again,  until  he  has  left  the  city  and 
returned  once  more. 

The  Malikite  doctrine  as  summarized  by  al-Dardlr  is  as 
follows :  The  dhimmi  traders  pay  a  toll  of  ten  per  cent  on 
the  wares  they  sell  or  purchase  in  other  than  their  own  dis- 
tricts (iqllm,  ufq),  even  if  they  should  return  (ikhtalafil) 
to  a  district  several  times  in  a  single  year,  for  the  toll  is 
levied  in  consideration  of  the  benefit  derived  from  the  trade 

1  Mawardi,  p.  359;   Angari,  vol.  iv,  p.  218;   Wajis,  vol.  ii,  p.  aoi; 
Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  278;  Mugni,  vol.  iv,  p.  288;  cf.  Umm,  vol.  iv,  p.  193. 

2  Dardlr,  pp.  205-6;  cf.  Mudowwonah,  p.  40;  Zarqani,  vol.  ii,  pp.  51,  75. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

and  the  benefit  recurs  every  time  the  dhimmi  returns  for 
trade.  At  each  time,  however,  the  toll  is  collected  only 
once,  even  if  he  should  buy  and  sell  during  that  time  re- 
peatedly. In  case  of  purchase,  the  toll  is  collected  in  kind, 
but  in  case  of  sale  it  is  collected  in  specie  from  the  price, 
and  consequently  no  toll  is  collected  if  the  goods  are  not 
sold.  In  order  to  induce  the  importation  of  foodstuffs  to 
Mecca  and  Medina  and  the  adjoining  country,  the  rate  of 
the  toll  in  those  cities  was  only  five  per  cent  of  the  price. 
If  the  dhimmi  traders  buy  goods  in  one  city  and  sell  them 
in  another  city,  both  cities  being  within  the  same  district, 
for  instance,  in  Syria  or  Egypt  or  the  Byzantine  country 
(rum)  or  the  Magrib,  they  are  subject  to  no  toll  whatever. 
Unless  otherwise  stipulated,  the  harbi  traders  pay  as  toll 
ten  per  cent  of  their  wares,  whether  or  not  they  sell  them. 
This  toll  is  not  repeated  if  they  travel  from  one  district  to 
another  within  the  Moslem  world,  for  with  respect  to  the 
harbis  all  Moslem  districts  are  like  one  single  district.  The 
toll,  however,  is  repeated  if  they  had  meanwhile  returned 
to  their  country  and  are  coming  back  from  it;  for  upon 
their  return  to  their  country  the  effect  of  the  aman  which 
was  given  to  them  before  ceases. 

The  'ashirs  must  be  distinguished  from  the  sa'is  who  are 
the  collectors  of  the  zakat  of  sawaim  animals  and  go  about 
in  the  country  calling  on  the  owners  of  sawa'im  animals  for 
their  zakat  dues ;  as  the  word  sai,  literally  runner,  indicates. 
As  opposed  to  these  special  terms,  musaddiq  means  any  col- 
lector of  zakat,  within  or  without  the  cities;  so  does  lamil, 
literally,  agent.  On  the  other  hand,  the  expression  wall  al- 
sadaqat  denotes  the  authorities  entrusted  with  the  collection 
and  disbursement  of  the  zakat  taxes.1 

The  Hanifite  views  concerning  the  powers  and  duties  of 

1  Cf.  Angari,  p.  395 ;  Mugni,  vol.  iii,  p.  102. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT      317 

the  *  Oshir  are  as  follows:  The  'ashirs  are  entitled  to  collect 
the  zakat  of  both  apparent  and  non-apparent  property 
which  conies  under  their  jurisdiction,  although  they  are 
primarily  appointed  to  collect  the  zakat  of  non-apparent 
property  and  the  tolls  imposed  on  the  non-Moslem  traders. 
The  jurisdiction  of  the  'ashirs  as  regards  the  zakat  of 
non-apparent  property  (which  is  normally  outside  of  gov- 
ernmental jurisdiction),  is  based  on  the  fiction,  already  re- 
ferred to,  that  non-apparent  property  becomes  apparent 
property  when  it  is  taken  outside  of  the  cities  into  the 
country  where  it  is  exposed  to  the  danger  of  robbers  and 
hence  needs  the  protection  of  the  state;  which  in  consid- 
eration for  the  protection  it  affords  acquires  the  right  itself 
to  collect  the  sakat.  Al-Sarakhsi x  observes  that  this  (fic- 
tion) holds  even  more  truly  as  regards  the  non-Moslems 
because  they  are  more  exposed  to  the  danger  of  robbers. 

The  'ashirs,  therefore,  in  reckoning  up  the  nisab,  have  no 
right  to  count  non-apparent  property  that  the  traders  may 
happen  to  possess  elsewhere,  but  may  count  the  property  in 
question  only  when  the  owners  have  it  with  them.  They 
may,  however,  count  apparent  property  found  elsewhere, 
because  apparent  property  remains  such,  no  matter  where 
situated.2 

In  accordance  with  the  hadlth  of  the  calif  Omar  already 
referred  to,  the  rates  are  two  and  one-half  per  cent  for  the 
Moslems,  but  five  per  cent  for  the  dhimmis,  owing  to  the 
fact  that  they  need  protection  from  robbers  more  than  the 
Moslems.  Unlike  the  Moslems,  who  must  pay  the  zakat  of 
their  trade  articles  whether  or  not  they  pass  an  'ashir,  the 
dhimmis  are  subject  to  this  toll  of  five  per  cent  only  in  so 
far  as  they  come  under  the  jurisdiction  of  an  'ashir  by 

1  Mabstt,  p.  199. 

*Mabstt,  ibid.;  fdmi',  p.  318;  'Alomkiriyyah,  p.  257. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

traveling  for  trade.1  This  difference  is  due  to  the  fact  that 
while  the  tax  collected  by  the  'ashirs  from  Moslems  consists 
in  their  zakat  dues,  the  one  collected  from  the  dhimmi  is  in 
reality  only  an  octroi  duty.  Except  for  these  two  differ- 
ences the  dhimmis  are  treated  like  the  Moslems  in  every  re- 
spect. According  to  the  doctors,  the  dhimmis  by  paying  a 
double  tax  have  earned  a  right  to  this  equality  of  treatment. 
As  regards  the  harbi  traders,  the  f  ashir  collects  from  the 
property  they  have  with  them  at  the  rate  of  ten  per  cent,  pro- 
vided their  property  amounts  to  a  nisab  and  the  'ashir  does 
not  know  the  rate  collected  from  the  Moslems  by  the  harbis 
in  their  country  but  only  knows  the  fact  of  collection. 
If,  however,  the  'ashir  knows  the  rate  paid  by  Moslems  in 
the  land  of  harbis,  he  then  collects  from  the  harbis  the  same 
rate,  whether  it  be  little  or  much,  in  order  to  get  even  with 
them.  According  to  the  Path,2  it  is  only  with  respect  to  the 
rate  of  the  tax  that  the  principle  of  reprisal  (mujasat) 
holds  true,  since  the  right  of  collecting  a  tax  at  all  (asl  al- 
akhdh)  is  based  on  the  fact  that  the  harbis  during  their 
sojourn  in  Moslem  territory  enjoy  the  protection  of  the 
Moslem  state  and  so  come  under  its  taxing  power.  If  the 
harbis  are  collecting  as  a  tax  from  Moslem  traders  the 
whole  of  their  property,  the  'ashir  does  not  collect  the  whole 
of  the  harbis'  property  but  leaves  with  them  enough  to 
enable  them  to  return  home.  Some  say  that  in  such  case  the 
whole  should  be  taken  in  order  to  dissuade  the  harbis  from 
doing  the  same  thing  to  the  Moslems,  but  the  Path  replies 
that  this  would  be  unjust  after  the  harbis  have  been  given  a 
pledge  (amdn)  of  safety  when  they  entered  the  Moslem 
territory,  and  that  therefore  the  Moslems  should  not  do  it 
simply  because  the  harbis  do,  for  leaving  a  person  without 

1  Yusuf,  p.  76. 
'P.  175. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT 


319 


any  means  for  returning  home,  after  having  given  him 
a  pledge  of  safety,  would  practically  amount  to  murdering 
him.  The  Hidayah  applies  the  principle  of  reprisal  also  as 
regards  the  requirement  of  nisab,  for  according  to  it,  if  the 
harbis  tax  any  quantity,  the  Moslems  also  do  the  same.  In 
another  view  of  the  matter,  however,  the  harbis  are  never 
taxed  when  their  property  is  little,  because  they  will  need  it 
for  food  and  for  satisfying  other  wants,  and  because  the 
property,  being  little,  does  not  need  protection  from  robbers. 

If,  finally,  the  harbis  collect  no  tax  from  Moslem  traders, 
then  likewise  the  'ashir  does  not  collect  a  tax  from  the 
harbis,  "  for  the  fact  that  they  have  given  up  their  oppres- 
sion (i.  e.,  collecting  taxes  from  Moslems)  while  they  have 
the  power,  is  on  their  part  an  exercise  of  favor  toward  us, 
but  we  (i.  e.,  Moslems)  are  more  fit  to  be  possessed  with 
virtues  than  the  harbis"  x 

The  children  and  women  of  the  harbis  are  exempt  from 
tax  on  condition  that  similar  treatment  is  accorded  to  Mos- 
lems by  the  harbis. 

If  the  harbi  traders  claim  that  they  have  debts  or  that  the 
year  is  not  complete,  their  statements  are  not  accepted  and 
they  must  pay  the  tax  even  if  those  assertions  would  be 
proved.2  Some  say  that  this  applies  only  in  case  the  prac- 
tice of  the  harbis  is  not  known  or,  if  it  is  known  that  they 
do  not  accept  similar  statements  made  by  Moslem  traders 
in  their  country.  If  therefore  it  is  known  that  they  accept 
such  statements,  their  statements  then  are  accepted  by  the 
' ashir s  and  they  are  exempted  from  the  tax.8  If,  however, 
the  harbi  claims  that  a  certain  person  is  his  child  or  umm 
walad  (mother  of  a  child,  i.  e.,  a  slave  whose  child  was 

1  Fatb,  P.  175. 

'Path,  p.  174. 

,  pp.  319-30. 


320 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


acknowledged  by  her  master  as  his  own),  his  words  are  be- 
lieved and  he  does  not  pay  tax  on  them,  because  the  fact  that 
he  is  a  harbi  does  not  preclude  his  having  children  or  his 
acknowledging  as  his  own  the  children  of  his  slaves. 

If  the  harbi  passes  the  'ashir  for  a  second  time  before  the 
lapse  of  a  year  from  the  first  time,  he  is  taxed  again  if  he 
had  returned  to  his  country  in  the  meantime,  and  this  would 
be  true  if  he  passed  the  'ashir  ten  or  more  times  during  a 
single  day,  provided  that  each  time  in  the  meanwhile  he  had 
returned  to  his  own  country,  because  the  tax  is  collected 
from  him  in  consideration  of  the  aman  (pledge  of  protec- 
tion) given  him  when  he  entered  the  Moslem  territory,  and 
the  effect  of  the  aman  ceases  as  soon  as  he  returns  to  the 
country  of  the  harbis.  The  aman  in  fact  has  to  be  renewed 
every  time  he  enters  the  Moslem  territory. 

Consequently,  if  the  harbi  has  not  returned  to  his  country 
during  the  year  he  is  not  taxed  again  during  that  year. 
According  to  the  Jami'?  what  is  said  concerning  the  last 
case  applies  if  the  harbis  act  the  same  way  in  regard  to  the 
Moslems  or  if  it  is  not  known  how  they  act,  for  if  it  is 
known  that  they  act  differently  they  receive  a  similar  treat- 
ment at  the  hands  of  the  Moslems. 

If  the  dhimmi  passes  the  'ashir  with  wine  he  is  taxed  for 
its  value  if  he  intended  to  trade  in  it.  If  however  he  passes 
the  'ashir  with  pigs  he  is  not  taxed.  According  to 
al-Shafi'i,  wine  and  pigs  are  not  taxed,  because  they 
do  not  possess  a  value,  but  Zufar  holds  that  they  do 
possess  a  value  for  the  dhimmis  and  must  therefore  pay  a 
tax.  Finally,  Abu  Yusuf  says  that  they  pay  a  tax  if  they 
are  found  together, — in  such  case  the  pigs  being  consid- 
ered as  an  appendage  (tabaf)  to  wine;  but  if  they  come 
under  the  '  ashir' s  jurisdiction  separately,  only  the  wine 

'  P.  320. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     321 

is  taxed.  The  Moslem  is  never  taxed  for  his  wine. 
The  skins  of  dead  animals  are  treated  like  wine,  because 
both  may  be  converted  into  wealth  (mat), — the  former 
by  being  turned  into  vinegar  and  the  latter  by  being  tanned 
for  use  as  leather.  Pigs,  however,  do  not  constitute  wealth 
in  any  case.  Moreover,  wine  and  skins  being  fungible  goods, 
the  collection  of  a  part  of  their  value  as  a  tax  is  not  collec- 
tion of  the  thing  itself,  but,  pigs  being  non-fungible  (qlnti) 
goods,  the  collection  as  a  tax  of  part  of  their  value  is  col- 
lection of  a  part  of  the  pigs  themselves  (fayn),  which  are 
forbidden  to  Moslems.  The  value  of  the  skins  and  the  wine 
is  ascertained  from  a  dhimmi  and  according  to  another  view 
from  two  dhimmis  who  became  Moslems  or  from  two  Mos- 
lems who,  having  for  a  time  practised  impiety  (fisq),  have 
later  repented.  However  the  Majma'  remarks  that  the 
value  of  goods  changes  with  time  and  place  and  that  there 
is  difficulty  in  finding  two  persons  of  these  types  at  the  time 
of  need. 

According  to  Abu  Hanlfah,  if  a  person  should  pass  the 
*  ashir  with  perishable  goods,  like  fruits,  fresh  dates,  vege- 
tables, milk,  etc.,  the  'ashir  does  not  collect  their  tax  but 
orders  the  owners  themselves  to  pay  it  to  the  poor.  Ac- 
cording to  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  the 
f ashir  collects  the  zakat  on  them,  since  they  are  like  other 
goods  as  regards  need  for  protection  from  robbers.  Abu 
Hanifah's  argument  is  that  the  'ashir  collects  as  zakat  a  part 
of  the  nisab  in  order  to  disburse  it  to  the  poor,  but  that  in 
this  case  there  are  no  poor  to  whom  he  may  disburse  imme- 
diately, and  that  he  cannot  do  so  later  because  by  that  time 
the  goods  will  have  perished.  Therefore,  the  best  thing  to 
do  under  the  circumstances  is  to  order  the  owners  them- 
selves to  pay  their  zakat  dues  directly  to  the  poor.1  The 
above  applies  also  to  the  case  of  dhimmis  and  harbis. 
1  Mabsuf,  p.  204;  'Atomkiriyyah,  p.  259. 


322  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

The  'ashir  does  not  collect  zakat  from  the  mukatab  or 
the  minor  who  passes  him,  since  his  property  is  not  sub- 
ject to  zakat.  Likewise,  he  does  not  collect  zakat  from 
slaves  for  goods  (bida'ah)  of  their  masters  which  they 
happen  to  possess  for  trade  unless  their  masters  are  with 
them.  If,  however,  the  goods  do  not  belong  to  the  master, 
but  are  the  slave's  own  stock  earned  by  him  by  trading 
with  the  permission  of  his  master  (ma'dhun),  the  slave 
does  not  pay  zakat  on  them  if  he  owes  money  to  the  entire 
value  of  his  goods.  If  he  does  not  owe  any  debts,  the 
'tishir  collects  zakat  if  his  master  is  along  with  him.  If, 
however,  the  master  is  not  present,  then  according  to  Abu 
Hanifah,  as  quoted  in  the  al-Jami'  al-Sagir,  the  'ashir  still 
collects  the  zakat }  but  in  the  opinion  of  Abu  Yusuf  and 
Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  he  does  not.1 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah's  first  view,  if  the  mudarib 
passes  the  'ashir  with  trade  stock  (mal  mudarabah),  the 
'ashir  collects  zakat  from  it ;  but  according  to  his  later  view, 
the  'ashir  does  not  collect  zakat.  The  later  view  is  also 
shared  by  his  disciples.  Al-Sarakhsi  observes  that  although 
he  does  not  know  whether  Abu  Hanifah  changed  his  view 
concerning  the  case  of  the  slave  who  was  allowed  by  his 
master  to  trade,  the  analogy  of  the  mudarib  would  lead  one 
to  expect  that  Abu  Hanifah  would  exempt  the  slave  also. 
The  ground  for  the  first  view,  according  to  which  the  mu- 
darib is  subject  to  zakat ,  is  that  he  has  rights  in  the  trade 
stock  like  those  of  a  proprietor,  since  he  has  a  share  in  the 
profit.  The  ground  for  the  other  view  is  that  he  is  a  trustee 
concerning  the  trade  stock  which  belongs  to  the  principal 
(rabb  al-mal)  and  that  although  he  has  the  right  to  trade 
in  it  he  does  not  have  authority  to  settle  its  zakat ,  especially 
as  the  settlement  of  zakat  to  be  valid  must  be  accompanied 

1  Mabstt,  p.  201 ;  cf.  Al-Jami'  al-Sagir,  p.  21. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     323 

by  intention.  The  slave,  however,  trades  in  the  stock  for 
his  own  proper  benefit  and  differs  from  the  mudarib  by 
virtually  owning  his  profits. 

In  regard  to  'ashirs,  the  members  of  the  Taglib  tribe  are 
like  the  dhimmis. 

SECTION  III 

The  Discharge  of  the  Zakat  Obligation  (General)  l 
The  condition  determining  the  validity  (sihhah)  of  the 
payment  of  zakat  is  that  the  payment  be  coupled  with  the 
intention  that  it  is  to  discharge  the  sakat  rather  than 
some  other  obligation.  For  zakat  is  an  act  of  worship  and 
as  such  is  not  valid  unless  so  intended.  The  intention  may 

1  The  distinction  between  zakdt  as  a  predominantly  religious  obliga- 
tion and  zakdt  as  a  predominantly  political  obligation  must  always  be 
borne  in  mind.  The  Mohammedan  doctors,  when  they  want  to  refer 
to  the  settlement  of  the  zakdt  as  an  obligation  to  God  as  distinct  from 
that  to  the  state,  use  the  word  ajzd',  which  means  "  to  satisfy,"  "  to 
serve  instead  of."  This  word  has  been  rendered  by  the  English  "dis- 
charge." It  is  only  when  settlement  of  zakdt  as  an  obligation  to  the 
state  is  accompanied  by  its  discharge  as  an  obligation  to  God  that  the 
zakdt  payer  earns  religious  merit  (thawdb).  While  the  payment  of 
sdkat  to  the  state  collector  carries  with  it  normally  also  its  discharge 
as  a  religious  obligation,  this  by  no  means  always  follows.  Thus,  al- 
though the  payment  of  zakdt  to  tyrannical  governments  frees  the  zakdt 
payer  from  the  political  obligation,  in  the  opinion  of  some  doctors  it 
does  not  carry  with  it  the  "discharge"  of  the  zakdt,  which  should 
therefore  be  paid  over  again  by  the  owners  directly  to  the  proper 
beneficiaries  secretly  if  they  are  to  be  freed  from  the  religious  obli- 
gation also.  The  doctors  indicate  when  the  two  obligations  do  not  go 
together,  and  when  they  fail  to  do  so  it  may  be  presumed  that  they 
coincide.  The  question  of  the  discharge  of  the  zakdt  obligation  acquires 
special  significance  when  the  zakdt  may  be  and  is  disbursed  to  its 
beneficiaries  directly  by  the  owners,  since  in  such  cases  the  political 
obligation  is  not  present  and  the  "discharge"  of  the  zakdt  obligation 
is  the  only  point  at  issue.  The  first  two  sections  of  this  chapter  re- 
late chiefly  to  the  settlement  of  the  political  obligation,  while  the  last 
three,  particularly  the  last  two,  sections  concern  chiefly  the  "discharge" 
of  the  religious  obligation. 


324  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

accompany  the  act  of  payment,  whether  it  be  made  to  the 
zakat  payer's  agent  (in  order  to  be  paid  by  him  to  the 
poor)  or  directly  to  the  poor  themselves.  The  intention 
may  also  follow  the  act  of  payment,  provided  it  be  made 
while  yet  the  property  remains  intact  in  the  hands  of  the 
poor.  If,  however,  the  property  had  been  destroyed  in  the 
hands  of  the  poor  before  the  zakat  payer  intended  it  for 
the  settlement  of  his  zakat  debt,  his  zakat  debt  is  not  dis- 
charged and  the  amount  has  to  be  paid  over  again.  Finally, 
the  intention  may  accompany,  instead  of  the  actul  payment 
of  zakat j  its  setting  apart  from  the  nisab  by  the  property 
owner  for  its  future  payment.  Thus  if  one  sets  apart  from 
his  nisab  on  which  a  year's  zakat  falls  due,  an  amount  equal 
to  the  zakat  intending  it  for  such,  and  later  pays  it  to  a  poor 
person  without  intending  it  again  at  the  time,  the  zakat  debt 
is  discharged. 

The  generally  accepted  view  is  that  it  is  not  necessary 
for  the  discharge  of  the  zakat  debt,  that  a  poor  person 
should  know  that  what  was  given  him  was  intended  for 
zakat.  If  therefore  one  should  give  a  poor  person  money 
as  a  present  or  a  loan,  but  intend  it  for  zakat,  the  zakat  debt 
is  duly  discharged.  According  to  the  Fatawa  'Ali  Efendi,1 
in  giving  the  zakat  it  is  preferable  to  do  it  in  public  (izhftr) , 
unlike  alms  (tatawwuc),  which  should  preferably  be  given 
in  secret. 

If  one  should  give  the  poor  as  alms  (sadaqah)  the  whole 
of  the  nisab  without  intending  it  for  the  discharge  of  his 
zakat,  the  zakat  is  nevertheless  discharged.  Although  it  is 
necessary  that  the  intention  of  zakat  should  be  present,  and 
although  analogy  requires  that  the  part  of  the  nisab  in- 
tended for  the  zakat  debt  should  be  specified,  the  act  is 
valid,  judging  by  istihsan.  In  fact,  intention  is  essential 

1  P.  14. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT      325 

in  order  to  distinguish  an  act  of  piety  from  an  habitual 
act,  and  in  the  giving  of  alms  there  is  already  an  intention 
of  obtaining  the  divine  good  will.  The  requirement  that 
the  property  given  in  settlement  of  zakat  must  be  definitely 
known  is,  on  the  other  hand,  met,  in  that  the  portion  in- 
tended for  zakat  is  defined  through  the  fact  that  the  entire 
nisab  (which  includes  the  zakat)  has  been  defined.  Zufar, 
following  analogy,  held  the  contrary  view;  for  he  argued 
that  inasmuch  as  the  fard  and  the  natt  are  both  sharfah  ob- 
ligations, it  is  necessary  to  specify  whether  it  is  the  fard 
(i.  e.,  the  zakat)  or  the  nod  (i.  e.,  the  alms)  whose  discharge 
is  intended.1 

However,  according  to  Abu  Yusuf,  if  one  should  give 
as  alms  a  part  of  the  nisab,  that  part's  share  of  the  zakat  is 
not  discharged,  because  there  is  no  sign  that  the  part  given 
is  intended  to  include  its  share  of  the  zakat,  in  view  of  the 
fact  that  the  entire  zakat  may  be  settled  from  the  remain- 
ing part  and  that  it  cannot  therefore  be  known  how  much 
of  the  debt  was  intended  to  be  settled  in  the  part  given. 
According  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  the  zakat  of  the 
part  given  as  alms  is  included  in  it  and  discharged;  this  is 
because  he  considers  that  the  obligation  of  zakat  is  propor- 
tionately distributed  throughout  the  entire  nisab,  and  that 
when  part  of  it  is  given  as  alms  its  share  of  zakat  is  in- 
cluded and  discharged. 

If,  however,  one  gives  the  nisSb  or  part  of  it,  intending  it 
for  the  settlement  of  some  other  wajib  than  the  zakat,  then 
only  that  wajib  is  discharged,  and  the  zakat  debt  has  to  be 
settled  separately. 

The  Shafiites  and  Malikites  *  alike  require  the  presence 
of  intention  at  the  time  of  setting  apart  ('azl)  one's  zakat 

1  'Indyah,  p.  126. 

'Mintej,  p.  265;  Wajijf,  p.  87;  Umm,  p.  18;  Kharashi,  p.  126. 


326  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

for  future  disbursement  or  of  actually  disbursing  it.  Ac- 
cording to  the  Shafiites,  it  is  not  necessary  in  giving  the 
zakat  to  intend  it  for  the  zakat  of  a  definite  article,  the  zakat 
in  such  case  applying  to  zakat  due  on  any  article.  Ac- 
cording to  the  Malikites,  should  the  part  set  apart  for  zakat 
be  destroyed  before  its  disbursement  to  the  poor,  the  zakat 
debt  is  nevertheless  discharged. 

May  the  intention  of  the  sultan  or  his  agent  replace 
that  of  the  zakat  payer,  when  the  latter,  forced  to  pay 
his  eakat  dues,  fails  to  observe  the  requirement  of  inten- 
tion? The  question  is  answered  differently  by  different 
authorities.  According  to  the  prevalent  Shafiite  view  x  the 
intention  of  the  sultan  or  his  agent  is  sufficient.  The  Mali- 
kite  *  view  is  to  the  same  effect.  According  to  both  schools, 
the  intention  of  the  guardian  replaces  that  of  his  ward  who 
is  a  minor  or  insane. 

Finally,  the  Hanifite  *  views  on  the  matter  are  as  follows : 
According  to  al-Tahawi,  if  the  imam  collects  the  zakat  by 
force  and  disburses  it  to  its  lawful  beneficiaries,  the  zakat 
obligation  is  discharged.  According  to  the  accepted  view, 
(mufta  bih)  in  such  cases  the  zakat  is  discharged  only  as  re- 
gards apparent  property  over  which  the  imam  has  jurisdic- 
tion even  if  he  should  fail  to  disburse  it  to  its  beneficiaries. 
In  the  Khaniyyah  the  validity  of  such  a  view  is  questioned 
on  the  ground  that  intention  is  entirely  absent.  One  doctor 
observes  that  the  zakat  is  not  collected  by  force  but  that  the 
owner  is  told  to  pay  it  of  his  own  will.  The  Durr,  while 
agreeing  with  the  premise  of  the  last  view  remarks  that  the 
difficulty  may  be  avoided  by  forcing  the  cattle  owner, 

1  C/mm,  p.  19;  Minhdj,  p.  265;  Mugni,  p.  403;  Wafts,  p.  87. 

•Kharashi,  p.  130;  Dardir,  p.  128. 

8  B&br,  p.  227 ;  Durr,  p.  137 ;  Shilbi,  p.  257. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     327 

through  imprisonment,  to  pay  his  zakat  of  his  own  accord ; 
for,  it  is  argued,  duress  does  not  preclude  consent.1 

May  the  settlement  of  the  zakat  debt  be  delayed  or  must 
it  be  made  immediately  after  the  zakat  falls  due?  Accord- 
ing to  Abu  '1-Hasan  al-Karkhi  the  property  owner  becomes 
a  sinner  by  delaying  the  settlement  of  his  zakat  debt  It  is 
related  that  according  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  the  per- 
son who  delays  the  settlement  of  his  zakat  debt  without  an 
excuse  is  no  longer  acceptable  as  a  witness.  Muhammad 
made  a  distinction  between  zakat  and  pilgrimage  and  did 
not  allow  delay  in  zakat  because  in  doing  so  the  rights  of 
the  poor  would  be  encroached  upon.  On  the  other  hand, 
according  to  Abu  'Abdallah  al-Balkhi,  it  is  permissible  to  de- 
lay the  payment  of  zakat,  because  the  divine  commandment 
concerning  the  giving  of  zakat  is  indefinite  as  to  time  limit 
(mutlaq).  According  to  a  report  from  Hisham,  Abu  Yusuf 
held  the  same  opinion  on  the  ground  that  while  pilgrimage 
must  be  rendered  at  a  certain  season  and  one  may  not  know 
whether  he  shall  live  until  the  next  season,  by  the  delay  of 
zakat  no  harm  is  done  because  any  time  is  fit  for  its  dis- 
charge.2 

It  is  stated  in  the  Ma/wo'/  however,  that  according  to 
the  opinion  at  present  generally  accepted  the  immediate 
(faivr)  settlement  of  the  zakat  is  necessary.  By  immediate 
settlement  is  meant  that  the  obligation  must  be  settled  at  the 
earliest  opportunity. 

According  to  the  Shafiites,4  the  zakat  must  be  disbursed 

1  The  doctors  arc  concerned  about  the  discharge  of  the  sakdt  obliga- 
tion because,  unless  it  is  discharged,  the  amount  collected  would  not 
be  the  zakdt,  and  the  state  would  have  confiscated  a  Moslem's  prop- 
erty without  just  cause. 

1  Mabstt,  p.  169. 

1  P.  157- 

*  Minhdj,  p.  264 ;  Wajis,  p.  87. 


328  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

to  its  beneficiaries  as  soon  as  possible  (tamakkun).  Accord- 
ing to  al-Shafi'i,1  the  settlement  of  zakat  is  considered  pos- 
sible (tamakkun  min  al-ada')  if  the  owner  can  actually  dis- 
burse it  to  the  collector  or  the  zakat  beneficiaries,  or,  as  the 
Minhaj  puts  it,  if  the  property  and  the  beneficiaries  or  the 
collector  are  present,  provided,  according  to  the  Mugni,  that 
the  owner  is  not  occupied  with  an  important  religious  or 
worldly  function,  such  as  prayer  or  eating,  respectively. 
If  only  one  beneficiary  is  on  hand,  he  is  given  his  particular 
share,  and  is  not  made  to  wait  until  the  required  number  of 
beneficiaries  has  appeared.  According  to  the  Wajiz  one 
does  not  commit  sin  by  delaying  disbursement  in  order  to 
disburse  his  zakat  to  a  more  deserving  person  or  to  his  kin, 
but  if  the  property  meanwhile  should  be  destroyed  he  makes 
good  the  zakat.  In  the  case  of  property  situated  elsewhere, 
the  disbursement  of  zakat  is  considered  to  have  been  "  pos- 
sible "  as  soon  as  a  time  long  enough  to  reach  the  property 
in  question  elapses.  The  Malikite  z  view  is  analogous. 

May  the  zakat  debt  be  settled  before  it  has  yet  become 
due  (ta'jil)?  According  to  the  Hanifites  this  is  allowed. 
According  to  Malik,  however,  an  obligation  may  not  be 
settled  before  it  has  fallen  due.  According  to  the  preva- 
lent Malikite  doctrine,8  although  anticipation  is  abominable, 
it  is  nevertheless  allowed  as  regards  cattle,  gold  and  silver, 
and,  with  respect  to  professional  traders  (mudlr)  only, 
also  in  trade  articles  before  their  sale,  and  debts  before 
their  receipt,  provided  the  debts  have  not  arisen  from 
loans.  Such  anticipation  may  not,  however,  be  by  over  a 
month.  Al-Sarakhsi,  in  support  of  the  Hanifite  view,  in- 
vokes the  example  of  the  Prophet  who  received  in  advance 

1  Umm,  p.  44;  cf.  Minhaj,  p.  264;  Wajiz,  p.  89;  Mugni,  p.  401. 
"  Kharashi,  p.  126. 
•  Kharashi,  p.  128. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT      329 

from  al-'  Abbas  the  zakat  of  two  years,  and  argues  that 
the  sakat  is  due  when  there  is  a  productive  nisab,  and 
that  the  lapse  of  the  year  is  only  in  order  to  give  time  for 
the  payment  of  the  debt  and  may  be  disregarded  without 
affecting  the  obligation.  However,  it  is  not  allowed  to  an- 
ticipate the  payment  of  the  zak&t  if  there  is  not  already  a 
complete  nisab.  According  to  al-Shafi'i,  anticipation  of 
sakat  is  allowed  only  for  one  year.  According  to  Zufar, 
anticipation  of  zakat  for  more  than  one  nisab  is  not  allowed, 
though  it  may  be  allowed  for  more  than  one  year.  If  after 
the  anticipation  of  the  zakat  it  turns  out  that  at  the  end  of 
the  year  the  amount  anticipated  does  not  fall  due,  according 
to  al-Sarakhsi  the  zakat  receiver  may  not  be  forced  to  return 
the  part  that  has  not  fallen  due.  According  to  al-Shafi'i,  if 
at  the  time  of  discharge  it  was  made  clear  to  him  that  he 
would  have  to  reimburse  such  part  of  the  sakdt  as  would 
not  have  fallen  due  at  the  end  of  the  year,  it  may  be  taken 
from  him;  otherwise  the  taxpayer  has  no  right  to  demand 
restitution  of  the  sakdt  paid.  Al-Sarakhsi  remarks  that 
zakat  is  paid  to  the  poor  as  an  offering  to  God  and  may  not 
be  reclaimed  afterwards.1 

The  conditions  necessary  for  the  anticipation  of  zakat 
are  summarized  in  the  'Alamkiriyyah*  as  follows:  (i)  At 
the  time  of  anticipation  the  year  should  have  already  begun 
to  run  on  at  least  one  complete  nisab.  (2)  The  nisab  or 
nisabs  for  which  the  zakat  has  been  anticipated  must  be 
complete  at  the  end  of  the  year.  (3)  The  original  nisab 
should  not  disappear  entirely  in  the  interval.  An  example 
of  anticipation  for  one  year  for  many  nisabs  would  be  the 
payment  in  advance  of  zakat  for  one  thousand  dirhams  for 
one  year  by  one  having  two  hundred  dirhams.  If  this  per- 


tt,  PP.  176-8;  cf.  Umm,  p.  17;  Minhaj,  p.  266;  Waji*.  p.  87. 
'  P.  247. 


330  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

son  in  the  course  of  the  year  acquired  more  wealth  or  made 
profits  so  that  at  the  completion  of  the  year  he  was  pos- 
sessed of  one  thousand  dirhams,  the  anticipation  would  be 
valid  and  the  zakat  of  the  one  thousand  dirhams  for  the 
year  past  discharged.  If,  on  the  contrary,  at  the  comple- 
tion of  the  year  he  was  still  possessed  of  two  hundred  dir- 
hams only,  the  anticipation  would  not  be  valid,  and  should 
he  acquire  more  money  after  the  year,  he  would  have  to  pay 
its  zakat  when  a  year  passed  after  its  acquisition.  If  one 
should  pay  in  advance  zakat  for  two  thousand  dirhams 
while  he  possessed  only  one  thousand  and  intended  the  ad- 
ditional zakat  of  one  thousand  dirhams  for  the  second  one 
thousand  dirhams  he  would  come  by  during  the  year  or, 
failing  that,  for  the  zakat  of  the  original  one  thousand  dir- 
hams for  a  second  year,  it  would  be  valid. 

The  anticipation  of  tithe  is  not  allowed  with  respect 
to  what  has  not  yet  been  sown,  or  to  fruits  that  have 
not  yet  appeared.  Abu  Yusuf,  contrary  to  Abu  Hanl- 
fah  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  allows  anticipation  in 
fruits  whose  pollen  has  not  appeared  (qabl  zuhur  al-tal'), 
and  crops  which  have  not  grown  (qabl  al-nabat).  Abu 
Yusuf's  ground  is  that  the  fruits  and  the  crops  will  grow 
of  themselves  by  mere  lapse  of  time.  The  argument  of 
the  others  is  that  anticipation  is  not  valid  unless  the  cause 
(sabab)  of  tithe  is  present,  but  that  the  palmtrees,  for 
instance,  evidently  are  not  the  cause  of  tithe,  for  the  owner 
may  cut  them  down  without  incurring  responsibility  for  the 
tithe.  The  anticipation  of  the  tithe  of  what  has  not  yet 
been  sown  is,  however,  unanimously  held  to  be  void,  because 
land,  in  and  of  itself,  is  not  the  cause  of  tithe,  but  a  special 
act  is  needed,  namely,  cultivation,  before  there  may  be  any 
question  of  tithe.1 

lMabs&t,  part  iii,  p.  n;  ' Alamkiriyyah,  p.  261. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     33! 

According  to  the  Shafiites,1  anticipation  is  not  allowed 
before  the  fruits  have  ripened  or  the  grains  have  hardened. 
Some  Shafiites  express  the  opinion  that  anticipation  is  al- 
lowable after  the  grains  have  appeared  and  before  they  have 
as  yet  hardened.  Still  others,  with  respect  to  grapes  and 
dates,  hold  that  anticipation  is  not  allowable  before  they 
have  been  dried;  this  view  apparently  is  preferred  by  al- 
Gazzali,  who  mentions  it  first,  if  one  might  so  infer  from 
the  analogy  of  the  Hanifite  usage.  According  to  the  Mali- 
kites,  anticipation  in  fruits  and  crops  is  not  allowed.2 

In  the  settlement  of  the  sakat  debt  the  substitution  of 
values  (daf  al-qiyam)  is  allowed.  Thus  one  may  pay  three 
fat  sheep  instead  of  four  medium-sized  ones  or  pay,  instead 
of  bushels  of  wheat,  their  value  in  dirhams.  Al-Shaf?i 
holds  that  this  is  not  lawful  because  it  would  result  in  the 
setting  aside  of  the  express  shari'ah  prescription  (nass)* 
Consequently  he  does  not  allow  substitution  so  long  as 
it  is  possible  to  pay  the  very  thing  due  as  zakat.  Accord- 
ing to  the  Malikites,  substitution  of  values,  except  as  be- 
tween gold  and  silver,  is  unlawful.4  The  Path,6  in  reply 
to  al-Shafi'i,  says  that  the  cause  of  the  divine  prescription 
(nass)  is  the  desire  to  provide  for  the  poor  the  sustenance 
(rizq)  promised  them  by  God.  Indeed,  the  Almighty 
promised  a  sustenance  to  every  one,  but  he  gave  to  some 
the  means  of  acquiring  it,  such  as  trade,  while  he  de- 
prived others  of  all  means;  accordingly  he  commanded 
the  rich  to  give  them  from  God's  property  a  certain  propor- 
tion as  sakat.  Since  this  is  the  cause  of  the  prescription  and 

lMinhdj,  pp.  266-7;  Wajiz,  p.  87. 

'Kharashi,  p.  128. 

*  Hiddyah,  p.  144 ;  Mojmo',  p.  166. 

*Hiddyah,  p.  144;  Majma',  p.  166;  Umm,  p.  19. 

4  Kharashi,  p.  125. 

8P.  144. 


332  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  kinds  of  property  specified  for  payment  as  zakat  by  no 
means  exhaust  the  needs  of  the  poor,  the  specifications  of 
the  shari'ah  are  interpreted  in  a  liberal  way,  and  the  payment 
of  the  value  is  considered  as  the  main  object  in  view.  It  is 
not  therefore  a  setting  aside  of  the  divine  prescription 
(nass)  by  the  process  of  ta'lil  for  purposes  of  analogy,  as 
some  have  claimed,  but  on  the  contrary  if  it  is  at  all  a  case 
of  analogy,  it  is  one  of  establishing  by  analogy  all  the  var- 
ious implied  prescriptions  (nass)  in  regard  to  the  divine 
promise  to  provide  a  sustenance  to  every  poor  man;  there- 
fore it  is  only  a  case  of  setting  aside  the  construction  that  the 
divine  prescription  regarding  the  payment  as  zakat  of  cer- 
tain definite  animals  precludes  the  payment  of  their  values. 
The  Hanifite  construction  then,  instead  of  being  a  case  of 
analogy,  is  merely  one  of  interpretation  (madlul)  of  the  di- 
vine prescription.  Indeed,  this  construction  is  suggested 
by  the  context  of  the  divine  prescription.  Consequently 
the  value  of  the  identical  thing  due  as  zakat  is  not  a  substi- 
tute (badal)  for  that  thing  (asl) — since  in  that  case  the  sub- 
stitute could  be  paid  only  when  the  original  thing  was  not 
in  existence, — but  both  the  original  thing  and  its  value  are 
equally  obligatory.  The  zakat  payer  therefore  has  the 
option  between  four  things:  ( i )  He  may  pay  the  very  thing 
due  as  zakat,  e.  g.,  the  sheep  or  wheat.  Or,  even  if  he 
should  possess  the  very  thing  due,  he  may  pay  its  value  in 
one  of  the  following  three  ways:  (2)  He  may  pay  an  older 
animal  and  be  reimbursed  by  the  collector  for  the  difference. 
(3)  He  may  pay  a  younger  animal  and  make  up  the  differ- 
ence to  the  collector.  (4)  Finally,  he  may  pay  the  exact 
equivalent  of  the  thing  due  as  zakat ;  for  instance,  he  may 
pay  three  fat  sheep  in  lieu  of  four  middle-sized  ones,  or 
their  value  in  money. 

It  must  be  pointed  out  that  when  the  zakat  debt  is  paid 
in  terms  of  an  equivalent  the  latter  may  not  differ  from  the 


• 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     333 

original  debt  in  quantity  in  order  to  allow  for  a  difference 
in  quality  between  them,  if  they  are  fungible  (mithli)  goods 
of  one  and  the  same  genus.1  For  example,  it  is  not  allowed 
to  pay,  in  settlement  of  a  zakat  debt  of  four  bushels  of 
wheat  of  medium  quality,  three  bushels  of  good  quality ;  or 
to  give,  in  lieu  of  two  dresses  of  inferior  quality,  one  dress 
of  better  quality,  although  the  three  bushels  of  good  wheat 
may  be  worth  the  four  bushels  of  inferior  quality,  or  the 
one  superior  dress  may  be  worth  the  two  inferior  ones. 
The  reason  for  this  is  that  when  articles  subject  to  the  pro- 
hibition of  usury  are  exchanged  for  one  another,  no  allow- 
ance may  be  made  for  a  difference  in  quality  between  them 
if  they  are  both  of  the  same  genus.  Such  articles  are  ex- 
changed in  equal  amounts  only.  Zufar  held  the  opposite 
view,  arguing  that  the  prohibition  of  usury  applies  only  as 
between  man  and  man,  not  God  and  man,  as  is  the  case  in 
zakat. 

While  the  zakat  payer  has  the  four  options  mentioned, 
the  collector  may  nevertheless  refuse  to  accept  the  second 
alternative,  namely,  that  of  being  paid  more  than  the 
zakat  and  of  reimbursing  the  difference,  but  he  may  not 
refuse  the  other  three.  According  to  the  author  of  the 
Bada'i'?  the  collector  may  refuse  only  when  the  zakat  payer 
offers  in  payment  of  his  zakat  debt  a  fraction  of  an  article, 
for  instance,  a  part  of  a  hiqqah,  instead  of  a  bint  labiin. 
Others  say  that  the  above  four  options  belong  to  the  col- 
lector, but  this  view  is  not  generally  accepted. 

According  to  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan, 
when  the  zakat  payer  pays  the  value,  instead  of  the  very 
thing  due  as  zakat,  he  pays  its  value  on  the  day  of  pay- 
ment,8 but  according  to  Abu  Hanlfah,  he  pays  its  value  on 

1  Mabsat,  p.  203;  fdmf,  p.  313.  *  Majma',  p.  166. 

s  Cf.  Kharashi,  p.  125. 


334  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  day  on  which  the  zakat  fell  due  (yawm  al-wujub). 
Other  canonists  hold  that  in  the  case  of  sawaim  animals  one 
may  pay  the  animal  itself  or  its  value  on  the  day  of  pay- 
ment, and  in  the  case  of  other  than  sawa'im  animals,  the 
thing  itself  or  its  value  on  the  day  on  which  the  zakat  fell 
due.  However,  when  one  settles  in  any  of  these  ways,  he 
may  no  longer  change  to  another,  e.  g.,  in  paying  the  zakat 
of  two  hundred  measures  of  wheat  worth  two  hundred  dir- 
hams  on  the  day  of  wujub  (that  is,  when  the  zakat  fell  due) 
the  owner  may  give  five  measures  of  wheat,  and  this  is  not 
controverted,  or  according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  he  may  give 
five  dirhams  instead,  even  if  the  price  of  wheat  should 
meanwhile  have  changed,  but  according  to  his  two  disciples, 
if  the  price  on  the  day  of  settlement  should  be  four  hun- 
dred dirhams,  he  pays  ten  dirhams.  The  same  is  true  of 
the  sawa'im  animals.1 

If  the  property  on  which  zakat  fell  due  is  dayn,  as  dis- 
tinguished from  'ayn*  its  zakat  may  be  settled  in  terms  of 
'ayn  wealth.  Thus  a  person  having  a  claim  of  two  hundred 
dirhams  on  which  zakat  is  due,  may  give,  in  settlement  of 
the  same,  five  dirhams  in  cash,  because  dayn  as  compared 
with  'ayn  is  defective  (naqis)  and  the  (ayn  is  complete 

lJdm?,  p.  313. 

2  Dayn  means  wealth,  the  payment  of  which  attaches  as  a  liability  to  a 
legal  person  (dhimmah),  as  the  result  of  a  transaction  ('agrf)  or  a  loan, 
or  as  damages  for  property  destroyed  (istihldk).  Dayn  by  extension 
also  means  the  class  of  goods  called  mithli  (fungible)  ;  that  is,  goods 
whose  price  (thatnan)  in  sale  is  determined  on  the  basis  of  weight 
(wazn),  or  volume  (kayl),  or  number  ('adad),  and  among  the  various 
units  of  which  there  is  no  difference  of  value  due  to  human  art  (Tech. 
Diet.,  pp.  502,  1343).  The  definition  of  dayn  given  in  the  Majallah  (art. 
158)  in  a  way  combines  these  two  meanings.  According  to  it,  a  stated 
portion  of  a  heap  of  wheat  is  dayn  before  it  has  been  set  off.  'Ayn  is 
the  opposite  of  dayn  in  the  last  sense,  meaning  that  which  is  definite 
and  has  a  bodily  existence.  Thus,  in  the  above  example,  the  said  por- 
tion becomes  'ayn  by  being  set  off. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     335 

(kftmil),  and  the  settlement  of  the  defective  in  terms  of  the 
complete  is  valid.  On  the  contrary,  the  settlement  of  the 
complete  'ayn  in  terms  of  the  defective  dayn  is  not  valid, 
and,  therefore,  the  zakat  debt  is  not  discharged  if  a  person 
wants  to  pay  the  zakat  of  two  hundred  dirhams  which  he 
possesses  (*.  e.,  'ayn)  in  terms  of  the  five  dirhams  which  a 
poor  person  owes  him  (i.  e.,  the  dayn)  ;  namely,  by  absolv- 
ing him  from  the  debt  intending  it  for  his  own  zakat  debt 
on  the  two  hundred  dirhams.  Finally,  as  regards  the  settle- 
ment of  the  zakat  of  dayn  wealth  in  terms  of  dayn  wealth, 
if  the  wealth  on  which  zakat  is  due  is  of  the  kind  of  dayn 
which  becomes  fayn  it  is  not  valid;  otherwise  it  is  valid. 
Thus  if  a  person  has  five  dirhams  owed  him  by  a  poor  per- 
son and  two  hundred  dirhams  by  another  person,  he  cannot 
settle  the  zakat  of  the  two  hundred  by  making  a  present  of 
the  five  to  the  debtor  as  alms,  because  the  two  hundred  dir- 
hams will  become  (ayn  when  collected,  and  the  settlement 
of  the  zakat  of  'ayn  wealth  in  terms  of  dayn  is  not  valid. 
An  example  of  the  opposite  case  would  be  that  of  a  person 
who  wanted  to  settle  the  zakat  of  two  hundred  dirhams 
owed  him  by  another  by  making  a  present  of  those  dir- 
hams to  the  debtor  and  intending  it  for  his  zakat  debt. 
However,  this  is  allowed  only  in  case  the  debtor  is  a  poor 
person,  although  there  is  also  a  view  to  the  contrary.  It 
goes  without  saying  that  the  zakat  of  {ayn  wealth  is  dis- 
charged if  paid  in  terms  of  fayn  wealth;  if,  for  instance, 
one  pays  the  zakat  of  two  hundred  dirhams  he  possesses  by 
paying  five  out  of  those  two  hundred.1 

If  the  rebels  and  schismatics,  i.  e.,  Moslems  who  refuse 
to  acknowledge  the  authority  of  the  imam,  collect  once  from 
the  Moslems  the  zakat  of  their  sautfim  animals,  or  the 
tithe,  neither  is  collected  again  from  the  owners  by  the 

1  Kasani,  pp.  42-3. 


336  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

imam  when  he  recovers  control  over  them.  This  is  because 
taxation  is  based  on  protection  and  in  this  instance  the 
imam  has  failed  to  protect  them.  However,  a  person  taxed 
by  the  'ashir  of  the  rebels  once  is  taxed  again  by  the  'ashir 
of  the  Moslems,  for  it  was  his  own  fault,  and  not  that  of 
the  imam}  to  have  passed  the  'ashir  of  the  rebels.1  Accord- 
ing to  the  Majma'  the  taxes  are  not  collected  by  the  imam 
even  if  the  rebels  had  not  collected  them.  However  if  the 
zakat  taxes  collected  by  the  rebels  have  not  been  disbursed 
by  them  to  their  lawful  beneficiaries,  the  property  owners, 
as  between  them  and  God,  should  repeat  their  zakat  dues  by 
paying  them  secretly  to  the  poor.  In  one  opinion  of  the 
matter,  the  zakat  and  the  tithe  obligations  are  discharged 
even  if  the  proceeds  have  not  been  disbursed  to  their  lawful 
beneficiaries  because  in  that  case  the  sin  belongs  to  the 
authorities.2 

Some  express  the  view  that  zakat  paid  to  rebels  and  in 
general  to  any  tyrannical  person,  if  paid  with  the  intention 
of  zakat,  is  discharged  also  as  between  God  and  man  and 
therefore  need  not  be  paid  again  by  the  owners.  It  is  argued 
that  the  rebels  and  tyrants  are  in  reality  poor  in  view  of 
the  fact  that  they  would  be  reduced  to  poverty  if  they 
restored  the  properties  which  they  seized  unjustly,  and 
that  the  zakat  after  all  has  been  paid  to  its  lawful  bene- 
ficiaries.3 The  author  of  the  Hidayah,  however,  expresses 

1  Majma',  p.  173. 

*  Majma',  p.  167 ;  Hiddyah,  'Indyah,  and  Fat h,  p.  150 ;  Kasani,  p.  36. 

8  The  Hanifite  doctors  (Kasani,  p.  36;  Path,  p.  151)  in  this  connec- 
tion cite  a  certain  fatwa  according  to  which  it  was  declared  lawful  to 
pay  the  zakdt  to  'AH  Ibn  'Isa,  a  governor  of  Khurasan,  on  the  ground 
that  if  he  offered  damages  for  the  many  injustices  he  had  committed 
he  would  be  a  poor  man.  The  case  of  a  governor  of  Balkh  is  even 
more  interesting.  This  governor  having  committed  perjury,  had  to 
offer  expiation  (kaffdrah').  A  fatwa  was  given  that  in  his  case  the 
expiation  should  consist  in  fasting.  Thereupon  the  governor  is  said  to 
have  begun  crying,  saying  to  his  attendants :  "They  tell  me :  '  What  you 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT      337 

the  view  that  the  zakat  should  be  repeated  even  if  the  taxes 
paid  were  intended  for  it.  According  to  the  Path,  this  is 
necessary  because  the  person  who  collects  the  sakat  should 
know  why  he  is  collecting  it,  or,  perhaps,  because  the  zakat 
has  not  been  disbursed  to  its  lawful  beneficiaries. 

In  the  Durr  l  it  is  stated  that  there  is  a  dispute  as  to 
whether  the  above  applies  to  the  zakat  of  non-apparent 
property  as  well;  the  view  recommended  in  the  Mobs  fit 
being  that  they  are  alike.  This  is  also  the  view  expressed 
in  the  'Inayah.  In  the  Fatawa  'AH  Efendi,2  it  is  stated  that 
the  custom  duties  paid  nowadays  by  Moslem  traders  cancel 
the  zakat  dues  of  the  latter  if  they  are  intended  by  them  for 
those  dues. 

According  to  al-Haytami,3  to  the  question  whether  the 
zakat  obligation  is  discharged  in  case  the  imam  seizes 
property  unjustly  and  the  owner  intends  it  for  his  zakat 
dues,  the  reply  is  made  that  the  obligation  is  discharged  if 
the  imam  knew  his  intention.  It  is  added,  however,  that  in 
case  the  zakat  is  collected  by  other  than  the  imam  it  is  not 
necessary  that  the  latter  should  know  the  intention  of  the 
owner.  With  regard  to  the  imposts  (mukus)  of  later 
Moslem  states,  al-Haytami  says  that  they  constitute  a  pay- 
ment of  zakat  only  if  they  are  collected  under  the  name  of 
zakat  and  intended  by  the  owners  for  their  zakat  dues; 
that  consequently  the  so-called  'ushur  taxes  of  later  times 
are  in  reality  extrz-sharfah  taxes  (mukus),  and  do  not  re- 
owe  [before  God]  in  the  way  of  restoration  [for  injustice  committed] 
is  more  than  what  you  own,  and  therefore  your  expiation  (kaffdroh) 
is  that  of  a  person  who  owns  nothing."'  (According  to  the  law,  the 
expiation  for  perjury  for  people  who  have  the  means  is  to  free  a  slave 
or  to  feed  or  clothe  ten  poor  persons;  on  the  contrary,  for  those  who 
cannot  afford  this,  it  consists  in  fasting  for  three  consecutive  days.  Cf. 
Durar,  p.  335.) 

1  P.  137-  "  P-  J5- 

3  Al-Fatdiva  al-Kubra,  vol.  ii,  p.  48. 


338 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


suit  in  the  discharge  of  the  zakat  obligation  even  if  so  in- 
tended. 

According  to  al-Mawardi,1  if  the  zakat  collector  is  tyran= 
nical  in  collecting  the  sadaqah  but  just  in  disbursing  it, 
the  zakat  obligation  is  discharged  when  the  zakat  is  given 
to  him.  Conversely,  if  he  is  just  in  collecting  it  but  unjust 
in  disbursing  it,  the  obligation  is  not  discharged  as  between 
God  and  the  owner — whether  the  collector  collects  the  zakat 
by  the  consent  of  the  owner  or  whether  he  collects  it  by 
force.  In  such  case  the  owner  must  pay  the  zakat  over 
again  to  its  lawful  beneficiaries.  According  to  the  Mali- 
kites,2  this  applies  only  in  case  the  owner  paid  the  zakat  of 
his  own  accord.  According  to  Malik,  the  obligation  is  dis- 
charged and  the  owner  need  not  repeat  it.& 

According  to  al-ShafVi,4  if  after  the  disbursement  of 
zakat  by  the  public  distributor  (qasim)  to  a  person,  it  ap- 
pears that  such  person  was  not  a  lawful  beneficiary,  the 
zakat  is  taken  back  from  him  to  be  disbursed  to  the  proper 
person,  but  the  zakat  obligation  of  the  owner  remains  dis- 
charged whether  or  not  the  collector  fails  to  take  the  zakat 
back.  In  case  of  failure  the  collector  is  not  liable  for  dam- 
ages because  he  is  only  a  trustee  in  this  matter.  The  Mali- 
kite  5  view  is  similar.  If  in  the  above  case  it  is  the  owner 
himself  who  is  disbursing  the  zakat,  according  to  al-ShafTi, 
in  one  view  of  the  matter,  he  must  take  the  zakat  back  in 
order  to  disburse  it  to  the  right  person,  and  if  he  fails  to  do 
so,  he  must  pay  the  zakat  over  again  to  the  right  person  if 
his  obligation  is  to  be  discharged.  In  the  other  view,  the 

1  Mawardi,  p.  209. 
;*Kharashi,  p.  128. 
*  Cf.  Mudawwanah,  p.  45. 
4  Utnm,  p.  63. 
6  Kharashi,  p.  128 ;  'Adawi,  ibid. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     339 

owner,  too,  like  the  collector,  need  not  repeat  the  zakat;  for 
by  paying  it  to  a  person  whom  he  thought  to  be  a  lawful 
beneficiary  he  has  fulfilled  his  obligation.  The  Malikite 
view  is  again  similar.  Moreover,  according  to  the  Mali- 
kites,  if  a  person  disburses  his  zakat  to  a  person  who  he 
believes  (zann)  is  not  a  beneficiary  of  the  zakat,  and  later 
it  appears  that  he  was  a  beneficiary,  his  obligation  is  dis- 
charged ;  but  the  zakat  payer  becomes  a  sinner  by  having 
paid  his  zakat  to  one  believed  to  be  the  wrong  person.1 

SECTION   IV 

The  Place  of  Intuition  (Taharri)  in  the  Discharge  of  the 
Zakat  Obligation  2 

When  the  zakat  is  disbursed  directly  by  the  zakat  payer 
himself,  rather  than  by  the  state,  the  question  whether  or 
not  the  obligation  is  discharged  depends  on  whether  the 
person  to  whom  the  zakat  was  disbursed  was  a  lawful  bene- 
ficiary of  the  zakat.  If  the  zakat  payer  is  in  doubt  as  to  this 
last  point,  he  may  as  a  precaution  resort  to  his  intuition 
( taharri)  for  determining  it.  In  this  connection  the  follow- 
ing four  cases  are  conceivable : 

( i )  The  zakat  payer  gives  the  zakat  to  a  person,  without 
at  all  doubting  the  latter's  financial  need,  and  without  resort- 
ing to  the  process  of  taharri,  or  asking  some  one  about  it. 
In  this  case  the  zakat  obligation  is  lawfully  discharged 
(ajza)  and  the  payer  is  rewarded  by  God  for  it,  provided  it 
does  not  appear  later  that  the  person  to  whom  the  zakat  was 
given  was  rich.  This  is  because  the  act  of  a  Moslem  is 
construed  to  be  valid  until  the  contrary  appears  to  have 
been  the  case.  Besides,  the  presumption  is  that  the  person 

1  For  the  rules  to  determine  the  right  person  for  disbursing  the  zakat, 
«ee  infra,  under  Expenditure  of  Zakdt  Taxes. 
J  j'absut,  part  x,  p.  186;  'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  v,  p.  s&P- 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

who  received  the  zakat  is  poor,  for  man  is  born  poor  and 
is  assumed  to  remain  so  until  there  is  evidence  to  the  con- 
trary. Consequently,  the  zakat  obligation  is  considered  to 
have  been  discharged  until  it  becomes  evident  that  the  per- 
son who  received  the  zakat  was  rich,  and  in  that  case  the 
zakat  must  be  paid  again. 

(2)  The  zakat  payer  is  seized  with  doubt  concerning  the 
status  of  the  person  to  whom  he  intends  to  pay  his  zakat, 
either  because  that  person  looks  like  a  rich  man  or  because 
the  zakat  payer  inclines  to  the  belief  that  he  is  rich.    How- 
ever, notwithstanding  his  doubts,  he  settles  his  zakat  to 
him.     In  this  case  the  zakat  obligation  is  not  legally  dis- 
charged, because  after  once  doubting  his  poverty,  it  was  the 
duty  of  the  payer  to  turn  to  his  intuition  in  order  to  reach  the 
truth.     Having  failed  to  do  this,  he  has  forfeited  the  privi- 
lege of  presumption  granted  him  by  the  law.     If,  however  he 
finds  out  later  that  the  man  was  poor,  his  payment  of  zakat 
becomes  valid  in  spite  of  the  fact  that  he  omitted  to  resort 
to  taharri.     This  is  because  the  purpose  of  taharri  is  the 
determination  of  truth,  and  when  that  purpose  has  been 
achieved  in  some  other  way  the  obligation  of  taharri  lapses. 

(3)  The  zakat  payer  is  in  doubt  and  to  clear  his  doubts 
resorts  to  the  process  of  taharri.     His  intuition  tells  him 
that  the  man  is  rich,  yet  in  spite  of  it  he  settles  his  zakat  to 
him.     Clearly  in  this  case  the  obligation  is  not  discharged 
and  must  be  fulfilled  over  again,  unless  the  zakat  payer 
finds  out  that  the  man  was  really  poor,  in  which  case  he 
need  not  pay  the  zakat  over  again.    This  is  the  view  gener- 
ally accepted,  although  some  Hanifite  doctors  believe  that 
Abu  Hanifah  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  required  the 
zakat  to  be  repeated. 

(4)  The  zakat  payer  resorts  to  the  process  of  taharri  and 
the  conviction  dawns  upon  him  that  the  person  is  poor,  and 
thereupon  he  pays  the  zakat  to  him.    It  is  considered  a  case 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     34 x 

of  resort  to  taharri  if  the  taxpayer  without  actually  consult- 
ing his  intuition  pays  his  zakat  to  a  person  sitting  in  line 
with  the  poor,  or  dressed  like  a  poor  man,  or  if  he  gives  his 
zakat  to  one  after  his  begging  for  it.  In  such  cases  whether 
or  not  it  is  later  found  out  that  he  actually  was  poor, 
the  zakat  obligation  is  by  unanimous  opinion  discharged. 
According  to  Abu  Hanlfah  and  Muhammad  the  obligation 
remains  discharged,  even  if  it  later  appears  that  he  was 
rich.  Abu  Yusuf  held  that  the  zakat  must  be  paid 
over  again.  It  is  stated  in  the  ' Alamkiriyyah  that  in  such 
case  the  person  who  received  the  zakat  must  return  it  to  the 
zakat  payer  who,  in  case  the  zakat  is  not  returned,  acquires 
only  the  thawab  of  kindliness  but  not  that  of  sadaqah.  The 
argument  of  Abu  Yusuf  for  dissenting  from  the  others  is 
that  when  later  it  appears  that  the  zakat  receiver  was  rich, 
the  zakat  payer's  previous  intuition  to  the  contrary  patently 
appears  to  have  been  erroneous,  and  may  no  longer  be  taken 
into  account,  and  that  consequently  the  zakat  must  be  paid 
over  again.  Moreover,  the  decision  of  a  case  through  intui- 
tion is  valid  only  in  case  the  rights  of  third  parties  are  not 
involved,  which  is  not  true  in  the  present  case,  the  poor  hav- 
ing a  right  in  the  zakat.  The  others  reply  that  the  zakat 
payer  had  discharged  the  obligation  imposed  on  him  by  the 
sharfah  and  there  is  no  more  ground  for  requiring  a  re- 
petition of  the  zakat f  than  when  nothing  is  discovered 
about  the  zakat  receiver's  status.  In  fact,  the  zakat  payer  is 
obliged  to  pay  his  zakat  to  the  person  who,  in  his  opinion, 
is  poor,  but  this  person  need  not  be  poor  in  reality  also, 
since  that  is  impossible  to  ascertain.  Indeed  one  sometimes 
cannot  tell  his  own  financial  state,  and  how  can  he  be  ex- 
pected to  tell  that  of  others !  Furthermore,  a  shari'ah  obli- 
gation never  exceeds  human  capacity,  and  in  this  case  the 
utmost  the  zakat  payer  can  do  is  to  determine  the  state  of 
the  zakat  receiver  by  means  of  inferences  based  on  his  ap- 


342 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


pearance,  or  the  fact  of  his  sitting  in  line  with  the  poor,  or 
his  begging  for  alms  and  the  like,  or,  if  such  circumstances 
are  not  at  hand,  by  resorting  to  his  intuition,  the  only  re- 
maining means  at  his  disposal.  Besides,  when  later  it  ap- 
pears that  the  zakat  receiver  was  in  reality  rich,  it  is  no 
longer  of  any  avail,  since  by  unanimous  opinion  the  zakat 
payer  may  not  recover  the  zakat  or  its  equivalent  from  the 
zakat  receiver,  and  therefore  it  would  be  entirely  unjust  to 
require  him  to  settle  the  same  obligation  twice  over.  The 
above  applies  also  in  case  the  zakat  receiver  turns  out  to  be 
the  zakat  payer's  father  or  son,  or  according  to  a  Zahir-al- 
riwayah  report,  even  a  Hashimite  or  a  dhimmi.  The  sakat 
likewise  remains  discharged  if  the  sakat  receiver  appears 
to  be  the  slave  or  mukatab  of  a  rich  person.  If  however 
the  sakat  receiver  proves  to  be  the  sakat  payer's  own  slave 
or  mukatab,  by  unanimous  opinion  the  zakat  must  be  paid 
over  again,  since  a  condition  of  zakat  is  that  it  must  be 
"given"  (ifta),  but  this  does  not  happen  until  the  thing 
given  ceases  to  be  the  sakat  payer's  own  property. 

SECTION  v 

The  Use  of  Cunning  in  the  Discharge  of  the  Zakat 
Obligation  x 

According  to  the  Hanifite  doctors,  resort  to  cunning 
(hilah),  in  order  to  invalidate  the  right  of  a  third  person,  or 
to  involve  it  in  doubt  or  confuse  it,  is  unlawful  and  abomi= 
nable,  but  resort  to  cunning  in  order  to  escape  from  engag- 
ing in  an  unlawful  act,  or  in  order  to  be  able  to  do  an  act 
which  is  legitimate  (halal)  is  a  good  deed.  According  to 
Abu  Yusuf,  resort  to  cunning  is  permissible  even  in  order 
merely  to  avoid  incurring  an  obligation  (imtina  'an  al- 

1  'Alamktriyyah,  vol.  vi,  pp.  559-62;  Mabsut,  pp.  166-7:  cf.  part  xxx, 
p.  209;  Majma',  p.  161. 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     343 

wujub)  before  the  obligation  has  been  as  yet  contracted. 
The  use  of  cunning  is  justified  by  the  following  verse  of 
the  Koran : l 

"  Take  in  thy  hand  a  bundle  of  dry  herbs  and  strike 
with  it,  and  do  not  break  an  oath."  This  was  advice  given 
to  Job,  who  had  sworn  that  he  would  beat  his  wife  by  in- 
flicting on  her  a  hundred  stripes.  All  the  Hanifite  doctors 
agree  that  the  tenor  of  the  above  verse  has  not  been  abro- 
gated (naskh)  by  a  later  prescription. 

The  Hanifite  doctors  have  disagreed  as  to  the  legitimacy 
of  resorting  to  cunning  in  order  to  avoid  the  payment  of 
zakat.  According  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  such  a 
practice  is  abominable,  because  it  results  in  the  prejudice  of 
the  poor  and  because  the  giving  of  zakat  is  an  act  of  wor- 
ship and  it  does  not  befit  a  believer  to  try  to  avoid  it.  Abu 
Yusuf,  however,  holds  the  opinion  that  there  is  nothing  to 
condemn  in  such  a  practice  because  it  merely  consists  in  an 
attempt  to  avoid  the  incurring  of  an  obligation,  and  there- 
fore it  does  not  result  in  the  prejudice  of  third  parties,  since 
their  rights  accrue  only  after  the  obligation  has  been  in- 
curred. Moreover,  he  argues,  one  is  sometimes  afraid  that 
he  may  not  be  able  to  carry  out  a  divine  commandment  and 
that  he  may  so  become  a  rebel,  and  in  such  cases  it  is  advis- 
able to  avoid  coming  at  all  under  the  commandment  in 
question,  since  to  avoid  a  sin  is  itself  an  act  of  submission. 
For  instance  one  may  avoid  getting  rich  in  order  to  be  free 
from  the  obligation  of  performing  the  pilgrimage  or  paying 
zakat.  What  is  therefore  blameworthy  is  the  avoiding  of 
zakat  after  it  has  once  been  contracted,  but  not  before  it  has 
as  yet  been  incurred.  •  The  view  of  Muhammad  is  the  one 
generally  accepted. 

The  doctors  are  then  unanimous  in  holding  that  the  zakat 

1  Chap.  38,  verse  43. 


344  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

may  not  be  avoided  after  it  has  once  been  incurred.    Abu 

Yusuf  himself  severely  condemns  1  any  attempt  to  defraud 
the  public  treasury. 

It  is  not  allowed,  [he  says],  to  one  who  believes  in  God  and 
the  Last  Day  to  refuse  the  sadaqah  or  to  alienate  his  prop- 
erty in  favor  of  a  group  of  people  dividing  it  among  them 
in  a  way  that  the  share  each  receives  is  too  little  to  be  sub- 
ject to  zakat,  neither  is  it  allowed  for  any  cause  or  reason 
to  resort  to  cunning  in  order  to  annul  (ibtal)  the  sadaqah. 

He  further  cites  a  report  from  'Abdallah  Ibn  Mas'ud  ac- 
cording to  which  the  person  who  refuses  to  pay  his  zakat 
is  not  a  Moslem  and  is  not  admitted  to  say  prayers  (la  salat 
lahu),  and  the  hadlth  of  Abu  Bakr:  "  If  they  should  refuse 
me  a  halter  ((iqal)  of  what  they  used  to  give  the  Prophet  as 
zak&t,  I  would  indeed  fight  them  when  they  refused  it." 

The  Hanifite  doctors  have  devised  several  ways  in 
which  the  payment  of  zakat  may  be  lawfully  avoided  by 
the  property  owner  before  it  has  as  yet  become  due.  Thus 
if  a  person  owning  two  hundred  dirJiams  desires  to  escape 
paying  zakat  on  them,  the  method  is  to  give  away  as  alms 
one  of  the  two  hundred  dirhams  just  one  day  before  the 
year  has  run  out  in  order  that  the  nisab  may  be  incomplete 
at  the  end  of  the  year.  The  same  end  is  achieved  if,  instead 
of  giving  that  dirham  as  alms,  he  gives  it  as  a  present  to  his 
minor  son,  or  makes  a  present  to  him  of  the  entire  two 
hundred  dirhams,  or  spends  them  on  his  children. 

Again  if  a  person  wants  to  give  alms  to  a  poor  person  by 
giving  up  the  claim  he  has  on  that  poor  person  and  to  count 
the  same  for  his  zakat  dues,  he  may  not  do  so,  because  it  is 
an  established  Hanifite  principle  that  the  zakat  of  a  definite 
article  (eayn)  may  not  be  paid  in  terms  of  a  claim  (dayn), 
neither  may  the  zakat  of  a  claim  be  paid  in  terms  of  a  dif- 

1  Yusuf,  p.  45. 


COLLECTION  AXD  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT     345 


ferent  claim.  The  following  trick,  however,  offers  a  way  out 
of  the  difficulty:  the  creditor  gives  the  poor  an  amount  equal 
to  his  claim  on  him  intending  it  for  the  settlement  of  his 
zakat  debt,  and  then  the  debtor,  after  receiving  the  zakat, 
returns  it  to  the  creditor  in  settlement  of  his  debt  to  him, 
such  procedure  being  lawful.  It  is  stated  in  the  Nawadir 
that  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  when  asked  about  his  opin- 
ion of  this  trick,  answered  that  it  is  preferable  to  pay  one's 
zakat  to  one's  debtor.  In  fact  the  earlier  Hanifite  doctors 
used  to  resort  to  this  trick  in  regard  to  their  insolvent 
debtors.  The  creditor  need  not  be  afraid  that  the  debtor 
after  receiving  the  zakat,  may  refuse  to  give  it  back  in  settle- 
ment of  his  debt,  for  the  creditor  can  easily  extend  his  hand 
to  seize  the  property  of  his  debtor,  if  such  property  hap- 
pens to  be  of  the  same  genus  (jins)  as  the  claim  he  has  on 
him ;  and  should  the  debtor  attempt  to  prevent  him  from  so 
doing,  he  can  enforce  his  point  of  view  by  appealing  to  a 
judge.  Another  way  of  getting  at  the  same  result  is  to  tell 
the  debtor :  "  Name  as  your  agent  one  of  my  servants  in 
order  to  receive  this  as  the  zakat  of  my  property,  and  give 
him  power  to  settle  your  debt  to  me  by  paying  it  back  to 
me."  When  the  agent  receives  the  zakat  it  becomes  the 
property  of  his  principal,  that  is,  the  debtor;  but  being  also 
an  agent  for  the  settlement  of  the  debt  he  pays  the  sum  re- 
ceived back  to  the  zakat  payer.  Shams-al-a'immah  al- 
Halwa'i  (or  al-Halwani)  said  that  when  the  property  owner 
resorts  to  this  trick  it  is  advisable  that  the  sum  given  to 
the  debtor  should  exceed  the  amount  of  the  debt  by  a  little 
margin  so  that  after  the  settlement  of  the  debt  there  will 
still  be  left  something  in  the  hands  of  the  debtor,  and  there- 
fore he  will  not  be  tempted  to  refuse  to  settle  his  debt  after 
receiving  the  money. 

If  the  claim  is  a  joint  claim,  then  the  other  creditor  is  en- 
titled to  his  share  in  the  amount  received  on  account.     In 


346  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

order  to  avoid  this  inconvenience,  one  first  gives  the  debtor  as 
zakat  an  amount  in  cash  equal  to  his  share  of  the  claim.  Then 
he  gives  up  his  share  of  the  claim,  by  making  an  alms  of  it 
to  the  debtor,  whereupon  the  debtor  makes  a  gift  of  the 
cash  received  to  the  creditor,  and  in  this  case  the  other 
creditor  is  not  entitled  to  a  share  in  this  cash,  because  it  has 
not  been  given  in  settlement  of  their  joint  claim/  Another 
way  to  obtain  the  same  result  is  for  the  debtor  to  borrow 
from  another  person  a  sum  equal  to  the  creditor's  share 
in  the  joint  claim,  and  give  it  to  the  creditor  as  a  gift.  The 
creditor  then  returns  it  to  the  debtor  as  his  zakat,  at  the 
same  time  that  he  absolves  the  debtor  from  his  share  of 
the  claim,  and  again  the  other  creditor  cannot  claim  any- 
thing from  the  cash  he  had  received  as  a  gift. 

Cunning  may  be  resorted  to  also  with  respect  to  the 
zakat  of  sawa'im  animals  as  follows:  the  owner  of  the 
sawa'im  animals  exchanges  them  just  one  day  before  the 
completion  of  the  year  for  animals  of  the  same  or  a  differ- 
ent genus,  and  in  such  case  the  year  is  dissolved  and  he  es- 
capes the  zakat.  Or  he  makes  a  present  of  the  animals  to  a 
person  he  trusts  and  after  the  completion  of  the  year  he 
takes  back  his  present,  and  in  such  case  the  year  begins  to 
run  from  the  date  the  gift  has  been  revoked  and  taken  back, 
and  so  the  time  that  has  -passed  before  does  not  count 
against  him  in  reckoning  the  .zakat.  He  may  repeat  the 
same  trick  every  year. 

It  must  be  remembered  that  the  giving  of  zakat  is  valid 
only  if  the  process  involves  a  transfer  of  ownership  (tarn- 
lik)  from  one  person  to  another.  Consequently  the  zakat 
obligation  is  not  discharged  if  a  person  spends  a  certain  sum 
of  money  for  a  public  work  (wujtih  al-birr)  or  the  funeral 
expenses  (takfin)  of  a  poor  person.  The  dodge  here  is  to 
give  the  zakat  to  a  poor  person  and  direct  him  to  spend  it 
for  the  purpose  in  view.  The  consequence  is  that  the  tha- 


COLLECTION  AND  DISCHARGE  OF  THE  ZAKAT 


347 


wab  of  the  zakat  belongs  to  the  zakat  payer  and  that  of  the 
construction  of  the  public  work  or  the  funeral  to  the  poor 
person  who  attended  to  it.  It  must  be  stated  here,  however, 
that  should  the  poor  person,  after  receiving  the  zakat,  refu>e 
to  apply  it  to  the  purpose  for  which  it  was  intended,  the 
zakat  payer  would  have  no  legal  claim  against  him.1 

The  Shafiites,-  likewise,  consider  such  practices  abomi- 
nable *  if  resorted  to  merely  in  order  to  avoid  the  sakat. 
They  do  however  allow  them  if  they  are  necessary,  or  if 
the  intention  of  avoiding  the  zakat  is  only  incidental. 

Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,4  cunning  does  not 
avail  in  freeing  one  from  an  obligation,  either  in  religious 
('ibddat)  or  in  civil  matters  ( mii'&mal&t) .  Thus  if  a  per- 
son just  before  the  end  of  the  year  makes  a  present  of  his 
property  to  his  son  or  slave  or,  as  sometimes  happens,  to 
his  wife,  with  the  intention  of  taking  it  back  after  the  end 
of  the  year  and  so  escaping  the  zakat  of  that  year,  the  zakat 
is  nevertheless  collected  from  him  and  it  is  his  duty  to  pay 
it  of  his  own  accord.  It  is  likewise  futile  to  resort  to  cun- 
ning with  a  view  to  settling  one's  sakat  in  terms  of  one's 
claims,  c.  g.,  by  paying  one's  zakat  to  one's  poor  debtor 
with  the  understanding  that  the  debtor  will  return  the  zakat 
as  a  payment  on  account  of  his  debt.  The  later  Malikites, 
however,  disagree  as  regards  the  case  in  which  the  debtor 
pays  back  the  zakat  of  his  own  accord. 

1  Durr,  p.  145. 

1  An§ari,  p.  353 ;  Mugni,  p.  370. 

*  It  must  be  pointed  out  here  that  the  fact  that  a  practice  is  consid- 
ered abominable  (makrth*)  does  not  detract  from  its  legal  validity.  It 
simply  means  that  a  person  by  committing  it  becomes  a  sinner. 

4  Dardir,  p.  114;  cf.  Kharashi,  pp.  57,  59,  61,  119. 


CHAPTER  IV 

THE   FINANCIAL  CONTRIBUTION   FOR   THE   CONDUCT   OF 
HOLY  WAR  (ju'l)  AND  FOR  OTHER  PUBLIC  PURPOSES 

THE  word  "  ju'l "  literally  means  compensation  for  work 
done,  and,  more  specially,  compensation  for  military  ser- 
vices of  a  substitute,  hence  also,  the  financial  contribution 
levied  by  the  imam  on  Moslems  who  stay  away  from  the  war 
for  the  equipment  of  those  who  join  the  army.  It  is  related 
of  Omar  that  he  equipped  the  bachelors  at  the  expense  of  the 
married,  giving  the  bachelors  the  horses  of  the  married. 
Indeed,  Omar  was  a  man  of  great  executive  ability  and  had 
the  interests  of  the  Moslems  at  heart,  for  he  knew  that  the 
minds  of  married  people,  unlike  those  of  bachelors,  go  back 
to  their  families,  and  that  they  cannot  stay  away  from  them 
for  long.  In  this  way  married  people  were  enabled  to  stay 
with  their  wives  and  protect  them,  and  yet  participate  in 
the  war  by  means  of  their  horses;  and,  on  the  other  hand, 
the  bachelors  participated  in  the  war  in  body.  Some  say 
that  Omar  used  to  do  this  only  with  the  consent  of  the 
persons  concerned,  and  that,  failing  such  consent,  he 
equipped  the  soldiers  from  the  public  funds.  The  proper 
view  however  is  that  the  imam  has  the  right  to  levy  on 
the  people  the  amount  needed  if  there  are  no  available 
funds  (mal)  in  the  public  treasury,  because  the  im&m  is 
entrusted  with  the  interests  of  the  Moslems,  and  if  he 
should  fail  to  equip  an  army  for  their  defence  the  infidels 
would  be  victorious  and  seize  their  properties,  children,  and 
348 


I''I\AKCIAL  CONTRIBUTIONS  349 

lives.  It  is  therefore  only  wise  policy  to  assess  the  people 
of  means  for  raising  the  necessary  funds.1 

This  is  also  the  view  held  by  the  later  Hanifite  doctors.1 
If,  however,  there  are  available  funds  in  the  public  treas- 
ury, then  it  is  abominable  to  levy  this  impost,  since  the 
funds  in  question  are  destined  for  such  purposes.  Some  of 
the  later  doctors,  such  as  the  authors  of  the  Hidayah  and 
the  Durar,  hold  that  it  is  only  abominable  to  levy  the  impost 
in  case  there  are  no  available  funds  in  the  fa'y  treasury, 
but  others  reply  that  if  there  are,  for  instance,  sadaqah 
funds,  it  is  still  abominable  to  levy  the  impost  since  the 
imam  may  finance  the  campaign  by  borrowing  money  from 
the  sadaqah  funds  on  account  of  the  fa'y  treasury. 

Irrespective  of  the  levy  of  such  an  impost  by  the  imam, 
it  is  the  duty  of  every  Moslem  who  has  the  means,  but  can- 
not fight  himself,  to  equip  another  person  who  has  not  the 
means  but  can  fight.  Al-Sarakhsi,  in  support  of  this,  says 
that  the  person  who  is  able  to  fight  needs  a  large  amount 
of  money  to  equip  himself,  and,  on  the  contrary,  the 
wealthy  person  who  cannot  fight  himself  needs  some  one 
to  ward  off  the  evils  of  the  infidels  from  himself  and  his 
property,  and  therefore  there  is  no  harm  in  Moslems'  help- 
ing one  another.  Moreover,  the  wealthy  person  by  giving 
the  poor  fighter  his  equipment  aids  him  in  performing  a 
fard  obligation  (»'.  e.,  the  obligation  of  holy  war)  and  this 
is  a  commendable  act  on  his  part.  If  however  the  fighters 
have  the  means,  then  it  is  not  proper  for  them  to  receive 
such  help,  because  perfection  in  the  performance  of  the 
holy  war  obligation  is  reached  by  participating  in  it  both  in 
person  and  wealth,  and  because  if  he  received  assistance  it 

1  Mabsut,  part  x,  p.  20. 

*Majma',  p.  495;  Bahr,  vol.  v,  p.  79;  Hiddyah,  vol.  v,  p.  194;  Durar, 
p.  165. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

would  be  as  if  he  performed  his  religious  duty  for  a 
pecuniary  reward  (ujrah)^ 

According  to  al-Sugdi,  as  quoted  in  the  Bahr,  if  the  per- 
son who  stays  at  home  (qa'id)  says  to  the  person  who  is 
going  out  to  join  the  war  (shakhis)  :  "  Take  this  property 
and  fight  with  it,"  it  is  not  a  case  of  being  hired  for  fighting 
the  holy  war  and  is  permissible,  but  if  he  says :  "  Take  this  in 
order  to  fight  with  it,"  it  is  a  case  of  being  hired  and  is 
not  allowed. 

According  to  Malik,2  people  in  Medina  used  to  practise 
the  giving  of  ju'l ;  those  who  stayed  at  home  equipping  those 
who  joined  the  colors.  Malik  therefore  did  not  see  any 
objection  to  its  practice  as  between  two  stipendiaries  of  the 
Dlwan.  Ibn  al-Qasim,  however,  disapproves  of  stipen- 
diaries' sending  in  their  place  non-stipendiaries  by  paying 
their  expenses. 

According  to  the  Shafiites,  it  is  not  allowed  to  hire  a 
Moslem  to  fight,  but  the  stipends  which  the  soldiers  receive 
from  the  state  are  not  a  case  of  rental.  If  the  imam  assigns 
to  a  Moslem  the  task  of  washing  a  dead  Moslem,  he  is  not 
given  a  wage  if  the  dead  person  has  no  estate  and  the  treas- 
ury has  no  available  funds.3 

Al-Mawardi,4  in  discussing  the  duties  of  the  public  in- 
spector (muhtasib)  with  respect  to  the  enforcement  of  acts 
recommended  and  prescribed  by  the  shari'ah  ( amr  bi  7  maf- 
ruf) ,  extends  this  idea  of  forced  assessment  from  the  carry- 
ing out  of  the  holy  war  to  every  undertaking  which  re- 
dounds to  the  benefit  of  Moslems  as  a  whole  as  follows: 6 

1  Mabsut,  part  x,  p.  75. 

2  Mudawwanah,  part  iii,  pp.  43-6. 

3  Wajiz,  vol.  ii,  p.  189. 

4  Pp.  4H-3. 

5  The  general  nature  of  the  wording  used  by  al-Mawardi  would  ind'- 
cate  that  what  he  says  in  this  connection  applies  to  all  the  residents 


FINANCIAL  CONTRIBUTIONS  35! 

If  the  water  supply  of  a  city  is  cut  off  or  its  walls  are 
dilapidated,  or  if  needy  wayfarers  come  to  it,  there  is  no 
obligation  for  the  people  of  the  city  to  restore  the  supply 
of  the  water  or  build  the  walls  or  to  aid  the  wayfarers  so 
long  as  there  are  available  funds  in  the  treasury.  This 
would  also  apply  if  their  mosques  and  worshiping  places 
(masjid)  were  dilapidated.  If,  however,  there  are  no 
available  funds  in  the  treasury,  then  the  obligation  of  doing 
the  above  rests  upon  all  the  people  of  means  (dhu  'l-mik- 
nati)  in  general  though  upon  no  one  of  them  in  particular. 

Should  the  people  of  means  undertake  these  tasks,  the 
public  inspector's  right  to  order  them  lapses,  and  the  former 
are  not  required  to  obtain  permission  for  aiding  the  way- 
farers or  rebuilding  what  has  been  already  demolished. 
However  if  they  want  to  demolish  what  is  dilapidated  in 
order  to  rebuild  it,  they  are  not  given  the  above  prerogatives 
if,  for  instance,  the  matter  concerns  the  walls  of  the  mosque 
of  all  the  inhabitants  of  a  city.  They  must  then  obtain  the 
permission  of  the  authorities  (wall  al-amr),  not  of  the 
public  inspector;  furthermore,  they  have  to  offer  beforehand 
guarantee  that  they  will  build  it.  It  is  not,  however,  neces- 
sary to  obtain  the  permission  of  the  authorities  as  regards 
worshiping  places  of  tribes  and  clans  which  are  not  used  by 
many  people  (fltna  khassa).  It  is  the  duty  of  the  public 
inspector  to  require  the  people  who  demolished  a  building 
to  build  it  up,  but  he  may  not  force  them  to  complete  build- 
ings begun  by  them  for  the  first  time. 

When  the  persons  of  means  desist  from  building  and 
repairing  the  dilapidated  buildings,  if  residence  in  the  city 
is  still  possible,  or  if  the  water  supply,  although  scanty,  is 

(nds)  of  the  Moslem  state,  whether  Moslems  or  dhimmis.  Of  course, 
when  the  contribution  is  levied  en  the  dhin:it:is  it  is  a  secular  impost 
and  the  general  remarks  made  concerning  religious  taxes  do  not  apply 
to  it. 


352  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

sufficient,  the  public  inspector  leaves  them  in  peace.  If, 
however,  residence  in  a  city  becomes  impossible  on  account 
of  the  cutting  off  of  its  water  supply  or  the  collapse  of  its 
walls,  the  authorities  do  not  allow  the  residents  to  abandon 
their  city,  if — it  being  a  frontier  city — its  abandonment 
would  result  in  the  prejudice  of  the  "  Moslem  world  ". 
On  the  contrary,  the  persons  of  means  are  required  to  meet 
the  emergency,  in  the  way  such  untoward  contingencies 
(nawazil)  are  met.  The  duty  of  the  public  inspector,  on 
his  side,  is  to  inform  the  sultan  about  the  matter  and  to 
incite  the  people  of  means  to  meet  the  emergency. 

If,  however,  the  city  is  not  a  frontier  city  whose  aban- 
donment would  result  in  the  injury  of  the  "Moslem  world", 
the  case  is  easier  to  deal  with.  The  public  inspector  in 
such  case  has  no  right  to  force  the  inhabitants  (ahlahu)  to 
rebuild  it,  because  the  sultan  is  more  entitled  to  this  right, 
and  if  he  has  the  funds,  he  sees  to  it  that  it  is  rebuilt. 
But  if  the  sultan  does  not  possess  the  funds,  then  the  public 
inspector  says  to  the  inhabitants  of  the  city :  "  You  are  free 
to  abandon  the  city  or  to  undertake  to  do  what  is  necessary 
for  rendering  continued  residence  in  it  possible  ".  If  they 
undertake  to  do  so,  then  they  are  all  obligated  to  give  gener- 
ously what  they  will.  The  public  inspector  has  not  the 
right  to  force  any  one  of  them  in  particular  to  undertake 
to  give  what  he  would  not  of  his  own  free  will  and  consent, 
whether  little  or  much,  but  he  says :  "  Let  each  give  what 
is  easy  for  him  to  give  and  what  pleases  him  ".  Those  who 
can  give  money  do  so,  and  those  who  are  not  rich  offer  their 
services  until  a  sufficient  amount  has  been  raised  or  its  rais- 
ing has  been  insured  by  the  people  of  means  who  have  pledged 
themselves  for  the  amounts  agreeable  to  them.  Then  the 
work  is  begun  and  each  person  is  held  to  make  good  his 
pledge.  Although  such  pledges  are  not  valid  in  private  re- 
lations, in  this  case  they  have  been  considered  valid  and 


FINANCIAL  CONTRIBUTIONS  3-3 

binding  because  of  the  general  interests  involved.  In  cases 
where  the  interests  of  all  Moslems  are  involved,  the  public 
inspector  does  not  proceed  to  deal  with  the  situation  with- 
out previously  asking  for  the  permission  of  the  sultan ;  but 
it  is  allowed  to  begin  work  without  permission,  if  it  is  diffi- 
cult to  obtain  permission  or  it  is  feared  that  meanwhile  the 
evil  will  grow.1 

*Cf.  infra,  p.  437;  also  p.  521. 


CHAPTER  V 
PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS 

SECTION  I 
Classification  of  Persons  l 

ACCORDING  to  Mohammedan  theory  the  world  at  large 
falls  into  two  parts,  the  world  of  Moslems  (dar  al- 
islam)  and  the  world  of  foes,  the  harbis,  (dar  al-harb).2 
An  intermediate  position  may  be  assigned  to  the  world  of 
allies  (dar  al-'ahd),  although  strictly  speaking  the  ally 
world  is  only  a  temporary  stage,  since  theoretically  Mos- 
lems are  under  obligation  (fard)  to  engage  in  holy  war 
until  all  infidels  shall  have  accepted  Islam  or  the  status  of 
dhimmis*  Indeed  the  ifnam  may  break  the  truce  he  may  have 

1  Kasani,  vol.  vii,  p.  102. 

2  For  details  concerning  definitions  and  as  to  when  ddr  al-harb  be- 
comes ddr  al-isldm,  and  vice  versa,  consult  al-Kasani  (vol.  vii,  p.  130), 
the  'Alamkiriyyah  (vol.  ii,  p.  330),  and  the  Technical  Dictionary   (p. 
466);  also  al-Mawardi  (p.  239).     Suffice  it  to  say  that  the  expression 
ddr  al-isldm  applies  to  every  land  where  the  intdm  (ruler)  of  the  Mos- 
lems holds  sway  and  the  Moslems  enjoy  security,  and  that  the  enemy 
world   (ddr  al-harb)   becomes  moslem  world  when  the  sharl'ah  pre- 
scriptions are  enforced  in  it.     There  is  divergence  of  opinion  as  to 
when  the  moslem  world  becomes  enemy  world. 

8  Cf.  Umm,  vol.  iv,  p.  91;  Wajiz,  vol.  ii,  p.  186;  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p. 
255 ;  Kanz,  vol.  ii,  p.  253,  no.  5393 ;  Kharashi,  p.  406.  According  to  the 
Mugni  (vol.  iv,  p.  193)  the  obligation  of  holy  war  should  be  fulfilled  at 
least  once  a  year.  The  "  holy  war,"  however,  may  be  only  negative 
and  consist  in  the  strengthening  of  defences  instead  of  in  actual  aggres- 
sion. 

354 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS  355 

entered  into  with  the  infidels  on  condition  of  payment  by 
them  of  kliaraj  and  jisyah,  if  such  a  course  is  required  by 
the  best  interests  of  Islam,  provided  however  he  gives  them 
due  notice.  Normally  therefore  the  Moslem  world  is  in  a 
state  of  war  with  the  harbis  unless  this  state  has  been  ter- 
minated in  one  of  these  three  ways;  namely,  conversion  to 
Islam,  taking  of  refuge  in  the  Sanctuary  (haram),  and  the 
giving  of  aman.  Of  these  three  ways,  only  the  last  need 
be  discussed  here.  The  giving  of  aman  consists  in  pledg- 
ing security  and  protection  to  the  harbis  and  may  be  tem- 
p  rary  or  perpetual. 

( I )  The  Temporary  Anum  (aman  ntuwaqqat) .  This  is  of 
two  kinds:  the  well-known  (ma'riif)  or  informal,  and  the 
formal  (muwada'ah). 

(a)  The  Well-known  Aman.1     Any  freeborn  Moham- 
medan, man  or  woman,  may  give  pledge  of   protection 
(am&n)  to  a  harbi  or  a  group  of  harbis  or  even  the  entire 
defensive  force  of  a  fortress,  and  thereupon  the  harbis  be- 
come mitsta'mins  and  are  not  molested,  provided  they  can 
prove  by  two  witnesses  that  they  have  been  given  aman. 
The  imam  however  may  repudiate  such  an  aman  and  even 
punish  the  Moslem  who  gave  it,  if  the  latter  was  mistaken 
in  thinking  that  Moslem  interests  required  such  a  course. 

(b)  The  Formal  Aman  or  Truce  Pact   (muwada'ah)* 
It  is  allowed  to  the  imam  or  to  a  group  of  Moslems  without 
the  imam's  permission  to  make  truce  with  the  harbis  (en- 
emy) on  condition  of  payment  by  them  of  a  certain  sum  of 
money   or   goods,    unless    they    are    renegades;    such    are 
not  given  quarter,  but  have  to  choose  between  the  sword 
and  Islam.     The  money  received  from  the  enemy  is  consid- 
ered as  jizyah  if  the  enemy  agreed  to  pay  it  before  the  be- 

1  Cf.  Wajis,  vol.  ii,  p.  194 ;  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  271 ;  Kharashi,  p.  420. 

2  The  Shafiites  and  Malikites  instead  of  muwdda'ah  use  muhddanah 
and  hudnah. 


356  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

ginning  of  hostilities ;  otherwise  it  is  treated  as  spoils.  It  is 
even  allowed  to  conclude  a  truce  pact  on  condition  of  pay- 
ment on  the  part  of  Moslems,  if  such  course  is  indispen- 
sably necessary  for  the  furtherance  of  the  Moslem  interests. 
The  legal  result  of  the  pact  is  like  that  of  the  informal 
aman,  namely,  the  enemy  enjoys  security  from  death  and 
captivity,  and  security  of  property  on  the  part  of  Moslems. 
If  a  person  residing  in  the  country  with  which  the  pact  has 
been  made,  enters  the  country  of  the  harbis  and  subse- 
quently the  latter  country  is  conquered  by  the  Moslems, 
that  person  is  treated  as  a  musta'min.  Likewise  a  harbi 
entering  the  country  of  pact  with  aman,  is  considered  a 
musta'min  with  regard  to  the  Moslem  country  also  if  he 
has  not  meanwhile  returned  to  the  dar  al-harb.  The  imam 
may  repudiate  the  pact  made  if  that  is  conducive  to 
the  interests  of  Islam,  provided  the  enemy  is  duly  notified 
about  it,  and  in  such  case  there  is  returned  to  the  enemy  a 
proportionate  part  of  the  tribute  paid  by  them.  This  is 
based  on  the  precedent  of  the  Prophet,  who  broke  the  agree- 
ment made  between  him  and  the  Meccans.1 

According  to  the  Shafiites,  a  valid  aman  of  either  kind 
may  not  be  annulled  by  the  imam  unless  he  suspects  treach- 
ery.2 The  Malikites  agree  with  the  Shafiites  as  regards  the 
formal  aman  only.31  The  dissolution  of  the  pact  takes  place 
at  the  time  set  if  one  has  been  set.  If  no  time  has  been  set, 
the  pact  ends  in  two  ways,  namely,  by  express  dissolution 
by  either  side,  or  implicitly,  if,  for  instance,  the  harbis  go 
out  on  the  highways  with  the  permission  of  their  ruler  in 
order  to  rob  Moslems.  If  the  pact  is  made  with  the  condi- 
tion that  in  the  country  of  the  enemy  the  laws  of  Islam  will 
be  enforced,  it  is  equivalent  to  giving  the  perpetual  aman. 

lMajma',  p.  498. 

'  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  pp.  272,  290. 

8  Kharashi,  p.  449. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS 


357 


(2)  The  Perpetual  Aman  called  'aqd  dhimmah.  This 
consists  in  the  acquisition  of  the  status  of  the  dhimmi,  and 
may  be  expressed  or  implicit,  as,  for  instance,  when  the 
harbi  enters  the  Moslem  state  by  a  temporary  aman,  and 
exceeds  the  time  limit  set  by  the  imam,  or  if  no  limit  has  been 
set,  according  to  the  Mabsut,1  when  he  resides  in  the  Moslem 
state  a  year,  but  according  to  others,  only  after  a  time 
has  been  set  and  has  elapsed.  Indeed,  when  a  harbi  enters 
the  Moslem  state  by  virtue  of  an  aman  the  imam  should 
notify  him,  that  should  he  reside  a  year  or  more,  he  would 
be  considered  as  a  dhimmi  and  would  be  subject  to  the 
jizyah  and  the  kharaj.  The  author  of  the  Majma'  approves 
of  the  policy  of  allowing  the  harbis  a  short  stay  because  in 
the  contrary  case  trade  would  stop  and  the  Moslems  would 
suffer  by  it.  If  a  harbi  buys  a  kharaj  land  he  becomes 
dhimmi  from  the  time  the  kharaj  has  been  assessed  on  the 
land,  even  if  the  time  previously  set  has  not  elapsed.  The 
effect  of  becoming  a  dhimmi  is  security  of  property  and 
life.  Indeed  in  the  field  of  civil  transactions  the  dhimmis 
enjoy  the  same  rights  as  the  Moslems.2 

In  reply  to  the  following  question  put  by  certain  Moslems, 
"  How  may  the  dhimmis  be  allowed  to  persist  in  what  is 
the  worst  of  crimes,  i.  e.,  unbelief,  by  payment  of  a  mone- 
tary consideration?",  al-Sarakhsi  says  that  the  object  is 
not  the  monetary  consideration,  but  their  invitation  to  the 
Faith  in  the  most  beautiful  way.  In  fact,  as  a  result  of  the 
act  of  covenant  ('aqd  al-dhimmah)  the  dhimmi  abandons 
fighting,  and  the  person  who  does  not  fight  may  not  be  at- 
tacked. Then,  too,  "  the  dhimmi  by  living  among  the  Mos- 
lems sees  the  beauties  of  the  Moslem  faith  and  is  exhorted 
to,  and  often  does,  accept  Islam."  ! 


p.  510. 

*  Cf.  Wajlz,  vol.  ii,  p.  201  ;  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  283. 
8  Mabsut,  part  x,  p.  77. 


358  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

It  is  not  within  the  power  of  the  Moslem  state  to  break 
of  its  own  accord  the  pact  of  dhimmah,  but  the  pact  is  not 
binding  (lazim)  as  regards  the  dhimmis.1  The  pact  is  con- 
sidered dissolved  in  three  ways:  If  the  dhimmi  becomes 
Moslem,  because  the  reason  in  giving  him  the  status  of 
dhimmi  was  the  possibility  of  his  conversion  to  Islam,  and 
the  object  in  this  case  has  been  secured;  or  if  the  dhimmi 
returns  to  the  land  of  harbis,  for  by  so  doing  he  becomes 
like  the  renegades ;  except  that  if  he  is  captured  he  is  made 
a  slave,  which  is  not  true  of  the  renegades;  or,  thirdly,  if 
the  dhimmi  fights  the  Moslems. 

The  pact  is  not  broken,  however,  if  the  dhimmis  do  not 
pay  the  taxes,  for  it  may  be  due  to  their  poverty;  or  if  they 
slander  the  Prophet,  for  this  would  only  amount  to  an  in- 
crease of  unbelief,  but  unbelief  was  not  an  obstacle  to  their 
acquisition  of  the  status  of  dhimmi  in  the  first  place. 

The  refusal  of  a  dhimmi  to  pay  the  jizyah  is  not  con- 
strued as  a  breach  on  his  part  of  the  pact  of  dhimmah  by 
virtue  of  which  he  acquired  the  status  of  dhimmi,  because 
the  object  in  view  is  the  dhimmi 's  acceptance  of  the  obliga- 
tion to  pay  the  jizyah,  but  not  its  payment  per  se,  and  so 
when  he  refuses  to  pay  the  tax,  his  previous  acceptance  and 
the  humiliation  attendant  on  it  are  still  there. 

In  the  Durar  it  is  stated  that  there  is  a  difficulty  involved  in 
this  view,  because  to  refuse  to  pay  the  jizyah  is  virtually  to 
state  expressly  that  it  will  not  be  paid,  as  if  one  said :  "  I 
will  not  pay  the  jizyah  in  the  future  ",  and  it  is  evident  that 
this  makes  impossible  the  continuation  of  the  acceptance  un- 
less refusal  be  construed  to  mean  delay  and  offer  of  excuses, 
in  which  case  the  difficulty  is  removed.  It  may,  however,  be 
replied  that  in  consequence  of  the  dhimmi' s  acceptance  of 
the  obligation  the  jizyah  becomes  a  debt,  as  in  case  of  sur- 
etyship for  wealth,  and  therefore  if  the  dhimmi  later  says: 

1  Cf.  WajJz,  vol.  ii,  p.  197 ;  Kharashi,  p.  447. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS  359 

"  I  will  not  pay  the  jizyah  ",  it  has  no  legal  effect  beyond 
entailing  his  imprisonment,  as  in  the  case  of  other  debts.1 

According  to  the  Shafiites,2  the  pact  is  broken  if  the 
dhimmis  fight  the  Moslems,  or  if  they  refuse  to  pay  the 
j  icy  ah  or  to  obey  the  Moslem  laws,  but,  unless  expressly 
stipulated,  not  if  they  debauch  Moslem  women  or  slander 
the  Prophet.  Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,8  the  pact 
is  broken  in  all  the  four  cases  mentioned. 

Corresponding  to  the  three  "  worlds  ",  the  Moslem,  the 
ally,  and  the  enemy,  there  are  the  three  classes  of  persons 
designated  as  Moslems,  allies  (mu'nhid)  and  enemies 
(harbi)  ;  besides,  there  are  the  classes  of  dhimmis  and 
musta'mins.  The  dhimmis  are,  as  already  explained,  the 
harbis  who  have  definitely  committed  themselves  to  the  pro- 
tection of  the  Moslems,  whereas  the  musta'mins  are  per- 
sons who  have  come  under  that  protection  only  temporarily. 

SECTION   II 

Classification  of  Waters  and  Lands  * 

Waters  are  distinguished  into  tithe  and  kharaj  water.' 
Tithe  water  is  the  water  of  rivers,  seas,  and  springs  situ- 
ated, and  of  wells  sunk,  in  the  first  four  °  classes  of  tithe 
lands  set  forth  below,  or  as  the  author  of  the  Hidayah  puts 
it,  it  is  water  that  has  not  come  under  the  jurisdiction  (wild- 
yah )  of  any  person. 

1  Majnia',  p.  519. 

2  Minhdj,  vol.  iii.  p.  286;  Wajiz,  vol.  ii.  p.  203. 
*  Kharashi,  p.  447. 

'  Ifojma',  pp.  178,  512;  Path,  p.  199,  also  vol.  v,  p.  277;  Jam?,  p.  328. 

5  This  distinction  is  according  to  the  Hanifites.  The  Shafiites  an  1 
Malikites  ignore  it  because,  according  to  them,  in  determining  the  kind 
of  tax  to  he  levied  on  a  piece  of  land,  the  status  of  the  land-owner 
and  the  land  is  more  significant  than  that  of  the  water  used  in  its 
irrigation.  (Cf.  Mawardi,  pp.  262,  310.) 

'  'Indyah.  p.  199, 


360  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Kharaj  water,  on  the  other  hand,  is  the  water  of  rivers, 
seas,  and  springs  situated,  and  of  wells  sunk,  in  kharaj 
lands.  It  includes  also  the  water  of  rivers  dug  by  Persian 
kings,  such  as  the  river  Yazdajard,  and  the  water  of 
springs  and  canals  dug  at  the  expense  of  the  public 
treasury.1  Likewise,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah  and 
Abu  Yusuf,  the  water  of  the  rivers  Sayhun,  Jayhun 
(Oxus),  Euphrates,  Tigris,  and  Nile  is  kharaj  water,  be- 
cause these  rivers  are  from  time  to  time  taken  under  pos- 
session (yad),  in  that  in  these  rivers  vessels  often  are 
placed  alongside  one  another  so  as  to  form  a  sort  of  bridge- 
way  on  which  one  may  pass  across  to  the  other  bank.  Ac- 
cording to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  however,  these  rivers 
are  tithe  rivers  because  they  are  not  under  the  protection  of 
any  person,  but  are  like  the  open  sea,  and  because  the  form- 
ing of  bridges  referred  to  by  the  others  is  rare.  Accord- 
ing to  the  Path,  the  reason  why  waters  which  were  formerly 
under  the  possession  of  unbelievers  become  kharaj  water  is 
because,  like  the  rest  of  the  property  of  unbelievers,  through 
the  fact  of  conquest,  waters,  too,  become  booty  of  war  and 
like  the  lands  they  become  objects  of  kharaj  when  left  to 
the  infidels. 

Tithe  lands  are  the  following : 

(i)  The  entire  land  of  the  Arabs,  namely,  the  country 
extending  from  the  borders  of  Syria  and  Kufah  to  the 
farthest  point  of  Yaman,  or  according  to  al-Karkhi,  the  dis- 
tricts of  al-Hijaz,  Tihamah,  Yaman,  Ta'if,  and  Barriyyah. 
The  land  of  the  Arabs  has  been  considered  as  tithe  land, 
because  the  Prophet,  and  after  him  the  four  "  righteous  " 
califs,  did  not  impose  on  it  the  kharaj }  and  because  the  pay- 
ment of  kharaj  involves  humiliation,  and  the  lands  of  the 
Arabs  do  not  deserve  kharaj  any  more  than  their  persons 

1  Kasani,  p.  58. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS  361 

deserve  slavery.  In  fact,  the  kharaj  is  imposed  only  on 
lands  whose  owners  may  persist  in  their  unbelief,  but  the 
Arabs,  if  they  are  heathens,  have  only  two  alternatives  to 
choose  between,  namely,  Islam  and  the  sword. 

(2)  As  an  exception,  Basrah  has  been  considered  tithe 
land  owing  to  an  ijmtf  of  the  Companions.  Abu  Yusuf 
says  that  by  analogy  Basrah  should  be  kharaj  land  because 
it  is  a  part  of  kharaj  country,  but  that  analogy  was  aban- 
doned in  this  case  in  consequence  of  the  practice  of  the 
Companions  who  levied  the  tithe  on  the  lands  of  Basrah.1 
The  Shafiite  view  is  to  the  same  effect.3 

According  to  al-Mawardi  this  view  as  to  the  lands  of 
Basrah  being  tithe  lands  has  been  justified  by  the  doctors 
of  'Iraq  (i.  e.f  the  Hanifites)  who  follow  Abu  Hani f ah  on 
two  different  grounds:  the  first  ground  is  that  the  water  of 
the  Tigris,  which,  according  to  Abu  Hanlfah,  is  kliaraj 
water  diminishes  at  ebb  time  in  the  vicinity  of  Basrah  and 
that  the  lands  are  irrigated  at  flow  time  only,  that  is,  from 
sea  water.  Al-Mawardi  remarks  that  this  reasoning  is 
false  in  view  of  the  fact  that  the  flow  holds  the  sweet  water 
back  from  the  sea  and  prevents  its  mixing  with  the  sea 
water,  and  that  consequently  the  lands  are  irrigated  from 
the  water  of  the  Tigris.  The  second  ground  is  that  the 
water  of  Tigris  and  the  Euphrates  disappears  in  the  Great 
Swamps  (Bataih)  and  loses  its  character  of  kharaj  water 
since  the  Great  Swamps  are  not  kharaj  rivers ;  consequently 
when  the  water  reappears  at  Basrah,  it  is  no  longer  kharaj 
water.  Al-Mawardi  after  remarking  that  this  second  rea- 
soning is  also  false,  adds  that  the  grounds  invoked  by  the 
Hanifites  as  justification  for  their  view  on  the  matter  are 
only  pretexts  and  that  their  view  in  reality  is  based  on  the 
ijma.'  of  the  Companions. 

1  C7.  Zayla'i,  vol.  iii,  p.  272.  f  Cf.  Mawardi,  p.  310. 


362  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

(3)  All  the  lands  whose  owners  became  Moslems  of 
their  own  accord  and  have  been  allowed  to  remain  in  posses- 
sion of  their  lands. 

(4)  All  the  lands  which  were  conquered  by  force  ('an- 
wat)  and  divided  among  the  victorious  Moslem  army,  or  for 
that  matter  among  any  Moslems.     This  is  because  it  is  not 
fitting  to  begin  with  kharaj  in  taxing  the  land  of  a  Moslem 
for  the  first  time,  and  because  the  tithe  is  lighter  than  the 
kharaj,  and  includes  besides  an  element  of  worship.    Accord- 
ing to  al-Shafi'i  such  lands  become  booty  of  war  (garilmah) 
and  as  such  they  are  divided  among  the  victorious  army 
who  pay  for  them  tithe,  but  never  kJiaraj.     According  to 
Malik,  however,  these  lands  by  the  very  fact  of  conquest 
become  common  property  (waqf)  of  all  the  Moslems  and 
pay  kharaj  as  a  rental  (kirtf).1    Abu  Hanifah,  on  the  con- 
trary, gives  the  calif  the  option  of  dividing  these  lands 
among  the  army  and  levying  the  tithe,  or  of  leaving  them  to 
their  non-Moslem  owners  and  collecting  from  them  the 
kharaj. 

(5)  The  Habitations  (dar)  of  Moslems  which  have  been 
converted  by  their  owners  into  gardens,  provided  they  are 
irrigated  with  tithe  water.3    If  they  are  watered  alternately 
with  tithe  and  kharaj  water,  they  are  still  tithe  lands. 

(6)  The  waste  lands  (mau*at)  developed  (tijya')  for  cul- 
tivation by  Moslems  with  the  imam's  permission ;  according 
to  Abu  Yusuf ,  if  the  lands  are  situated  in  a  tithe  district ; 
but  according  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  if  the  lands 
have  been  developed  with  tithe  water.3 

According  to  the  Mukit*  the  principle  just  referred  to 

1  Mawardi,  p.  254;  Kharashi,  pp.  426-7;  Dardlr,  p.  200.     See  infra, 
under  (4)  of  Khardj  lands. 
*  Majma',  p.  178. 

3  Mabstit,  part  Hi,  pp.  57-58.    But  cf.  Mfnvardi,  p.  310. 
'Jam?,  p.  328. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS  363 

with  respect  to  waste  lands  developed  for  the  first  time  ap- 
plies also  to  lands  previously  developed  and  already  subject 
to  kharaj  or  tithe,  namely,  that  if  a  kharaj  land  is  cut  off 
from  its  kharaj  water  and  is  watered  with  tithe  water  it 
becomes  tithe  land,  and  vice  versa.  The  same  view  is  ex- 
pressed by  al-Zayla'i  l  as  well  as  the  Durar*  and  the  Durr ' 
except  that  they  restrict  this  to  the  Moslem  owners  only, 
the  non- Moslem  owners  always  paying  kliaraj  irrespective 
of  the  water  they  use.  The  Path,  however,  restricts  this 
to  the  case  of  waste  lands  first  developed  by  Moslems.4 

The  contention  of  Abu  Yusuf  is  that  when  a  piece  of  land 
is  in  a  tithe  district  it  legally  becomes  a  dependency  (taba') 
of  the  district  and  pays  tithe  like  the  rest  of  the  district,  ex- 
actly as  the  immediate  surroundings  of  the  house  are  a  de- 
pendency of  the  house  and,  like  it,  are  exempt  from  taxa- 
tion. Muhammad's  ground  is  that  it  is  not  proper  to 
begin  with  kharaj  in  taxing  the  land  of  a  Moslem  for  the 
first  time,  except  when  the  Moslem  voluntarily  incurs  such 
treatment  by  developing  his  land  with  kharaj,  rather  than 
with  tithe,  water.  Finally,  the  ground  for  the  view  ex- 
pressed in  the  Mulnt  is  that  the  tax  levied  on  a  land  de- 
pends on  its  productivity  and  the  latter  on  the  kind  of  water 
used.  However,  in  the  case  of  the  non-Moslem  owner  the 
water  is  disregarded,  because  the  payment  of  tithe  is  an  act 
of  worship  which  only  Moslems  can  perform.  Therefore 
the  non-Moslem  owner  perforce  pays  kharaj  in  either  case. 

According  to  al-Mawardi  ''  a  waste  land  developed  for 

•Vol.  Hi,  p.  271.  'P.  i77.  SP-  364. 

4  Path,  vol.  v,  p.  280.  According  to  al-Shafi'i  ( Mawardi,  pp.  262-3, 
310),  the  kind  of  tax  levied  on  land  depends  on  the  kind  of  land,  not 
of  water  used,  and  therefore,  contrary  to  what  Abu  Hani f ah  held,  th  • 
owner  of  a  tithe  land  should  be  allowed  to  use  khardj  water,  and  rice 
versa, 

*  P.  3io. 


364  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

cultivation  is  subject  to  tithe  irrespective  of  the  water  used 
in  its  irrigation. 

The  kharaj  lands,  on  the  other  hand,  are  the  following: 

(i)  The  Sawad  of  'Iraq,  namely,  the  territory  included 
lengthwise  between  Hadithah  and  'Abbadan,  both  on  the 
Euphrates,  and  in  breadth  between  the  streams  'Udhayb 
near  Kufah,  and  Hulwan.  This  territory  was  called  Sawad, 
meaning  black,  because,  owing  to  its  rich  flora  it  appeared 
black,  from  a  distance.  The  Sawad  is  kharaj  land  because 
Omar  in  the  presence  of  the  Companions  imposed  on  it  the 
khar&j. 

According  to  the  Hanifites  the  Sawad  was  conquered  by 
force  and  its  lands  were  left  in  the  ownership  of  their  origi- 
nal owners  who  may  therefore  sell  their  lands  to  one  an- 
other and  in  general  exercise  all  the  rights  of  ownership. 

The  Shafiites,1  while  agreeing  with  the  Hanifites  that  the 
Sawad  was  conquered  by  force,  claim  that  subsequently  the 
army  was  induced  by  proper  compensation  to  relinquish  its 
property  rights  in  the  lands  of  Sawad,  which  were  there- 
upon made  waqf  for  the  benefit  of  all  Moslems,  and  leased 
in  perpetuity  (ijarah  mu'abbadah)  to  the  former  owners 
who  thereby,  being  mere  tenants,  may  not  sell  or  inherit 
them.2  Al-Shafi'i s  says  that  the  question  whether  the 

1  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  269 ;  Wajis,  vol.  ii,  p.  193 ;  Mawardi,  p.  302. 

2  According  to  the  Hanifite  Abu  Bakr  al-Razi,  as  quoted  by  al-Zayla'i 
(vol.  iii,  p.  272),  there  are  ten  different  reasons  against  the  Shafiitc 
fiction  about  the  lands  of  Sawad  being  held  by  their  cultivators  merely 
on  lease.    The  most  important  of  these  reasons  are  as  follows :  A  lease 
implies  offer  and  acceptance  by  the  parties,  and  in  this  case  they  are 
absent;  had  it  been  a  case  of  lease,  the  Companions  could  not  have 
bought  any  lands  of  the  Sawad,  as  they  have  done ;  it  cannot  be  a  case 
of  lease,  for  the  term  and  object  of  a  lease  must  be  known,  further- 
more such  term  may  not  be  perpetual;  then,  too,  a  lease  would  not 
lapse  on  conversion  to  Islam,  but  according  to  al-Shan',  the  khardj 
lapses  on  conversion. 

8  Umm,  vol.  iv,  p.  193 ;  Muzani,  vol.  v,  p.  192. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS  365 

Sawad  was  conquered  by  force  of  arms,  or  acquired  through 
treaty  cannot  be  positively  settled  in  view  of  the  many  con- 
tradictory hadiths  bearing  on  the  matter.  However,  he 
strongly  inclines  to  believe  certain  hadiths  according  to  which 
immediately  after  the  conquest  of  the  Sawad  one- fourth  of 
it  was  divided  among  one-fourth  of  the  army  who  received 
the  rentals  for  3-4  years  until  the  calif  Omar  by  proper 
compensation  obtained  their  consent  to  the  return  of  the 
lands  in  order  that  they  might  be  made  waqf  for  the  benefit 
of  all  Moslems.  In  refutation  of  al-Shafi'i,  al-Sarakhsi  says 
the  following : 

Al-ShafVi  said  in  his  book :  "I  do  not  know  just  what  to 
say  concerning  the  Sawad  of  Kufah,  but  I  will  make  a  guess 
which  is  near  to  knowledge  ",  but  such  a  statement  is  con- 
tradictory and  a  sign  of  ignorance  on  the  part  of  the  per- 
son who  made  it,  for  how  may  a  guess  (zann)  be  called 
knowledge  unless  one  of  its  two  sides  predominates  on  the 
basis  of  evidence.  Moreover,  the  conquest  of  Sawad  by 
force  is  too  well-known  to  be  a  secret  to  any  one  and  there 
is  no  need  to  go  to  all  this  trouble,  for  al-Shafi'i  now  says : 
"  Omar  made  the  lands  property  of  the  Moslems  and  made 
the  residents  slaves,  afterwards  allowing  them  to  work  on 
the  lands  of  the  Moslems,  and  the  kharaj  and  jisyah  which 
he  imposed  upon  them  is  a  kind  of  impost  (daribah),  ex- 
actly as  the  master  arranges  with  his  slave  for  an  impost 
on  his  earnings  and  employs  him,"  and  again  he  says :  "  He 
(Omar)  set  them  free  as  a  favor  and  acquired  the  owner- 
ship of  the  lands,  then  he  leased  them  to  the  (people  of 
Sawad)  and  the  kharaj  he  imposed  on  them  is  a  rental." 
However,  this  is  absurd,  for  their  jisyah  is  too  well-known 
to  be  a  secret,  and  in  fact  they  have  been  accustomed  to  sell 
these  lands  to  one  another  and  inherit  them  from  one  an- 
other from  that  time  to  this,  and  so  we  know  that  the  cor- 
rect view  is  that  of  our  own  doctors,  namely,  that  he 
(Omar)  set  them  free  as  a  favor  and  made  them  a  present 
of  their  lands  and  he  imposed  on  them  the  jisyah  for  their 
heads  and  the  kharaj  for  their  lands.1 

1  Mabsvt,  ibid;  cf.  Utntn,  vol.  iv,  p.  192. 


366  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

According  to  the  Malikites   Sawad  was  conquered  by 
force  and  by  that  very  fact  became  waqf  territory. 

(2)  Egypt,  because  when  it  was  conquered  by  'Amr  Ibn 
al-'As,  Omar  imposed  on  it  the  kharaj. 

(3)  Syria,  because  concerning  it  there  is  an  ijmaf.     Ac- 
cording to  the  Path  1  the  tax  collected  "at  present"  from  the 
lands  of  Egypt  and,  by  analogy,  of  Syria,  is  not  kharaj  but 
in  reality  a  rental,  because  the  lands  became  property  of  the 
state    as    the    owners    gradually    died    without    rightful 
heirs.     According  to  the  Malikites,2  like  the  lands  of  the 
Sawad,  those  of  Syria  and  Egypt  were  also  conquered  by 
force  and  are  waqf  lands. 

(4)  All  lands  that  were  conquered  by  force  ("anivat)  and 
were  not  divided  among  the  victorious  army  but  were  left 
to  the  original  owners  or  given  to  non-Moslem  settlers 
brought  from  elsewhere.    The  Prophet  made  an  exception 
in  the  case  of  Mecca,  which  city,  although  conquered  by 
force  and  left  to  its  owners,  was  not  subjected  to  kharaj, 
According  to  al-Shafi'i,3  Mecca  was  conquered  by  treaty. 
However,  al-Gazzali 4  and  Malik  agree  with  the  Hanifites. 
According  to  the  Majma',  this  is  because  the  lands  of  the 
Arabs  are  not  subject  to  khar&j  any  more  than  their  persons 
are  liable  to  slavery.     According  to  al-Shafi'i,5  however, 
following  the  precedent  of  the  Prophet  with  the  people  of 
Khaybar  and  the  tribe  of  Qurayzah,  lands  too,  like  chattel, 
become  the  property  of  the  army  which  conquered  them, 
and  after  deduction  of  the  state's  share  of  one-fifth  they 
are  divided  among  the  army  and  only  pay  tithe.     However, 

1  Durr,  p.  364;  Bahr,  Minhah,  vol.  v,  p.  114, 

J  Kharashi,  p.  426. 

8  Cf.  Mawardi,  p.  284;  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  271. 

4  Wajis,  vol.  ii,  p.  194. 

6  Umtn,  vol.  iv,  p.  193. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS  367 

the  soldiers  may  of  their  own  accord  relinquish  their  rights 
in  these  lands,  and  then  the  imdm  makes  them  into  waqf  and 
the  state  collects  their  rental  (gallah).  According  to  the 
Malikites,1  lands  conquered  by  force  of  arms  by  that  very 
fact  become  waqf  but  are  nevertheless  left  in  the  hands  of 
their  former  owners  in  order  that  they  may  better  be  able  to 
pay  the  jisyah.  These  lands  are  subject  to  the  kharaj,  which 
in  reality  is  a  rental,  and  being  waqf  lands,  they  revert  to  the 
state,  upon  the  death  of  their  holders.  Unlike  the  lands,  the 
buildings  conquered  by  force,  pay  no  rental,  though  they 
also  become  waqf.  However,  buildings  put  up  by  the 
dhimmis  on  waqf  ground  after  the  conquest  become  their 
private  property. 

The  author  of  the  Multaqa,  following  al-Quduri,  says 
that  these  lands  do  not  become  tithe  lands  even  when  irri- 
gated with  tithe  water.  The  author  of  the  Hidayah,  on  the 
other  hand,  quoting  the  al-Jami'  al-Sagir,  says: 2 

"  All  lands  conquered  by  force  and  irrigated  by  rivers 
are  kharaj  lands,  and  if  they  are  not  irrigated  by  rivers,  but 
by  springs  issuing  from  them,  they  are  tithe  lands."  The 
author  of  the  Path,  however,  remarks  that  the  preceding 
quotation  can  refer  only  to  waste  lands  which  were  con- 
quered by  force  from  infidels  and  were  first  developed  by 
Moslems.  Indeed  the  cultivated  lands  so  conquered,  if  left 
to  their  infidel  owners,  are  kharaj  lands,  even  if  watered  by 
rain  (i.  e.,  tithe  water)  ;  on  the  other  hand,  if  such  lands 
were  divided  among  the  Moslem  soldiery,  they  are  tithe 
lands,  even  if  watered  by  rivers  (i.  e.,  kharaj  water).*  For 
while  it  is  unanimously  admitted  that  in  taxing  the  infidel 
for  his  land  for  the  first  time,  he  is  always  taxed  kharaj, 

1  Kharashi,  p.  426. 

1  Hiddyah,  vol.  v,  p.  280. 

3  But  cf.  Zayla'i,  vol.  iii,  p.  271;  Durar,  p.  176;  Durr,  p.  364. 


368  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  Moslem's  land  is  never  taxed  kharaj  for  the  first  time 
unless  it  be  that  the  Moslem  entails  upon  himself  such 
treatment  by  his  own  consent,  namely,  by  developing  his 
land  with  kharaj,  instead  of  with  tithe,  water.1 

(5)  Lands  concerning  which  the  imam  (i.  e.,  the  Mos- 
lem ruler)  has  come  to  an  agreement  with  their  infidel 
owners  that  the  lands  shall  be  left  to  them  and  that 
they  will  not  be  forced  to  migrate.  According  to  the 
'Alamktriyyah*  the  imam,  if  he  chooses,  may  impose  on 
these  lands  the  tithe  ('ushr)  but  this  is  in  name  only,  for 
such  a  tax  "  is  in  reality  kharaj  and  it  is  for  that  very  reason 
that  this  tithe  is  disbursed  like  the  kharaj  ".  An  example 
of  this  class  are  the  lands  of  the  people  of  Najran  who  had 
made  an  agrement  with  the  Prophet  to  pay  on  their  lands  a 
fixed  amount  of  kharaj.  Another  example  is  the  tribe  of 
Taglib  who  had  a  similar  treaty  with  Omar.  Balkh  and 
Sugd  are  further  examples.  According  to  this,  the  lands 
of  Samarqand  should  also  be  kharaj  lands,  but  because  they 
were  on  the  frontier,  they  were  made  tithe  lands  for  in- 
suring the  protection  of  the  frontiers.3 

In  the  Nutaf  it  is  written  that  when  the  imam  agrees 
with  a  Moslem  people  upon  a  certain  tribute  to  be  paid  by 
them  on  their  lands  this  tribute  is  legally  a  tithe,  and  if  it  is 
less  than  the  lawful  rate  of  tithe  the  balance  must  be  dis- 
bursed by  the  people  directly  to  the  poor.  This  applies  also 
to  agreements  made  with  the  infidels  if  they  later  become 
Moslems.4 

lMajma',  p.  513;  Path,  vol.  v,  p.  280;  Bahr,  vol.  v,  p.  113;  Durar,  p. 
176;  Durr,  p.  364;  Jdmi',  p.  328. 
*Vol.  ii,  p.  291. 

3  In  other  words,  Moslem  soldiers  stationed  on  the   frontiers  were 
given  in  fief  kharaj  lands,  and  as  an  inducement  to  military  pursuits 
they  were  required  to  pay  on   these  lands   the  tithe  instead   of  the 
khardj,  because  the  former  was  much  lighter  and,  besides,  could  be  paid 
to  the  poor  by  the  soldiers  themselves. 

4  Jam?,  p.  330. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS  369 

According  to  the  Shafiite  view,  as  summed  up  by  al- 
Mawardi,1  this  class  of  lands  are  the  only  ones  which  pay 
the  kharaj  and  they  fall  into  two  classes:  (a)  The  lands 
whose  owners  (ahl)  have  evacuated  them,  so  that  they  came 
into  Moslem  hands  without  fighting.  These  lands  become 
immobilized  (waqf)  in  the  general  interest  of  Moslems  and 
are  subject  to  kharaj,  which  is  really  a  rental  collected  from 
them  forever,  even  if  no  time  limit  was  set  for  it,  because 
the  benefit  derived  from  these  lands  belongs  to  the  entire 
Moslem  community.  Moreover,  the  kharaj  levied  on  these 
lands  is  not  affected  by  conversion  to  Islam,  and  being 
waqf  lands,  they  may  not  be  alienated  by  sale  to  private 
individuals,  (b)  The  lands  whose  owners  have  not  aban- 
doned them  and  which  by  the  terms  of  the  agreement  are 
left  in  the  possession  (yad)  of  the  owners  (ahl),  subject 
to  the  payment  of  kharaj.  This  class  is  of  two  kinds:  (i) 
The  owners  have  by  the  terms  of  the  agreement  relin- 
quished their  rights  of  ownership  in  the  lands  in  favor  of 
the  Moslems.  These  lands  become  waqf  (mortmain)  in 
the  interest  of  all  Moslems,  as  was  the  case  with  lands 
whose  owners  had  abandoned  them,  and  the  kharaj  levied 
on  these  lands  is  a  rental  (ujrah)  which  does  not  lapse  on 
their  conversion  to  Islam,  neither  can  they  validly  sell 
the  ownership  in  the  lands  (bay'  riqabihim).  However, 
they  are  entitled  to  (the  possession  of)  the  lands  more 
than  others  (ahaqq)  so  long  as  they  abide  by  the  terms  of 
the  agreement  and  the  lands  may  not  be  taken  away  from 
their  possession,  whether  they  persist  in  their  unbelief  or 
are  converted  to  Islam,  just  as  land  which  was  leased  may 
not  be  taken  away  from  the  possession  (yad)  of  the  tenant. 
These  people  by  paying  the  kharaj  do  not  become  exempt 
from  the  jizyah,  should  they  acquire  the  status  of  dhimmi 

1  Pp.  254-6,  also  pp.  237-9;  cf.  Umm.  vol.  iv,  pp.  103,  193. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

by  settling  (in  the  "Moslem  world");  for  they  are  not 
allowed  to  reside  for  an  entire  year  unless  they  relinquish 
the  status  of  ally  (hukm  al-'ahd)  and  become  dhimmis. 
They  may  however  reside  for  a  shorter  time  without  pay- 
ing the  jizyah.  (ii)  By  the  terms  of  the  agreement  they 
preserve  their  ownership  (milk)  in  the  lands  but  pay  kharaj 
on  the  lands  in  consideration  therefor.  According  to  al- 
Shafi  V  the  jizyah  to  be  paid  yearly  should  be  a  definite 
sum,  for  there  is  no  advantage,  he  goes  on  to  say,  in  stipu- 
lating that  the  kharaj  shall  be  so  much  per  jarib  when 
there  is  a  produce,  since  crops  may  fail  or  be  abundant,  and 
so  the  amount  which  will  be  collected  is  never  known.  This 
kharaj  is  of  the  nature  of  a  jizyah  which  is  levied  on  them 
so  long  as  they  persist  in  unbelief  but  lapses  upon  their 
conversion  to  Islam.  It  is  also  allowed  not  to  provide  for 
the  payment  of  a  jizyah.  These  people  may  sell  their  lands 
to  any  persons  they  desire,  including  Moslems  and  dhimmis. 
When  they  sell  their  lands  among  themselves,  the  amount 
of  kharaj  is  not  affected,  but  if  they  sell  them  to  Moslems, 
the  latter  do  not  pay  kharaj.  If,  finally,  the  land  is  sold  to 
a  dhimmi,  from  one  point  of  view  the  tax  should  also  lapse, 
because  by  being  a  dhimmi  the  owner  remains  outside  of  the 
scope  of  the  treaty  by  which  the  tax  was  collected,  since  that 
treaty  was  made  with  the  "  allies  " ;  but  from  another  point 
of  view  the  kharaj  should  not  be  allowed  to  lapse,  because 
the  dhimmi,  like  the  allies,  is  also  an  unbeliever. 

When  the  kharaj  lapses  with  respect  to  some  of  the  lands 
by  reason  of  the  owners  being  Moslems  (bi  islam  ahlihi), 
if  the  kharaj  was  assessed  on  the  basis  of  area,  at  the  rate 
of  so  much  silver  or  grain  per  jarib  of  area,  the  remain- 
ing lands  pay  the  usual  rate,  which  is  not  increased  to  allow 
for  the  part  that  has  lapsed.  If,  however,  the  kharaj  was 

1  C/mm,  vol.  iv,  p.  104. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS  371 

assessed  as  a  lump  sum  without  regard  to  area,  according  to 
al-Shafi'i,  the  amount  which  lapsed  on  account  of  the 
owners  being  Moslems  is  deducted  from  the  total,  but  ac- 
cording to  Abu  Hanifah  the  share  of  such  Moslems  is  not 
deducted  from  the  total. 

According  to  the  Malikites,1  when  a  city  comes  under 
Moslem  rule  as  a  result  of  a  treaty  stipulating  the  payment 
of  a  tribute  under  the  name  of  jizyah  or  kharaj,  the  lands 
of  the  city  in  every  case  remain  in  the  ownership  of  the 
former  owners  who  inherit  and  may  sell  them  at  will. 
Other  points,  however,  vary  according  to  the  terms  of  the 
treaty  as  follows : 

(a)  The  tribute  may  have  been  fixed  at  a  lump  sum 
(ujmilat)  without  being  distributed  over  the  heads  (riqab) 
or  the  lands,  e.  g.,  at  so  much  per  tree  or  unit  area.    The 
amount  of  the  tribute  in  this  case  does  not  vary  with  the 
increase  or  decrease  of  the  population  of  the  city,  but  re- 
mains constant,  and  every  one  of  the  people  of  the  city 
continues  to  be  responsible  for  the  entire  tribute  until  it  has 
been  paid.    When  one  of  them  dies  without  heirs  his  lands 
devolve  to  his  fellow  people  who  become  responsible  for 
his  tribute.    If  some  of  them  should  become  Moslems  they 
become  exempt  from  tribute,  but  they  nevertheless  con- 
tinue to  own  their  lands.     According  to  Ibn  Habib,  how- 
ever, they  forfeit  their  lands  when  they  become  Moslems, 
because  the  lands  are  legally  immobilized  in  order  to  enable 
them  to  pay  the  jizyah,  and  consequently  they  may  not  be 
inherited  or  sold. 

(b)  The  tribute,  on  the  contrary,  may  have  been  dis- 
tributed over  the  heads  or  the  lands,  or  over  both.    In  such 
case  the  tribute  varies  with  the  number  of  the  heads  or  the 
area  of  the  lands.     The  latter  continue  to  be  the  property 

1  Kharashi,  and  'Adawi,  pp.  444-5 J  Dardir,  p.  204;  cf.  Ibn  Rushd,  Af., 
p.  280. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

of  their  owners  even  after  conversion,  notwithstanding  that 
in  such  case  they  become  exempt  from  tribute.  Should  one 
of  them  die  without  heirs,  his  lands  become  waqf  property 
of  all  the  Moslems  unless  it  be  that  he  had  willed  away 
one-third  of  such  lands.  He  cannot,  however,  in  the  ab- 
sence of  heirs,  will  more  than  one-third  of  his  lands.  In  case 
the  tribute  was  distributed  over  the  lands,  whether  or  not 
it  was  distributed  over  the  heads,  the  owners  and  their  heirs 
do  not  become  free  from  the  kharaj  by  selling  their  lands, 
but  continue  to  pay  it.  According  to  one  doctor,  in  case 
of  sale,  the  kharaj  should  be  paid  by  the  whole  community 
rather  than  by  the  seller,  and  after  his  death,  by  his  heirs 
alone.  According  to  a  third  view  of  the  matter,  the  kharaj 
should  be  paid  by  the  buyer. 

(6)  Waste  lands  developed  for  cultivation  by  dhimmis 
with  the  state's  permission. 

(7)  Lands  granted  by  the  imam  to  the  dhimmis  from  the 
lands  conquered  from  the  enemy  in  consideration  of  assist- 
ance rendered  by  the  dhimmis  in  fighting  the  enemy.1 

(8)  Waste  lands  developed  for  cultivation  by  Moslems 
if  they  have  been  developed  with  kharaj  water,  or  are  situ- 
ated in  a  kharaj  district. 

(9)  Habitations  of   dhimmis  converted  into  gardens. 
Also  habitations  of  Moslems  converted  into  gardens,  if 
they  are  irrigated  with  kharaj  water.2 

If  a  dhimmi  buys  a  land  from  a  Taglabi,  he  pays  on  it 
the  double  rate  of  two-tenths,  because  according  to  Abu 
Hanifah,  as  well  as  his  two  disciples,  Abu  Yusuf  and  Mu- 
hammad, the  rate  is  doubled  in  regard  to  the  dhimmi,  as  it 
is  doubled,  for  instance,  when  he  passes  the  public  collector 
(rashir).  According  to  Abu  Hanifah,  likewise,  two-tenths 

1  Durar,  p.  176. 

*  For  details  concerning  this  and  the  preceding  class,  see  classes  5 
and  6  of  tithe  lands. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS  373 

is  collected  if  the  land  is  bought  by  a  Moslem,  instead  of 
by  a  dhimmi,  or  if  the  owner  (the  Taglabi)  becomes  a  Mos- 
lem, because  the  land  was  taxed  at  that  rate  before  and  the 
charge  continues  as  it  was.  According  to  Abu  Yusuf,, 
however,  the  rate  is  reduced  to  one-tenth,  because  the 
doubling  of  the  rate  was  due  to  the  owner's  being  an  infidel, 
and  when  he  is  a  Moslem  the  tax  should  be  only  one-tenth. 
Muhammad  in  this  connection  agrees  with  Abu  Hanifah, 
for  he  believes  in  the  continuation  of  the  double  rate,  al- 
though he  does  not  believe  in  the  doubling  of  the  rate  after 
it  had  been  one-tenth.1 

If  a  non-Taglabi  dhimmi  buys  a  tithe  land  from  a  Mos- 
lem, according  to  Abu  Hanifah  the  land  becomes  khar&j 
land  and  he  pays  kharaj  on  it.  According  to  Abu  Yusuf 
he  pays  a  double  rate.  According  to  Muhammad  he  pays 
only  a  single  rate.  Malik  claims  that  the  dhimmi  is  forced 
to  sell  it  back  to  a  Moslem.  Al-Shafi'i,  according  to  one 
report,  considers  the  sale  of  a  tithe  land  to  a  dhimmi 
as  essentially  null  and  void,  but  according  to  another  re- 
port, the  land  pays  both  tithe  and  khar&j.  Finally, 
Shank  Ibn  'Abdallah,  following  the  analogy  of  sawa'im 
animals,  said  that  the  dhimmi  pays  for  the  land  no  tax 
whatever.  The  argument  of  Malik  is  that  the  right  of  the 
poor  is  attached  to  the  land,  but  because  the  property  of 
an  infidel  is  not  fit  for  payment  in  discharge  of  this  right, 
the  dhimmi  is  forced  to  sell  it  back  to  a  Moslem.  Muham- 
mad's ground  is  that  the  charge  attaching  to  the  land  does 
not  change  with  the  status  of  the  owner.  Moreover,  ac- 
cording to  one  report  from  him,  the  single  rate  of  tithe  col- 
lected from  the  dhimmi  is  disbursed  like  the  proceeds  of 
zakat  to  the  poor,  because  the  right  of  the  poor  was  already 
attached  to  it.  The  reason  of  Abu  Yusuf  is  that  when  the 

1  Majma',  pp.  177-8. 


374  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

infidel  is  subject  to  the  same  tax  as  the  Moslem  the  rate  to 
him  is  doubled.  The  reason  of  Abu  Hanifah,  finally,  is 
that  productive  lands  in  Moslem  states  cannot  remain  un- 
taxed,  and  that  of  the  two  taxes,  the  kharaj  and  the  tithe, 
the  tithe  is  precluded  here  because  it  is  a  kind  of  sadaqah, 
which  the  infidel  may  not  pay,  and  that  therefore  he  is  sub- 
ject to  kharaj.  If  the  land  sold  by  the  Moslem  returns  to 
him  or  to  another  Moslem  through  the  exercise  of  the  right 
of  pre-emption  or  option  (khiyar),  or  through  the  sale's 
being  imperfect  (fasid),  or  by  virtue  of  a  judgment  of  dis- 
solution on  the  ground  of  a  defect  ('ayb)  in  the  land,  it 
becomes  again  a  tithe  land.  If,  however,  the  land  is  re- 
turned to  its  former  Moslem  owner  for  a  defect  without  a 
judgment  to  that  effect,  or  by  reason  of  a  dissolution  of  the 
sale  by  the  common  consent  of  the  two  parties  (iqalah) 
then,  because  such  a  dissolution  is  a  new  sale  as  re- 
gards third  parties,  the  Moslem  owner  pays  kharaj  on  it.1 
If  a  Moslem  buys  a  kharaj  land  from  a  dhimrrri, 
the  land  still  pays  kharaj,  according  to  the  Hanifites. 
Malik  says  that  the  land  becomes  tithe  land  because  kharftj 
involves  humiliation  and  a  Moslem  is  never  humiliated  either 
when  he  acquires  a  land  that  is  not  subject  to  kharaj,  or  even 
when,  for  instance,  he  buys  land  already  paying  kharaj. 
Al-Sarakhsi  says  that  Malik,  in  arriving  at  his  con- 
clusion, likened  the  kharaj  of  heads  (kharaj  al-ru'us)  to 
that  of  lands.2  But  this  is  not  true,  not  only  because  the 
precedents  of  Ibn  Mas'ud,  al-Hasan  Ibn  'Ali,  and  Abu  Hu- 

1  Durr,  p.  143. 

The  difference  between  dissolution  for  defect  by  a  judge  and  disso- 
lution by  the  two  parties  lies  in  the  fact  that  dissolution  by  the  judge 
in  virtue  of  the  general  authority  (wildyah  'dmmah)  vested  in  him 
amounts  to  an  absolute  dissolution  (faskh)  of  the  sale,  as  if  the 
Moslem  seller  had  never  sold  his  land.  Consequently  the  latter  con- 
tinues to  pay  tithe  on  his  land. 

*  Cf.  Utnnt,  vol.  iv,  p.  193;  vol.  vii,  p.  325. 


PRELIMINARY  CONSIDERATIONS 


375 


rayrah,  who  paid  kharaj  on  lands  owned  by  them  in  the 
Sawad,  point  to  the  conclusion  that  the  kharaj  must  be  con- 
tinued on  the  land  with  respect  to  its  new  Moslem  owner, 
but  also  because  the  humiliation  in  paying  kharaj  exists 
only  when  the  kharaj  is  imposed  on  a  land  for  the  first  time, 
but  not  when  it  is  continued  on  a  land  that  already  was 
paying  it.  Just  as  it  is  not  an  humiliation  to  continue  in 
the  status  of  slavery  after  conversion  to  Islam,  although  it 
is  humiliating  to  a  person  to  be  reduced  to  slavery  after 
having  become  a  Moslem.  As  regards  the  hadlth  invoked 
by  certain  opponents  to  the  effect  that  the  Prophet  referring 
to  instruments  of  agriculture  said :  "  These  have  not  en- 
tered the  house  of  a  people  but  that  they  have  become  de- 
graded ",  the  meaning  is  only  that  if  Moslems  occupy  them- 
selves with  agriculture,  follow  the  tails  of  oxen,  and  so  be- 
come sedentary  and  abandon  the  holy  war,  their  enemies 
will  return  to  the  charge  upon  them  and  so  humiliate  them ; 
it  by  no  means  signifies  that  the  payment  of  kharaj  is  humil- 
iating. The  kharaj  of  heads,  however,  is  different  because 
it  is  humiliating  whether  assessed  in  the  first  place  or  con- 
tinued, and  therefore  if  a  person  paying  this  kharaj  be- 
comes a  Moslem  he  ceases  to  pay  it.  Al-Sarakhsi  adds  that 
all  this  is  based  on  the  customs  of  the  people.1 

Later  doctors 2  distinguished,  besides  tithe  and  kharaj 
lands,  a  third  class  of  lands  called  amiriyyah  (also  tnamla- 
kat)  lands.  These  are  lands  conquered  by  force  or  gained  by 
treaty  which  were  not  left  in  the  ownership  of  their  former 
proprietors  but  were  made  the  property  of  the  public  treasury 
( bayt-d-mal) .  Their  proprietors  therefore  were  reduced  to 
mere  tenants  (mutasarrif)  and  paid  on  the  produce  of  the 

1  Mabstit,  part  iii,  p.  5 ;  cf.  part  x,  p.  83. 

3  Ifajtna',  p.  513.    For  details,  see  Belin,  Padel,  Gatteschi,  and  Husnt 
(pp.  19-20). 


376  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

land  a  proportional  kharaj  commonly  known  as  tithe  ('ushr). 
The  tenants  do  not  have  the  right  to  sell,  or  make  gift  of, 
or  constitute  as  waqfs,  their  lands  unless  so  permitted  by 
the  sultan.  Furthermore,  if  they  allow  the  lands  to  lie  idle 
for  three  years  they  forfeit  their  rights  of  tenancy,  and  the 
lands  are  leased  again  upon  repayment  of  their  value.  For- 
merly the  right  of  inheritance  was  restricted  to  the  male 
children  of  the  tenant  only,  his  daughters  and  paternal 
brothers  enjoying  only  a  right  of  preference  to  acquire  the 
tenancy  rights  by  payment  of  the  land's  value.  Later  the 
right  of  inheritance  has  by  law  been  considerably  extended. 
The  transfer  of  the  tenancy  rights  in  these  lands  is  effected 
only  by  permission  of  the  sultan  or  his  representative.1 

1  This  permission  is  a  matter  of  form  only,  being  never  refused.  The 
legal  status  of  these  lands  viewed  from  the  standpoint  of  the  shari'ah 
is  not  well  defined.  Thus  the  concession  of  the  tenancy  rights  in  these 
lands  is  not  exactly  in  accordance  with  the  shari'ah  principles  concern- 
ing location  (ijdrah)  because  the  duration  and  the  rental  are  not 
known.  Turkish  faqihs  consider  it  a  case  of  txtrz-shan'ah  or  imper- 
fect (fdsid)  location.  (Cf.  Husni,  pp.  24,  93.)  Consequently,  the 
lump  sum  paid  at  the  time  of  the  concession,  which  is  called  tdpu,  and 
is  equal  to  the  value  of  the  land,  is  looked  upon  as  the  anticipated  part 
(mu'ajjalah)  of  the  future  rentals,  while  the  taxes  collected  yearly  as 
tithe  or  muqdta'ah,  etc.,  are  considered  as  the  delayed  (mu'ajjalah) 
part  of  the  same.  In  Turkey  the  so-called  ijdreteynli  waqfs  present 
another  case  in  which  the  exigencies  of  the  times  have  made  a  depar- 
ture from  accepted  principles  necessary. 


CHAPTER  VI 
THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  * 

THE  word  kharaj  literally  means  the  revenue  derived 
from  a  piece  of  land  or  a  slave.  Technically  it  denotes  the 
tax  imposed  on  land,  and  by  extension,  it  also  means  the 
jizyah.  According  to  the  Path,  the  proper  meaning  of  the 
word  kharaj  is  the  kharaj  of  land,  and  therefore  it  may  not 
be  construed  to  mean  the  kharaj  of  heads  (ru'us),  that  is, 
the  jizyah,  unless  there  is  an  indication  to  that  effect.2 

1  A/a/ma',  p.  512;  Mabsuf,  part  x,  p.  79;  Hiddyah,  vol.  v,  p.  281 ;  Jdml', 
p.  330;  Durr,  p.  364;  Durar,  p.  177;  'Alantkiriyyah,  vol.  ii,  p.  337;  Babr, 
vol.  v,  p.  115;  Mawardi,  p.  253.  Unlike  the  Hanifites,  the  Malikites 
and  the  Shafiites,  with  the  exception  of  al-Mawardi,  do  not  discuss  the 
khardj  beyond  summarily  indicating  the  disbursement  of  its  proceeds. 
As  regards  the  khardj  levied  on  the  strength  of  a  treaty,  it  is  easy  to 
explain  why  they  do  not  discuss  it,  for  the  details  of  its  administra- 
tion in  that  case  did  not  concern  the  central  Moslem  authorities,  who 
were  interested  in  the  proceeds  only.  On  the  other  hand,  as  regards 
the  khardj  levied  on  lands  conquered  by  force  and  brought  under  im- 
mediate Moslem  administration,  we  saw  that  such  lands  were  legally 
considered  as  waqf  property  left  in  the  possession  of  their  original 
owners  by  perpetual  leases  in  return  for  the  payment  of  rentals  known 
as  khardj.  Al-Shafi'i  (Umm,  vol.  iii,  p.  240)  considers  the  nature  of 
their  holdings  in  the  lands  as  one  of  qabdlah,  namely,  an  undertaking 
to  pay  the  khardj  in  return  for  their  cultivation.  Later  Shafiites  ( Tan- 
blh,  p.  300;  Wajlz,  vol.  ii,  p.  201 ;  Afugni,  vol.  iv,  p.  217;  cf.  Mawardi, 
P-  303),  on  the  other  hand,  consider  it  a  case  of  perpetual  lease  (ijdrah 
tnu'abbadah) ,  the  khardj  levied  being  a  rental  pure  and  simple.  Ap- 
parently the  theory  is  that  such  lands  are  governed  by  the  principles 
of  location  (ijdrah}  in  general.  Probably  these  facts  account  for  the 
silence  of  the  two  schools  on  this  subject. 

*  Tec h.  Diet.,  p.  409. 

377 


378  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

The  kharaj  is  levied  only  on  the  lands  which  come  under 
the  description  of  kharaj  lands,  as  explained  in  the  last  sec- 
tion, and  is  of  two  kinds,  the  proportional  kharaj  (kharaj 
muqasamah)  and  the  fixed  kharaj  (kharaj  wazifah  or  mu- 
wassaf).1 

The  Proportional  Kharaj  consists  in  a  proportion  of  the 
produce  of  the  ground,  like  one-half,  one-third,  one-fourth, 
or  one-fifth  of  the  same.  The  Kharaj  wazlfah,  on  the  con- 
trary, is  a  fixed  charge  on  the  ground,  at  so  much  of  natural 
produce  or  money  per  unit  area  or  per  tree. 

The  kharaj  is  levied  on  land  irrespective  of  whether  the 
owner  is  a  minor  or  adult,  free  or  slave  (mukatab),  man  or 
woman,  Moslem  or  infidel.  Consequently  if  the  dhimmi 
owner  of  the  land  is  converted  to  Islam,  or  if  he  sells  his 
land  to  a  Moslem,  the  land  is  still  subject  to  kharaj.  How- 
ever, Malik  said  that  in  such  case  the  kharaj  is  remitted 
exactly  as  the  jizyah  is  remitted. 

In  the  case  of  the  fixed  kharaj  the  rates  imposed  by  the 
calif  Omar  on  the  lands  of  Sawad  in  'Iraq  constitute  the 

1  Max  Van  Berchem  (p.  53),  inferring  from  al-Baladhuri's  use  of  the 
word  muqdta'ah,  distinguishes  a  third  kind  of  khardj,  the  kharaj 
muqata'ah.  He  means  by  it  the  khardj  paid  as  a  lump  sum  by  certain 
tributary  provinces,  especially  such  of  them  as  were  on  the  border  of 
the  Moslem  empire  and  had  been  able  to  preserve  their  autonomy.  On 
the  other  hand,  according  to  the  Persian  commentary  of  al-Mawardi's 
al-Ahkdm  al-Sultdniyyah  (Mawardi,  pp.  33  et  seq.  of  the  notes)  the 
word  muqdta'ah  denotes  the  lump  sum  agreed  upon  to  be  paid  yearly 
to  the  state  by  individuals  in  consideration  of  (public)  lands  made  over 
to  them  by  the  state.  The  commentary  adds  that  this  procedure  was 
followed  as  regards  waste  lands  which  needed  development  or  villages 
and  estates  which  needed  improvement.  The  ' Alamkiriyyah  (vol.  ii, 
p.  344)  seems  to  use  the  word  in  this  second  sense  when  it  says  that 
the  imam  may  give  away,  in  the  form  of  muqdta'ah,  khardj  lands  aban- 
doned by  their  owners.  The  standard  books  on  fiqh  do  not  discuss 
either  one  of  these  two  meanings  of  muqdta'ah.  The  only  reference 
to  it  which  I  have  come  across  is  in  the  Jdmi'  (p.  331)  to  the  effect 
that  the  khardj  wazlfah  is  also  called  khardj  muqdta'ah.  For  definitions 
of  terms  pertaining  to  tax  administration,  see  Mafdtlh  (pp.  58-62.) 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  379 

lawful  rates  and  may  not  be  augmented.  These  rates  were 
collected  from  every  land  fit  for  cultivation  and  accessible 
to  water,  at  the  rate  of  one  sa'  of  barley  or  wheat  and  one 
dirham  from  every  jarib  of  barley  or  wheat,  and  according 
to  al-Shafi'i,  from  the  wheat  four,  and  from  the  barley  two 
dirhams;  and  from  every  jarib  of  trefoil  (ratbah)  five  dir- 
hams,  and  according  to  al-Shafi'i  six ;  and  from  every  jarib 
of  closely  planted  trees  (karm),  vines  and  palms  ten,  and 
according  to  al-Shafi'i  eight  dirhams,  but  according  to  al- 
Mawardi,  from  the  trees  ten  and  the  palms  eight  dir- 
hams, and  the  sugar-cane  six  dirhams.1  The  above  taxes 
concerning  trees  applied  only  in  case  they  were  closely 
planted  in  such  a  way  that  cultivation  of  the  intervening 
space  was  impossible,  for  isolated  trees  growing  in  cultivated 
fields  were  exempt  from  tax,  for  the  land  was  then  taxed 
as  a  cultivated  land.2 

In  other  than  the  above  cases,  namely,  in  cases  concern- 
ing which  there  is  no  precedent  of  the  calif  Omar,  for  in- 
stance, in  saffron  or  in  gardens  (bust&n),3  the  kharaj  is 
assessed  according  to  the  tax-bearing  capacity  (taqah)  of 
the  lands,  and  as  the  limit  of  tax-bearing  capacity  (gay at 
al-tOqati)  has  been  fixed  by  Hanifite  doctors  at  half  of  the 
entire  produce,  in  no  case  may  the  rate  exceed  half  the  entire 
produce,  whether  or  not  the  rates  were  fixed  in  accordance 

1  Other  variants  of  the  above  numbers,  as  found  in  Abu  Yusuf,  al- 
Mawardi,  and  al-Baladhuri,  are  for  palms  five,  vines  eight,  meadows  and 
cotton  plantations  five,  and  for  sesame  five  dirhams.  According  to  one 
report,  palms  were  taxed  on  the  basis  of  feet,  as  under  the  Sassanides, 
and  according  to  another  report,  palms  were  exempt  from  tax.  How- 
ever, this  last  report  applied  to  isolated  palm  trees  found  in  cultivated 
fields,  which  were  exempt  from  tax  already  under  the  Sassanides  (Ber- 
chem,  p.  50,  fn.  i.) 

1  Fa/A,  vol.  v,  p.  282,  1.  6. 

*  Bustdn  here  means  any  enclosure  of  trees  sufficiently  apart  to  allow 
of  cultivation  in  the  intervening  spaces.  It  is  the  opposite  of  karm. 


380  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

with  the  precedent  of  Omar  and  whether  the  kharaj  is  fixed 
or  proportional.  This  is  because  Omar  himself  in  assessing 
the  rates  above  mentioned  took  into  consideration  the  tax- 
bearing  capacity  of  the  land. 

If  then  a  land  cannot  stand  the  rate  of  kharaj  imposed 
upon  it,  the  rate  may  be  reduced  to  what  it  can  stand,  but 
it  is  not  allowed  in  any  case  to  increase  the  rates  imposed 
by  Omar  or,  for  that  matter,  by  another  imam,  in  accord- 
ance with  the  rates  imposed  by  Omar,  even  if  the  land  can 
stand  a  higher  rate.  According  to  the  Durr*  the  kharaj 
may  in  no  case  fall  short  of  one-fifth  of  the  entire  produce, 
as  it  may  not  exceed  one-half  of  it.  If,  however,  a  piece 
of  land  is  assessed  for  the  first  time,  according  to  Abu 
Hanifah  and  Abu  Yusuf ,  it  is  still  unlawful  to  assess  higher 
rates  than  those  assessed  by  Omar,  because  Omar  said  to 
his  agents  'Uthman  and  Hudhayfah  who  had  assessed  the 
kharaj  of  Sawad :  "  Perhaps  you  assessed  the  land  with  a 
rate  which  it  cannot  stand?",  and  they  said:  "  No,  on  the 
contrary,  we  have  assessed  it  with  a  rate  which  it  can  stand, 
but  if  we  had  assessed  a  higher  rate  the  land  could  still 
stand  it."  These  words  indicate  that  the  rate  may  be  re- 
duced if  the  land  cannot  stand  it,  but  that  it  may  not  be  in- 
creased even  if  it  can  stand  it,  for  Omar,  although  informed 
that  the  land  could  stand  more,  did  not  order  an  increase  of 
rate.  According  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  however, 
higher  rates  may  be  assessed,  since  the  rates  are  determined 
on  the  basis  of  the  tax-bearing  capacity  of  the  land.2 

According  to  al-Mawardi,3  if  the  crop  is  one  on  which 
there  is  no  legal  prescription  (nass),  it  pays  the  rate  pre- 
scribed in  the  shart'ah  for  the  crop  that  most  resembles  it  in 
appearance  and  profits. 

1  P.  365.  J  Hiddyah,  vol.  v,  p.  283. 

8  P.  262. 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  381 

Al-Mawardi  *  discusses  as  follows  the  factors  which  de- 
termine the  tax-bearing  capacity  (taqah)  of  land.  The 
person  who  assesses  the  kharaj  on  a  piece  of  land  should 
consider  the  capacity  of  land,  which  varies  according  to 
three  factors,  each  factor  affecting  the  amount  of  kliardj 
more  or  less.  One  of  these  factors  pertaining  to  the  land 
itself  is  the  quality  of  the  land  by  virtue  of  which  the  crop 
grown  on  it  is  rich,  or  the  defect  which  causes  the  produce 
to  be  small.  The  second  factor  relates  to  the  kind  of  crop, 
since  grains  and  fruits  vary  in  price,  some  fetching  a  higher 
price  than  the  others,  and  the  kharaj  must  therefore  be 
assessed  accordingly.  The  third  factor  pertains  to  the 
method  of  irrigation,  for  the  crop  that  has  been  irrigated 
with  water  carried  on  the  back  of  beasts  or  raised  by  a  water- 
wheel,  cannot  stand  the  same  rate  of  kliardj  which  could  be 
charged  on  land  watered  by  running  water  or  rain. 

The  irrigation  of  crops  and  trees  may  be  effected  in  four 
ways:  Artificial  irrigation  without  the  use  of  any  in- 
strument, that  is,  by  means  of  running  water  derived  from 
springs  and  rivers,  by  turning  their  course  to  the  field 
to  be  watered.  This  way  is  by  far  the  most  profitable  and 
least  expensive,  inasmuch  as  the  water  is  turned  on  when 
needed,  and  turned  off  when  enough  of  it  has  been  used. 

(2)  Artificial   irrigation   by  means  of   some   instrument, 
*•   9-y   by   water   carried   on   the  back   of   beasts,    or   by 
buckets    or   waterwheels,    this   way   being   the   most    ex- 
pensive, and  the  one  that  entails  the  greatest  hardship. 

(3)  Natural  irrigation  by  means  of  rain  or  snow  or  dew. 

(4)  Irrigation  by  means  of  the  humidity  of  soil,  or  by  water 
concealed  underground.     In  this  case  the  crops  and  trees 
are  irrigated  by  means  of  their  roots. 

Irrigation  by  means  of  conduits  falls  under  the  first  class 
if  the  water  used  is  running  water,  and  under  the  second 

1  P.  257  et  seq. 


3g2  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

class  if  not  so.  Again,  irrigation  by  water  derived  from 
wells  belongs  in  the  second  class  if  the  water  is  carried  on 
the  back  of  beasts,  and  in- the  first  if  drawn  (ustukhrija) 
through  conduits. 

The  assessor  of  kharaj,  therefore,  in  estimating  the 
amount  of  tax  to  be  assessed  on  a  piece  of  land,  should 
take  into  consideration  the  above-named  three  factors, 
namely,  the  quality  of  land,  the  kind  of  crop,  and  the 
method  of  irrigation.  In  this  way  justice  is  attained,  as 
between  the  beneficiaries  of  the  fa'y  and  the  taxpayer,  since 
neither  the  latter  is  overburdened  nor  the  former  are 
prejudiced. 

Some  have  recognized  a  fourth  factor,  namely  the  dis- 
tance of  the  land  from  cities  and  markets,  because  the  price 
increases  or  decreases  according  as  this  distance  is  shorter 
or  longer,  but  this  concerns  only  the  case  in  which  kharaj 
is  paid  in  silver  (i.  e.,  specie),  and  does  not  apply  to  the 
collection  of  the  tax  in  grain  (kind),  whereas  the  three 
factors  above-mentioned  apply  equally  in  both  cases. 

When  the  kharaj  has  been  fixed  by  reference  to  the  above- 
mentioned  principles,  it  is  assessed  on  the  ground  according 
to  the  most  profitable  of  the  following  three  ways:  It  is 
assessed  on  the  area  of  the  land,  or  on  the  area  of  the  cul- 
tivated portion  of  the  land,  or,  finally,  on  the  produce  as  a 
definite  proportion  of  the  same.  When  the  kharaj  is  as- 
sessed on  the  area  of  the  entire  land  the  year  used  is  the 
lunar  year,  and  if  the  kharaj  is  assessed  on  the  cultivated 
area,  the  year  used  is  the  solar  year,  but  if  the  kharaj  is 
proportional,  the  tax  is  due  when  the  crop  is  ripe  and  the 
grain  ready  for  consumption. 

When  any  one  of  these  three  alternatives  has  been  settled 
upon,  one  is  not  allowed  to  change  *  it  to  another  but  it  is 

1  Cf.  Babr,  vol.  v,  p.  116. 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  383 

continued  for  ever,  and  hence  the  tax  may  not  be  increased 
or  decreased  so  long  as  the  land  continues  to  remain  the 
same  with  respect  to  its  irrigation  and  advantages  (ma- 
salih). 

If,  however,  the  land  changes  as  to  its  method  of  irriga- 
tion and  its  advantages,  then  there  are  two  cases  conceiv- 
able :  ( i )  The  change  is  caused  by  an  act  of  the  landowner, 
e.  g.,  the  productivity  of  the  land  is  increased  by  means  of 
water  diverted  from  a  river  or  derived  from  the  ground, 
or  on  the  contrary,  it  is  decreased  owing  to  negligence  in 
cultivation  and  defective  methods.  In  this  case  the  kharaj 
is  left  as  it  is;  not  being  increased  for  increased  produc- 
tivity, or  diminished  for  decreased  productivity.  The 
owner,  however,  is  reproved,  in  order  that  he  may  cultivate 
the  land  so  that  it  may  not  go  to  waste.  (2)  The  change 
has  occurred  owing  to  no  act  of  the  owner,  but  by  reason 
of  a  natural  contingency,  either  to  the  advantage  or  the  dis- 
advantage of  the  land:  (a)  When  the  change  is  to  the  dis- 
advantage, c.  g.,  when  the  valley  subsides,  or  the  river  dries 
up,  if  repair  is  possible,  it  is  the  duty  of  the  imam  to  use 
for  this  purpose  the  revenue  appropriated  for  works  of 
public  utility,  namely,  from  the  share  of  masGlih;  and  the 
kharaj  is  remitted  to  the  landowner  for  the  time  the  land 
has  lain  uncultivated.  The  Hanifite  view  is  to  the  same 
effect.1  If,  however,  repair  is  not  possible;  in  case,  for  in- 
stance, the  land  cannot  be  cultivated;  the  kharaj  is  defini- 
tively remitted  if  the  land  cannot  be  utilized  in  some  other 
way,  for  instance,  as  a  pasture  or  hunting  ground.  But  if 
it  can  be  used  for  some  other  purpose,  then  the  land  pays 
the  rate  of  kharaj  levied  on  similar  lands,  (b)  When,  on 
the  other  hand,  the  change  results  to  the  advantage  of  the 
land,  e.  g.,  when  the  river  follows  a  new  course  and  as  a  re- 

1  Cf.  'Alamklriyyah,  vol.  ii,  p.  345. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

suit,  the  land  is  irrigated  in  the  future  by  running  water  in- 
stead of  by  artificial  means,  if  the  change  is  not  believed  to  be 
permanent,  the  tax  is  not  increased,  but  if  the  change  is 
believed  to  be  permanent,  then  the  imam  increases  the  tax 
or  desists  from  so  doing  according  as  he  hold  one  or  the 
other  course  to  be  in  the  best  interests  of  both  the  land 
owner  and  the  beneficiaries  of  the  tax. 

If  a  piece  of  land  cannot  be  cultivated  every  year,  but 
must  be  allowed  to  lie  fallow  every  other  year,  this  fact  is 
taken  into  account  when  the  kharaj  is  first  assessed,  and  one 
of  the  following  three  methods  is  applied  with  a  view  to 
reconciling  the  interests  of  both  sides.  Half  of  the  regular 
rate  on  the  cultivated  portion  is  collected  on  the  entire  field ; 
or  every  two  jaribs  are  counted  as  one  single  jarib  in  order 
to  allow  for  the  uncultivated  portion;  or,  finally,  the  full 
rate  is  assessed  on  the  cultivated  portion  only.1 

According  to  the  Hidayah,2  if  a  person  without  excuse 
changes  from  a  kind  of  crop  that  pays  a  high  rate  of  kharaj 
to  one  that  pays  a  lower  rate  he  still  pays  the  higher  rate, 
because  he  is  responsible  for  the  decrease  of  the  rate.  The 
Hidayah,  however,  does  not  recommend  this  view  (la  yufta 
bihi)  because  it  would  give  an  excuse  to  tyrants  to  oppress 
the  Moslems  by  forcing  them  to  cultivate  crops  which 
require  great  pains. 

If  a  person  plants  in  his  farmland  vines  or  fruit-bearing 
trees,  he  continues  to  pay  on  his  land  the  kharaj  of  crops 
until  the  new  plants  shall  have  borne  fruit,  and  he  then  pays 

1  There  is  in  the  text  a  statement  to  the  effect  that  in  such  case  "  one- 
half  of  the  produce  "  is  taken.  This  statement  was  omitted  as  inconsis- 
tent with  the  previous  sentence  where  it  was  said  that  "the  whole  of  the 
tax  is  assessed  ".  If  the  whole  of  the  tax  is  only  one-fifth,  one  cannot 
evidently  collect  "half  of  the  produce."  The  variants  of  the  text  in- 
dicated at  the  bottom  of  the  page  confirm  the  suspicion  that  the  text 
at  this  point  suffered  corruption. 

*  Vol.  v,  p.  285. 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  385 

ten  dirhams  per  jarib,  if  the  value  of  the  fruits  is  twenty  or 
more  dirhams ;  and  if  their  value  is  less  than  this,  he  pays 
half  of  that  value,  provided  it  does  not  fall  short  of  the 
equivalent  of  one  qajiz  of  grain  and  one  dirliam,  because 
that  is  the  least  rate  that  a  jarib  of  land  pays  when  its  cul- 
tivation is  possible. 

The  kharaj  is  due  on  land  irrespective  of  whether  or  not 
the  owner  cultivated  the  land,  provided  that  he  has  been 
able  to  do  so,  because  the  reason  for  klwraj  is  the  produc- 
tivity of  land,  and  the  owner  by  not  cultivating  his  land, 
notwithstanding  that  it  was  productive,  has  deprived  the 
beneficiaries  of  kharaj  from  their  revenue.1  According  to 
Malik,  the  owner  pays  no  kharaj  if  the  land  was  not  culti- 
vated, whether  or  not  he  had  an  excuse  for  not  cultivating 
it.2  If  the  owner  was  unable  to  cultivate  his  land  because 
he  lacked  the  means  to  do  so,  the  imam  is  entitled  to  lease 
the  land  to  another  farmer  by  way  of  muzara'ah?  and  col- 
lect the  tax  from  the  owner's  share  of  the  produce,  or  to 
lease  the  land  to  a  tenant  and  collect  it  from  the  rental,  or, 
finally,  to  have  the  land  cultivated  at  the  expense  of  the  pub- 
lic treasury  and  collect  the  tax  from  the  owner's  share. 
According  to  the  ' Alamklriyyah*  a  similar  course  is  fol- 

1  Mabsiit,  part  x,  p.  82. 

1  Mawardi,  p.  261. 

5  Muzdra'ah  is  an  agreement  between  the  owner  of  a  farm  and  a 
farmer  that  the  latter  shall  cultivate  the  farm  in  consideration  of  a 
certain  proportion  of  the  produce.  It  is  also  called  ntukhdbarah.  The 
term  muzdra'ah  applies  to  the  cultivation  of  grains,  while  the  terms 
mu'dmalah  and  musdqdt  are  used  with  respect  to  trees.  Mufldrabah  is 
the  counterpart  of  the  same  idea  with  respect  to  trade,  meaning  a  part- 
nership between  the  principal  (rabb  al-mdl)  who  owns  the  stock  and 
the  trader  (mu^drib)  who  contributes  the  labor  for  a  part  of  the 
profits.  If  all  the  profit  is  to  belong  to  the  capital  owner  (mubd?)  the 
transaction  is  called  bidd'ah,  and  the  person  who  trades  with  it 
mustabd?. 

4  Vol.  ii,  p.  344. 


386  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

lowed  if  the  owners  abandon  their  lands,  or  if  one  of  them 
dies.  However,  according  to  a  report  from  Abu  Hanifah, 
when  the  kharaj  people  abandon  their  lands  the  imam  may 
have  them  cultivated  at  public  expense,  or  lease  (muqata'ah) 
them,  the  entire  income  belonging  to  the  public.  If  none  of 
the  above  mentioned  courses  is  possible,  the  imam  sells  the 
land  and  collects  the  tax  from  the  price,  returning  the 
balance  to  the  owner.1  Should  the  owner  later  again  be  able 
to  cultivate  his  land,  it  is  returned  to  him  unless,  indeed  it 
has  been  sold. 

According  to  al-Mawardi,2  if  m  the  above-mentioned 
case  of  neglect  of  cultivation  the  kharaj  levied  on  the  land 
would  differ  with  the  kind  of  crop  raised,  only  the 
lowest  of  the  possible  rates  is  collected  from  the  owner, 
for  if  the  latter,  instead  of  entirely  neglecting  the  cultiva- 
tion, had  only  raised  the  crop  subject  to  that  lowest  rate,  he 
would  have  been  within  his  right. 

According  to  the  Path*  there  is  a  reliable  report  from 
Abu  Yusuf  to  the  effect  that  when  the  owner  is  unable  to 
cultivate  the  land,  the  public  treasury  should  advance  him 
as  a  loan  the  necessary  funds. 

According  to  al-Mawardi, *  however,  when  the  owner 
lacks  the  means  of  cultivation,  he  is  told  either  to  lease  his 
land  to  another  person  or  to  forego  his  possession  (yad)  of 
the  land  in  order  that  it  may  be  turned  over  to  a  person 
who  can  cultivate  it;  for  the  land  is  not  allowed  to  go  to 
waste  even  if  its  kharaj  is  paid,  because  it  would  then  be- 
come waste  (mawat)  land. 

According  to  the  Durr,5  all  the  above  applies  to  the  fixed 
kharaj  only,  provided  the  owner  is  not  prevented  from  cul- 

1  Bahr,  vol.  v,  p.  118. 

2  Pp.  261-2.  '  Vol.  v,  p.  285. 
*  P.  264.  5  P.  365. 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  387 

tivating  his  land.  For  if  he  is  so  prevented  or  if  the  kharaj 
is  of  the  proportional  kind,  no  kharaj  is  due  on  the  land. 

In  the  Bahr  it  is  said  that  since  the  kharaj  levied  on  the 
lands  of  Egypt  is  in  reality  a  rental,  the  cultivators  (fal- 
Idh)  should  not  be  obliged  to  pay  the  kharaj  when  they  do 
not  cultivate  the  land  and  are  not  tenants  thereof.1  Further- 
more, it  is  unjust  to  oppress  the  farmers  when  they  abandon 
agriculture  and  settle  in  the  cities,  especially  when  they  do 
so  in  order  to  engage  in  the  study  of  the  sharfah. 

With  respect  to  the  present  land  holders  of  Syria,  Ibn 
'Abidm2  remarks  that,  being  mere  cultivators  of  the  land  for 
a  part  of  the  produce  ( nut-sari')  t  they  may  not  lease  (I jar) 
their  holdings  in  consideration  of  a  rental  (ujrah)  to  be 
collected  by  themselves  from  the  lessees  (nmsta'jir)  over 
and  above  what  is  already  paid  by  the  latter  to  the  imam. 
Consequently  the  above-mentioned  practice  of  the  cultivators 
(mitsari')  of  the  sultaniyyah  (i.  £.,  amiriyyah)  and  waqf 
lands  betokens  their  ignorance,  and  so  "  I  have  rendered 
a  fatwa  to  the  effect  that  it  is  not  lawful  ".  According 
to  the  Tatarkhaniyyah,  as  quoted  by  Ibn  'Abidin,  the  so- 
called  al-aradi  al-mamlakah  (i.  e.,  annriyyah),  namely, 
lands  without  owners,  may  be  given  away  to  people  on  con- 
dition of  payment  of  kharaj  by  them.  This  is  lawful  on 
one  of  these  two  grounds :  either  the  people  in  question  be- 
come like  owners  (iqdmah  maqam  al-mulldk  fi  l'-zirdfah  wa 
i'tff  al-kharaj)  so  far  as  cultivation  and  the  payment  of 
kharaj  is  concerned;  or  it  is  a  case  of  lease  (ijdrah)  at  a 
rental  equal  to  the  kharaj,  and  in  such  case,  the  amount  col- 
lected from  the  lessees  is  kJiardj  as  regards  the  imam, 
though  it  is  rental  as  regards  them.  Ibn  'Abidin  concludes 
from  this  quotation  that  the  cultivators  of  Syrian  lands 

1  Bahr,  vol.  v,  p.  118. 
1  Mwthah,  vol.  v,  p.  114. 


388  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

should  not  pay  the  tithe  (fushr),  for  if  the  tax  already  col- 
lected from  them  is  kharaj;  it  is  a  well-known  principle  that 
the  kharaj  and  the  tithe  are  never  levied  on  the  same  land ; 
and  if,  on  the  other  hand,  it  is  rental,  it  is  again  well-known 
that,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  the  tithe  should  be  levied 
on  the  lessor  (mu'jir) — though  according  to  his  two  dis- 
ciples it  is  levied  on  the  leaseholder — "  however,  what  is 
collected  is  not  rental  in  every  respect  since  it  is  kharaj  as 
regards  the  imam.  Reflect  on  it." 

If  there  is  in  a  piece  of  land  a  thick  wood  with  plenty  of 
game,  no  kharaj  is  paid  on  the  land;  but  if  the  land  is  grow- 
ing reeds  or  tamarisks  or  pinetrees  or  willows  or  other  non- 
fruit-bearing  trees,  the  owner  pays  kharaj  if  he  can  clear 
the  ground  and  grow  crops  on  it;  otherwise  he  is  exempt 
from  the  tax.  The  same  principle  applies  if,  instead  of  trees, 
there  are  salt  deposits  on  the  land.1 

If  a  person  owns  a  village  situated  on  kharaj  lands,  he 
pays  no  kharaj  for  the  houses  and  dwellings  of  the  village 
whether  or  not  he  leases  them.  Likewise,  if  a  person  con- 
verts part  of  his  habitation  situated  in  a  Moslem  city  into  a 
field,  he  pays  no  kharaj  on  the  field  because  the  field  is  con- 
sidered a  dependency  of  the  house  and  houses  are  exempt 
from  taxes;  but  if  he  turns  the  whole  of  his  habitation  into 
a  field,  then  he  pays  for  it  the  kharaj,  provided  it  is  kharaj 
land.  On  the  other  hand,  if  a  person  turns  his  kharaj  land 
into  a  habitation  he  pays  kharaj  for  it.2  According  to  al- 
Mawardi,3  such  part  of  the  land  as  is  covered  with  build- 
ings which  are  indispensable  should  be  exempted  from  the 
tax.4 

1  'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  ii,  p.  345. 
8  'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  ii,  p.  341. 
1  P.  263. 
4  Cf.  Kharashi,  p.  427. 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  389 

The  kharaj  becomes  due  only  once  a  year,  even  if  the 
land  should  grow  during  the  year  many  crops,  because  the 
calif  Omar  collected  from  the  lands  of  the  dhimmis  only 
once  a  year,  and  because  lands  in  general  grow  only  one 
single  crop  during  a  year,  and  the  law  is  rather  concerned 
with  general  cases  than  with  exceptions.1  Of  course  this 
applies  to  the  fixed  klwrcij  only,  as  the  proportional  kharSj, 
like  tithe,  is  collected  every  time  a  crop  has  been  grown.2 

A  land  subject  to  kharaj  does  not  also  pay  tithe  under 
any  circumstances  according  to  the  Hanifite  school,  but  the 
other  two  schools  allow  the  combination  (ijtimtf)  of  the 
two  taxes. 

The  kharaj  lapses  if  the  entire  crop  has  been  destroyed 
(istilam)  as  a  result  of  unavoidable  natural  forces  (afat), 
such  as  the  subsiding  of  the  land,  fire,  extreme  cold,  etc. 
If,  however,  the  crop  was  destroyed  in  consequence  of 
avoidable  agencies,  such  as  wild  birds,  or  if  the  crop  is  de- 
stroyed after  harvest,  the  tax  is  not  remitted.  Some  say 
that  the  tax  is  remitted  only  if  the  year  is  too  far  spent 
to  allow  the  farmer  to  cultivate  again.  According  to 
the  Path  this  time  has  been  fixed  at  three  months.  All  the 
above  applies  in  case  the  entire  crop  has  been  destroyed, 
for  if  only  part  of  it  has  been  destroyed  the  whole  of  the 
tax  is  collected,  if  the  remaining  part  is  still  sufficient  for 
the  settlement  of  the  tax  twice  over;  however,  only  half 
of  the  remaining  part  is  collected,  no  matter  how  little, 
if  such  part  is  less  than  the  khar&j.  According  to  the 
'Alamklriyyah*  the  leading  Hanifite  doctors  hold  the  view 
that  the  proper  thing  to  do  in  this  last  case  is  to  deduct 
from  the  remaining  produce,  before  everything  else,  the 


t,  part  x,  p.  82. 
*Majmo',  p.  515;  Jdmi',  p.  330;  Mawardi,  p.  260. 
8  VoL  ii,  p.  345- 


390  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

expenses  of  the  farmer,  and  then  proceed  as  explained.  The 
reason  for  the  remission  of  the  tax  in  case  of  destruction  is 
that  the  farmer  has  been  stricken  with  adversity  and  deserves 
assistance,  since  the  opposite  policy  would  result  in  his  ex- 
termination. Besides,  one  of  the  virtues  for  which  the  Per- 
sian kings  have  been  praised  has  been  their  policy,  in  case 
of  the  destruction  of  the  entire  crop,  of  returning  to  the 
owners  (dihqan)  from  their  treasuries  their  expenses  of 
cultivation;  and  therefore,  if  such  expenses  are  not  re- 
turned, at  least  the  kharaj  must  be  remitted.  Moreover, 
when  the  entire  crop  has  been  destroyed,  it  has  become  ap- 
parent that  the  possibility  of  deriving  a  benefit  from  the 
land  has  been  absent,  but  the  kharaj  is  due  only  when  such 
possibility  has  existed.1 

If  the  owner  sells  his  land  during  the  year,  the  kharaj  is 
paid  by  the  buyer  if  cultivation  is  possible  during  the  re- 
maining part  of  the  year;  otherwise  the  kharaj  is  paid  by 
the  seller.  According  to  the  Tatarkhaniyyah,  this  applies  in 
case  the  land  was  sold  free  of  cultivation.  For  if  a  land 
already  under  cultivation  is  sold  with  its  crop  before  it  has 
as  yet  grown  the  kharaj  is  in  every  case  paid  by  the  buyer. 
If,  on  the  contrary,  the  crop  has  grown,  it  is  the  same  as  if 
the  land  was  sold  free  of  cultivation.  According  to  a  report 
from  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  if  a  kharaj  land  is  sold  suc- 
cessively from  person  to  person  so  that  the  land  has  not  been 
in  the  possession  of  any  one  person  for  at  least  three  months, 
no  one  of  the  buyers  is  subject  to  payment  of  kharaj.  In 
deciding  whether  there  was  enough  time  left  for  cultivating, 
the  time  necessary  for  the  cultivation,  according  to  some 
doctors,  of  wheat  or  barley,  and  according  to  others,  of  any 
crop,  is  taken  as  the  basis,  but  according  to  the  Waqi'at  of 
al-Natifi,  this  time  is  fixed  at  three  months. 

1  Mabsat,  part  x,  p.  83. 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX 

According  to  al-Ramli,1  the  proportional  kharaj  is  like 
the  fixed  kharaj  as  regards  its  appropriation,  but  like  tithe 
in  all  other  respects:  namely,  in  that  every  produce  which 
may  be  subject  to  tithe  may  be  also  subject  to  the  propor- 
tional kharaj,  and  that  it  is  like  tithe  a  charge  on  the  produce 
and  hence  due  every  time  there  is  a  produce.  It  is  claimed, 
according  to  the  Jami',  that  the  proportional  kharaj  is  not 
due  if  the  land  has  been  allowed  to  lie  idle,  even  if  cultiva- 
tion was  possible;  that  although  some  hold  the  contrary, 
the  farmer  may  consume  a  reasonable  part  of  the  produce 
before  the  tax  has  been  paid,  the  fixed  kharaj  being  like  the 
proportional  in  this  respect;  that  the  tax  is  remitted  if  the 
product  is  destroyed,  even  though  after  the  harvest ;  that  in- 
debtedness does  not  exempt  from  its  payment;  finally,  that 
the  payment  of  the  tax  need  not  be  made  as  soon  as  the  tax 
falls  due,  subject,  however  to  the  same  divergence  of  view 
as  tithe. 

The  farmer  may  bestow  alms  from  his  crop  before  the 
kharaj  has  been  demanded  by  the  sultan,  but  not  after. 
If  the  sultan  makes  to  the  kharaj  payer  a  gift  of  his  kharaj 
debt,  it  is  lawful  according  to  Abu  Yusuf,  and  unlawful 
according  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan.  The  view  of  Abu 
Yusuf  is  the  one  generally  recommended,  provided  the 
kharaj  payer  is  one  of  the  beneficiaries  of  kharaj  revenue. 
In  tithe,  however,  according  to  all,  the  amount  constituting 
the  present  must  be  made  good  to  the  sadaqah  treasury  from 
the  kharaj  treasury  unless  the  tithe  payer  was  poor.  It  is 
allowed  to  collect  the  entire  amount  of  the  fixed  kharaj  in 
specie,  since  the  object  in  view  is  that  the  tax  should  equal 
the  capacity  of  the  land.  As  in  proportional  kharaj,  a 
charge  of  debt  does  not  exempt  the  land  from  the  kharaj. 
Finally,  a  debt  of  kharaj  of  either  kind  does  not  lapse  upon 

1  Bahr,  Minhah,  vol.  v,  p.  1 16. 


392  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  death  of  the  land  owner,  but  is  collected  from  his  estate. 
However,  according  to  the  Mabsut,1  if  the  owner  of  the 
kharaj  land  dies  before  the  collection  of  the  kharaj,  the  latter 
lapses  and  is  not  collected  from  the  estate.  This  is  because, 
like  the  kharaj  of  heads,  the  kharaj  of  lands  also  has  the 
meaning  of  humiliation.  Moreover,  it  cannot  be  collected 
from  the  heirs,  for  although  they  own  the  land,  they  could 
not  use  it  before  the  death  of  the  deceased. 

According  to  al-Mawardi,2  if  the  kharaj  land  is  leased 
with  or  without  a  rental,  the  tax  is  collected  from  the  land 
owner,  and  not  from  the  lease  holder;  but  Abu  Hanifah 
holds  that  the  tax  is  paid  by  the  lease  holder  if  the  lease  was 
made  without  a  rental,  and  by  the  owner  in  the  other  case. 
Abu  Hanifah's  two  disciples  hold  the  same  view  as  al-Ma- 
wardi.* 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah,4  in  the  collection  of  kharaj 
the  taxpayers  must  be  treated  with  consideration  and  justice, 
and  the  kharaj  must  be  collected  in  instalments,  namely, 
from  each  crop  must  be  taken  its  proportionate  share  of  the 
year's  kharaj.  For  instance,  if  a  piece  of  land  grows  two 
crops,  when  the  first  crop  is  taxed,  only  half  of  the  year's 
kharaj  is  collected  by  the  collector  if  he  thinks  that  the  sec- 
ond crop  will  be  as  good  as  the  first ;  and  so  on  for  the  rest. 

If  one  is  unable  to  pay  his  kharaj  debt 6  he  is  allowed  to 
delay  its  payment  until  his  finances  improve.  Abu  Hani- 
fah says  that  the  kharaj  is  due  only  when  the  landowner 
can  pay  it,  and  that  it  lapses  when  he  is  unable  to  pay  it.  If, 
however,  a  person  delays  the  payment  of  his  kharaj  debt, 

'Part  iii,  p.  50. 

*  P.  263;  cf.  Umm,  vol.  iii,  p.  240. 

8  'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  ii,  p.  340. 

4  'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  ii,  pp.  342,  346. 

8  Mawardi,  p.  264. 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  393 

notwithstanding  his  ability  to  pay  it,  he  is  put  in  prison 
for  it,  unless  there  is  discovered  some  of  his  property.  In 
such  case  the  property  is  sold  and  the  debt  settled  out  of 
the  sale  price,  just  as  this  is  done  for  the  recovery  of  ordi- 
nary claims.  If  the  debtor  has  no  other  property  than  the 
kharaj  land,  the  imam,  if  he  sees  fit,  sells  enough  of  the 
land  to  settle  the  debt,  or  he  leases  the  land  and  settles  the 
debt  from  the  rental  and  returns  the  rest  to  the  land  owner. 
According  to  the  '  Alamkiriyyah,1  the  sultan  may  keep 
under  control  (hobs)  the  produce  of  the  land  until  the 
kharaj  is  collected. 

According  to  a  report  from  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,3 
if  one  pays  in  advance  ('ajjala)  'the  kharaj  of  his  land  for 
one  or  two  years,  it  is  lawful.  If  subsequently  the  land  is 
flooded  with  water,  the  kharaj  is  returned  to  the  landowner 
if  it  remained  intact.  According  to  the  Muntaqa,  the  kharaj 
is  returned,  or  reckoned  as  payment  on  account  of  the 
kharaj  of  the  next  year. 

If  the  kharaj  has  been  collected  once  by  rebels  and  schis- 
matics it  is  not  collected  again  by  the  imam  when  he  re- 
covers control  over  the  taxpayers,  for  taxation  is  based  on 
protection  and  in  this  instance  the  imam  has  evidently  failed 
to  protect  them.3  The  view  expressed  by  al-Mawardi  *  is 
practically  to  the  same  effect. 

In  settling  the  kharaj  in  specie,6  only  gold  and  silver 
coins  which  are  not  mixed  with  baser  metals  (gishsh)  are 
to  be  accepted.  Again,  only  those  of  these  coins  bearing 
the  impression  of  the  sultan  are  accepted,  because  they 

1  Vol.  ii,  p.  346. 

1  Ibid. 

•Ma/ma',  p.  167;  Hiddyah,  p.  150;  Kasani,  p.  36. 

4  P.  225. 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  269-72. 


394  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

alone  are  reliable  and  secure  from  counterfeiting  or  other 
source  of  loss.  Consequently,  ingots  of  gold  and  silver  are 
not  accepted,  because  they  are  not  reliable  and  may  not  be 
depended  upon  unless  tested  by  melting.  If  more  than  one 
impressed  coin  of  the  same  degree  of  purity  of  metal  but  of 
different  value  be  current,  and  the  tax  collector  demands 
payment  of  the  tax  in  terms  of  the  most  highly  valued  of 
those  coins,  the  tax  is  settled  in  its  terms,  in  case  such  coin 
is  one  that  has  been  struck  by  the  sultan  of  the  time,  be- 
cause the  contrary  course  would  involve  disloyalty.  If, 
however,  the  coin  has  been  struck  by  another  sultan,  then 
the  tax  is  still  settled  in  it,  if  the  previous  landowner  has 
paid  in  the  same  coin;  otherwise  it  is  tyranny  to  insist  on 
that  particular  coin. 

The  dirhams  *  and  dinars  are  not  accepted  in  payment  of 
kharaj  if  their  silver  or  gold  has  been  reduced  (maksur).2 

As  regards  the  measure  used  in  the  kharaj,*  if  it  is  the 
proportional  khar&j,  it  makes  no  difference  what  measure 
is  used.  If,  however,  the  kharaj  is  of  the  fixed  kind,  ac- 
cording to  the  'Alamkiriyyah,  the  measure  used  in  this  con- 

1  The  dirham  used  in  connection  with  khardj  is  the  same  as  is  used 
in  sakdt. 

3  The  doctors  disagree  as  to  the  propriety  of  reducing  the  metal  of 
the  coins.  Malik  and  most  of  the  Medina  doctors  declare  such  a 
practice  to  be  abominable.  The  Prophet  is  said  to  have  forbidden  the 
reduction  of  the  size  of  the  coin  (sikkah).  This  hadlth  is  taken 
by  some  to  mean  a  prohibition  of  turning  the  coins  into  bullion,  by 
others,  of  turning  them  into  plate,  by  still  others,  of  trimming  off  the 
edges  of  coins  with  scissors,  because  in  the  beginning  of  Islam  coins 
were  counted  by  tale.  Abu  Hanifah  and  the  doctors  of  'Iraq,  on  the 
other  hand,  hold  the  view  that  such  a  practice  is  not  abominable.  Al- 
Shafi'i  says  that  the  practice  is  not  abominable  if  the  reduction  was 
required  by  necessity,  otherwise  it  is  a  wanton  act.  Finally  Ahmad 
Ibn  Hanbal  approves  of  it  only  with  respect  to  coins  on  which  the 
name  of  God  was  not  impressed. 

s  Mawardi,  p.  272;  'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  ii,  p.  339;  Foth,  vol.  v,  p.  281; 
Mafatih,  pp.  14-5,  66-8. 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  395 

nection  is  the  sa'  which  is  eight  ritls.  According  to  al- 
Mawardi,  when  a  district  is  assessed  with  kharaj  for  the  first 
time  the  measure  of  that  district  is  taken  as  the  basis. 

Finally,  as  regards  the  measure  used  for  measuring  the 
land,1  according  to  the  'Alamklriyyah,  the  jarib  is  sixty  by 
sixty  cubits,  in  terms  of  the  cubit  of  al-Malik,  which  is  seven 
qabdahs ; 3  namely,  one  qabdah  longer  than  the  common 
cubit,  which  is  six  qabdalis.  According  to  the  Kafi  as  quoted 
in  the  Path,  in  measuring  the  land  in  every  district  the  meas- 
ure commonly  used  there  is  taken  as  the  basis. 

If  the  tax  collector  and  the  land  owner  disagree  about 
the  status  of  the  land,8  the  former  claiming  that  the  land  is 
kharaj  land,  and  the  latter  contending  that  it  is  tithe  land, 
in  case  the  contention  of  either  side  may  be  true,  the  claim 
of  the  land  owner  is  given  preference;  but  if  he  is  suspected 
he  must  swear  as  to  the  truth  of  his  contention  in  order  to 
clear  up  the  doubt.  In  such  cases  of  dispute,  it  may  be  re- 
ferred to  the  public  registers  (dvwan)  if  their  reliability  is 
well-known  and  the  registrars  may  be  relied  upon.  Dis- 
putes of  this  kind,  however,  are  rare,  occurring  only  on  the 
borders  of  territories  subject  to  one  or  the  other  of  the  two 
taxes. 

If  the  landowner  claims  that  he  paid  the  kharaj,  his 
claim  is  not  observed  although  he  is  believed  if  he  makes 
a  similar  statement  with  respect  to  the  tithe.  In  such  case 
it  may  be  referred,  in  accordance  with  custom,  to  the  public 
registers  concerning  the  kharaj,  if  they  are  reliable. 

Like  the  zakat  collectors,  the  kharaj  collectors  receive 
their  pay  (risq)  out  of  the  kharaj  proceeds,  and  this  is  also 
true  of  the  pay  of  the  surveyor  (massah),  but  there  is  dis- 

1  For  details  on  kinds  of  measures,  see  Mawardi,  p.  265. 
1  Qabdah  is  the  measure  of  the  fist,  t.  e.,  about  4  fingerbreadths,  or 
nearly  6*4  inches. 
1  Mawardi,  p.  263. 


396  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

agreement  as  regards  the  wages  (ujrah)  of  the  distributor 
(qassam)*  According  to  al-Shafi'i,  his  wage  is  taken  out 
of  the  proceeds  of  the  tithe  or  kharaj  collected.  Abu 
Hanifah,  on  the  other  hand,  says  that  the  wage  is  paid  in  an 
equitable  manner  out  of  the  produce  before  the  collection 
of  the  tax.  Sufyan  al-Thawri  says  that  such  wages  are 
paid,  in  the  case  of  kharaj,  by  the  sultan  and  in  the  case  of 
tithe,  by  the  landowner,  and  finally  Malik  holds  that  wages 
relating  to  tithe  are  paid  by  the  tithe  payer  and  those  relat- 
ing to  kharaj  are  paid  half  and  half  by  the  taxpayer  and 
the  sultan. 

The  officials  of  the  fa'y  revenue,2  such  as  the  kharaj  and 
the  jisyak,  besides  being  reliable  and  active,  are  required  to 
possess  certain  other  qualities  according  to  the  extent  of 
jurisdiction  and  power  with  which  they  are  invested:  (i) 
If  they  are  charged  with  the  assessment  and  distribution  of 
the  fa'y  revenue,  they  must  possess  these  four  qualities: 
they  must  be  freemen,  Moslems,  mujtahids,  and  conversant 
with  arithmetic  and  surveying.  (2)  If  they  have  full  au- 
thority over  the  collection  of  tax  rates  which  have  already 
been  assessed,  they  must  be  freemen,  Moslems,  and  con- 
versant with  arithmetic  and  surveying,  but  they  need  not 
be  mujtahids •;  since  their  duty  is  only  to  collect  what  has 
already  been  assessed.  (3)  If  they  have  limited  authority 
over  a  specified  part  of  the  ftfy  revenue,  then  it  depends 
on  the  duties  they  have  been  charged  with.  If  their  duties 
are  such  that  they  need  to  appoint  a  substitute,  they  must 
be  Moslems,  freemen,  and  conversant  with  arithmetic  and 
surveying  to  the  degree  required,  but  they  may  not  be 

1  Qassdm  (distributor)  means  the  official  who  measures  off  the  tithe 
or  the  proportional  tax  from  the  entire  produce  which  after  harvest 
was  deposited  in  the  barns  (bayddir).  The  massdh  (surveyor),  on  the 
other  hand,  is  the  official  who  measures  the  land  in  order  to  deter- 
mine the  amount  of  the  khardj.  (Cf.  Berchem,  p.  72,  fn.  4.) 

3  Mawardi,  p.  224 ;  also  p.  264. 


THE  KHARAJ  OR  LAND-TAX  397 

dhimmis  or  slaves,  because  these  two  are  not  qualified  to 
exercise  authority  (wilayah).  On  the  contrary,  if  they  do 
not  need  to  appoint  substitutes,  they  may  be  slaves,  since 
they  are  in  this  case  like  messengers  (rasul)  sent  on  an 
errand.  As  for  their  being  dhimmis,  it  depends  on  the 
taxes  they  are  to  collect.  If  they  are  to  collect  taxes  from 
dhimmis,  such  as  the  jizyah,  and  the  tolls  ('ushr)  levied  on 
the  dhimmi  traders,  they  may  be  dhimmis.  If,  however, 
they  are  to  collect  taxes  from  Moslems,  such  as  the  kharaj 
of  lands  found  in  the  possession  (yad)  of  Moslems,  opin- 
ion varies. 

If  the  person  named  collector  is  not  qualified  to  exercise 
the  authority  vested  in  him  and  yet  collects  the  tax,  the 
taxpayer  is  released  from  his  debt  if  the  collector  was  not 
forbidden  from  collecting  the  taxes,  because  the  collector 
was  authorized  to  collect  the  tax  from  him,  although  his 
authority  was  imperfect  (fdsid)  and  he  was  acting  as  a 
messenger.  The  difference  between  the  collector's  author- 
ity being  valid  (sahih)  and  imperfect  (fdsid)  is  that  in 
the  first  case  he  may  force  the  taxpayer  to  pay  the  tax,  and 
in  the  second  he  may  not.  If  the  authority  of  the  collector 
is  not  only  imperfect,  but  he  is  also  forbidden  to  collect, 
he  may  not  then  force  the  taxpayers  to  pay  the  taxes,  or 
even  collect  the  same.  Should  the  taxpayers  pay  the  tax 
to  the  collector,  though  knowing  that  he  was  forbidden 
to  collect  taxes,  they  are  not  released  from  their  tax  dues; 
but  if  they  did  not  know  about  it,  then,  according  to  one 
view  of  the  matter,  they  are  released,  but  according  to  an- 
other view,  they  are  not.  The  same  divergence  of  view 
exists  concerning  agents  (wakll). 

Unike  the  sakat  official,  the  fa'y  official  may  not  distribute 
the  ftfy  revenue  he  has  collected  without  permission,  be- 
cause while  the  beneficiaries  of  zakat  have  been  determined 
by  revealed  texts,  those  of  the  fafy  are  determined  by  the 
imam. 


CHAPTER  VII 
THE  JIZYAH  OR  POLL  TAX  a 

THE  word  jizyah  is  derived  from  jaza  meaning  compen- 
sation, requital  for  good  or  evil.  This  tax  owes  its  name 
to  the  fact  that  it  is  taken  from  the  dhimmis  as  a  punish- 
ment for  their  unbelief  in  order  to  humiliate  them  or,  it 
may  be,  by  way  of  mercy,  as  a  price  for  the  protection 
given  them  by  the  Moslems.2 

The  collection  of  the  jizyah  is  based  on  the  divine 
words : 3  "  Make  war  upon  such  of  those  to  whom  a  Scrip- 
ture has  been  given,  as  do  not  believe  in  God,  nor  in  the  last 
day  .  .  .  until  they  pay  by  their  hands  the  jizyah  in  order 
to  be  humiliated."  The  dhimmis  by  paying  the  jizyah  be- 
come entitled  to  two  rights :  security  from  molestation  and 
protection.  By  virtue  of  the  first  right  they  become  safe 
(amiri)  and  of  the  second,  proteges  (mcthrOs).4 

According  to  the  Hanifite  doctors,  the  tax  is  called  jiz- 
yah because  it  is  paid  by  the  dhimmis  as  a  compensation 
(jaza)  for  being  spared  from  death;  since  by  the  payment 
of  the  jizyah  the  non-Moslems  purchase  their  lives  and 
may  no  longer  be  killed.  Al-Sarakhsi,  in  this  connection 
remarks  that  the  infidel  who  lives  in  the  Moslem  state  is 

lMajma',  p.  515;  Hiddyah,  vol.  v,  p.  288;  Yusuf,  p.  69;  Mawardi,  p. 
245;  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  275;  Mugni,  vol.  iv,  p.  224;  Angari,  vol.  iv,  p. 
210;  Dardir,  p.  203;  Kharashi,  p.  441. 

2  Mawardi,  p.  246;  cf.  Kharashi,  p.  441. 

s  Koran,  chap.  9,  verse  29. 

4  Mawardi,  p.  247. 
398 


THE  JIZYAH  OR  POLL  TAX  399 

subjected  to  the  payment  of  jizyah  for  his  humiliation  and 
punishment  so  long  as  he  persists  in  his  unbelief,  and  in  order 
to  impress  him  with  the  degradation  of  unbelief  and  the 
power  of  Islam.  According  to  him,  the  jizyah  is  taken  from 
the  dhimmis  in  lieu  of  the  assistance  which  they  would  be 
liable  to  give  if  they  had  not  persisted  in  their  unbelief,  be- 
cause, living  as  they  do  in  the  Moslem  state,  they  must  be 
ready  to  defend  it.  However,  since  they  do  not  embrace 
Islam,  they  are  not  fit  for  such  assistance  in  person  because 
they  would  be  favorably  inclined  towards  the  enemy.  Con- 
sequently, instead  of  personal  service  they  are  required  to 
give  part  of  their  wealth,  which  is  spent  on  the  Moslem 
soldiers  who  defend  the  state ;  and  exactly  as  the  poor  Mos- 
lems take  part  in  the  war  as  footmen,  and  the  rich  as  horse- 
men, so  the  amount  of  the  monetary  equivalent  collected 
from  the  dhimmis  varies  according  to  their  means.  Some 
say  that  the  jizyah  levied  on  the  dhimmis  is  a  rental  for 
residing  in  the  Moslem  state,  but  the  former  view  is  prefer- 
able; for  if  the  latter  view  were  true,  women  and  children 
also  would  be  liable  to  pay  the  tax,  which  they  are  not,  be- 
cause they  are  not  liable  for  the  defence  of  the  country.1 

The  jizyah  is  levied  only  on  those  who  may  be  admitted 
into  the  status  of  the  dhimmi,  namely,  Christians,  Jews, 
both  of  whom  possess  a  Scripture,  and  the  idolaters 
and  fireworshipers.  According  to  the  Malikites,2  except- 
ing apostates,  all  persons  who  may  be  made  slaves,  that 
is,  all  unbelievers  (kafir),  even  including  the  Quraysh,  may 
be  admitted  into  the  status  of  dhimmi.  According  to  al- 
Shafi'i,  the  jizyah  may  be  accepted  only  from  Christians, 
Jews  and  fireworshipers,  but  not  from  idolaters,  inasmuch 
as  the  above-mentioned  verse  refers  only  to  the  first  two 

1  Mabsiit,  part  x,  p.  8. 
1  Kharashi.  p.  442. 


400  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

classes,  and  the  Prophet  extended  its  scope  to  the  firewor- 
shipers  also;  but  the  idolaters  are  left  out  entirely.  The 
Hanifites  argue  that  since  the  idolaters  may  be  made  slaves 
it  should  also  be  allowed  to  accept  the  jizyah  from  them, 
but  they  admit  that  this  is  true  only  of  the  idolaters  who 
are  not  Arabs.  The  Arab  idolaters  may  not  pay  the  jizyah, 
for  the  Prophet  was  sent  from  among  them  and  the  mir- 
acles were  performed  before  their  eyes.  So  their  persist- 
ence in  unbelief  is  of  the  worst  type.  By  Arabs  here  are 
meant  the  original  Arab  tribes  that  are  idolaters,  and  not 
the  Jews  and  Christians  settled  among  the  Arabs  or  Arabs 
who  have  been  converted  to  the  Hebrew  or  Christian  re- 
ligion. The  jizyah  is  likewise  not  accepted  from  renegades, 
for  these  "  have  turned  to  unbelief  after  having  once  wit- 
nessed the  beauties  of  Islam  ".  The  Arab  idolaters  and  the 
renegades  have  to  accept  either  Islam  or  the  sword,  but 
their  wives  and  children  are  spared  and  made  slaves. 

The  jizyah  is  of  two  kinds : 

(i)  The  jizyah  imposed  by  agreement  and  treaty,  the 
amount  of  which  has  been  fixed  by  the  terms  of  the  agree- 
ment and  may  not  be  later  changed.1  For  example,  the  Pro- 
phet arranged  with  the  people  of  Najran  that  they  should  pay 
yearly  in  two  instalments  2,000  hidlahs  (a  dress  of  two 
pieces),  each  hullah  being  worth  40  dirhams.  According  to 
Abu  Yusuf ,  this  yearly  payment  is  for  both  their  persons  and 
their  lands,  and  the  part  paid  for  the  persons  applies  only  to 
the  non-Moslem  part  of  the  population  of  Najran,  while  the 
part  paid  for  the  lands  is  collected  from  every  piece  of 
land,  even  when  sold  to  a  Moslem.  According  to  the  1AI- 
amkiriyyah?  the  imam  may  require  the  payment  of  a  lump 
sum  of  money  or  goods  without  specifying  the  part  to  be 

1  Path,  vol.  v,  p.  288. 
9  Vol.  ii,  p.  350. 


THE  JIZYAH  OR  POLL  TAX  401 

paid  by  persons  (jam&jim)  and  by  lands,  or  he  may  so 
specify.  In  the  former  case,  the  total  sum  is  justly  appor- 
tioned among  the  persons  and  the  lands,  the  part  allotted  to 
the  persons  being  jizyah  and  the  other  kharaj.  Both  of 
them  are  distributed  among  the  individual  taxpayers  ac- 
cording to  the  principles  governing  the  jizyah  and  kharaj 
in  general.  If  the  number  of  heads  decreases  or  entirely 
disappears  by  conversion  to  Islam  or  death  or  otherwise, 
their  share  of  the  tribute  is  reduced  or  entirely  removed  and 
charged  to  the  lands  if  the  latter  can  stand  it;  otherwise  it 
lapses.  Should  the  heads  later  increase,  they  gradually  re- 
sume payment  of  their  full  share.  A  similar  course  is  fol- 
lowed if  the  lands  cannot  bear  their  share  of  the  tribute. 
In  the  case  of  lands,  however,  should  they  be  entirely  de- 
stroyed, their  share  lapses.  If,  on  the  contrary,  the  shares 
of  the  lands  and  the  persons  were  specified  by  the  imam, 
then  neither  bears  the  share  of  the  other,  should  the  latter 
be  unable  themselves  to  pay  it,  but  such  share  lapses  until 
they  are  again  able  to  pay.  Should  they  become  Moslems, 
the  part  assessed  on  the  persons  lapses,  but  the  fact  of  con- 
version has  no  effect  on  the  part  assessed  on  the  lands. 
Should  the  imam  follow  a  third  course  and  arrange  for  a 
tribute  on  the  persons  or  the  lands  alone,  such  an  agreement 
is  null  and  void  (la  yasihJm),  the  sum  arranged  being  distri- 
buted as  noted  above  between  the  persons  and  the  lands.1 

The  Shafiites2  agree  with  the  Hanifites  that  the  jizyah 
agreed  upon  in  a  treaty  may  not  later  be  changed,  but  they 
hold  that  the  rate  of  the  jizyah  per  individual  as  provided 
for  in  the  agreement  should  never  fall  short  of  the  mini- 
mum rate  of  one  dinar.  When  by  such  an  agreement  the 

1  For  the  Shafiite  and  Malikite  views,  see  supra,  pp.  369-372. 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  249,  250 ;  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  pp.  279,  281 ;  Wajiz,  vol.  ii, 
p.  200;  An§ari,  vol.  iv,  p.  216;  Path  al-Qarib,  p.  624;  Umm,  vol.  iv,  p. 
IOI. 


402  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

infidels  retain  the  ownership  of  their  city  or  their  village, 
it  is  recommended  to  the  imam  to  obtain  the  insertion  of  a 
provision  for  the  entertainment  of  Moslem  travelers  who 
may  stop  in  that  city  or  village.  In  such  case  the  total  num- 
ber of  the  days  of  entertainment  during  the  year,  and  the 
number  of  guests  and  horses,  as  well  as  the  length  of  time 
individual  guests  are  to  be  entertained,  are  specified.  As 
in  the  case  of  jizyah,  the  individual  assignments  are  varied 
according  to  the  wealth  of  the  entertainers.  When  the  in- 
dividual assignments  have  not  been  specified  in  the  agree- 
ment, then  the  people  of  the  city  or  village  themselves  make 
the  assignments  among  themselves.  The  amount  and  kind 
of  food  to  be  served  the  travelers  and  the  quantity  of  bar- 
ley to  be  given  their  animals  are  also  indicated.  The  super- 
fluous residences  and  the  churches  where  the  Moslems  are 
to  be  lodged  are  also  mentioned,  in  this  respect  the  lodg- 
ings of  the  poor  infidels  being  equally  liable.  The  sojourn 
of  the  same  individual  may  not  exceed  three  days,  neither 
may  he  require  medical  service  nor  baths.  Furthermore, 
the  infidels  are  never  forced  out  of  their  houses  in  order 
to  make  room  for  Moslem  travelers.  Some  Shafiites  say 
that  this  burden  of  entertainment  is  in  lieu  of  the  mini- 
mum rate  of  one  dinar  in  specie,  and  that  consequently  it 
may  be  converted  to  its  monetary  equivalent  and  collected 
in  specie.  Others  hold  that  it  is  independent  of,  and  over 
and  above,  the  minimum  rate  of  one  dinar,  and  that  conse- 
quently the  latter  may  not  be  reduced  to  allow  for  this  bur- 
den in  kind,  and  that  the  infidels  may  not  be  forced  to  pay 
it  in  specie.  If  it  is  converted  to  specie  it  becomes  a  part 
of  the  fa'y  and  may  be  disbursed  to  the  fa'y  beneficiaries 
only,  although  before  its  conversion  any  Moslem  is  entitled 
to  entertainment. 

Like  the  Hanifites,  the  Malikites  give  power  to  the  imam 
to  settle  the  jizyah  at  any  figure.      If  the  amount  was 


THE  JIZYAH  OR  POLL  TAX  403 

not  indicated  in  the  treaty,  it  is  collected  at  the  same  rates 
as  obtain  in  regard  to  dhimmis  who  do  not  enjoy  any  treaty 
rights.1 

(2)  The  jizyah  imposed  by  the  imam  upon  the  popula- 
tion of  a  district  conquered  by  force  of  arms.2  The  yearly 
rate  for  the  rich  is  forty-eight  dirhams,  i.  e.,  four  dirhams 
per  month,  for  the  middle  class  half  of  this  sum,  and  for 
the  poor  who  can  earn  their  living,  one-fourth  of  this  sum. 
The  above  is  based  on  the  precedents  of  the  califs  Omar, 
'Uthman  and  'AH,  the  other  Companions  having  approved 
of  their  action.  In  other  words,  it  is  based  on  ijma'.  There 
is  no  Zahir-al-riwayah  report  concerning  the  meaning  of 
the  terms  rich,  middle-class  and  poor,  but  in  the  commen- 
tary of  al-Tahawi  it  is  stated  that  the  person  who  owns 
10,000  dirhams  and  upwards  is  rich,  the  person  owning 
from  200  upwards  is  middle  class,  and  finally  the  person 
owning  less  than  that  is  poor.  Some  say  that  the  person 
who  needs  to  work  in  order  to  earn  a  living  is  poor,  the  per- 
son who,  though  having  possessions,  works,  middle  class, 
and  the  person  who  owns  enough  to  afford  to  be  idle,  rich. 
Still  others  say  that  the  person  who  has  not  enough  is 
poor;  the  person  who  has  enough  food  for  his  family  and 
himself,  middle  class;  and  the  person  who  has  more,  rich. 
The  author  of  the  Ikhtiydr  believes  that  this  point  should 
be  settled  by  the  imam  on  the  basis  of  the  particular  condi- 
tions prevailing  in  each  locality. 

Al-Shafi'i  has  expressed  the  opinion  that  the  minimum 
rate  of  jizyah  is  one  dinar  or  twelve  dirhams  upon 
every  adult,  rich  or  poor,  the  maximum  rate  being 
fixed  by  the  imam  according  to  his  judgment.  Ac- 
cording to  the  Minhaj,2  the  imam  should  bargain 

1  Ibn  Rushd.,  M.,  p.  279 ;  Dardir,  p.  204.        *  Cf.  Kharashi,  p.  443. 
1  Vol.  iii,  p.  279 ;  Wajls,  vol.  ii,  p.  200 ;  Mugni,  vol.  iv,  p.  229. 


404  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

(mumakasah)  until  he  obtains  the  rate  of  four  dinars  for 
the  rich  and  two  for  the  middle  class.  Some  say  that  this 
bargain  may  be  made  only  at  the  time  of  the  agreement, 
since  afterwards  the  agreement  may  no  longer  be  changed. 
Still  others  hold  that  it  may  be  made  at  the  time  of  the 
agreement,  or  afterwards,  at  the  time  of  collection  as  well. 
According  to  Malik,  both  the  minimum  and  the  maxi- 
mum are  fixed  by  the  imam?  However,  according  to 
Khalll,2  the  rate  of  the  jizyah  is  fixed  at  four  dinars  or 
forty  dirhams,  with  necessary  reductions  to  allow  for 
poverty. 

According  to  both  the  Shafiites  and  the  Malikites,3 
if  the  infidels  refuse  to  pay  as  jizyah  more  than  the  mini- 
mum of  one  dinar,  the  imam  may  not  fight  them  in  order  to 
obtain  a  higher  rate,  but  is  obliged  to  accept  that  rate. 
According  to  Malik,  the  dinar  is  valued  at  ten  dirhams.  Ac- 
cording to  most  of  the  Shafiites  the  dinar  is  valued  at  its 
current  market  value.  According  to  the  Hanifites,  however, 
although  the  dinar  in  general  is  valued  at  ten  dirhams,  in 
the  case  of  jizyah,  following  the  precedent  of  Omar,  it  is 
valued  at  twelve.4 

The  jizyah  is  not  imposed  upon  the  children,  insane,  and 
the  imbecile  old  people;  in  other  words,  persons  who  do  not 
possess  legal  responsibility;  because  they  are  not  fit  for  as- 
sistance in  the  defence  of  the  state.  This  is  also  true  of 
senile  old  people,  and  of  the  blind  and  cripples.  Abu  Yusuf 
says  that  the  blind  and  the  cripples  who  have  property  are 
subject  to  the  tax,  because,  although  they  cannot  assist  in 
person,  they  may  do  so  by  their  wealth,  and  because  such 

1  Mawardi,  p.  249. 

1  Kharashi,  p.  443. 

1  Wajiz,  p.  200 ;  Ibn  Rushd,  M. .,  p.  279. 

4  Path,  vol.  v,  p.  289. 


THE  JIZYAH  OR  POLL  TAX  405 

persons,  when  they  have  had  a  voice  in  government,  are 
liable  to  death  in  time  of  war.  Likewise,  the  poor  who 
are  not  engaged  in  business  are  exempt  from  the  tax.  Also 
monks  who  are  retired  from  the  world,  even  if  they  can 
work,  are  not  subject  to  it,  because  they  are  not  liable  to 
death  in  time  of  war.  According  to  Abu  Hanifah  and  Abu 
Yusuf,  monks  pay  the  jizyah  if  they  can  work.  Slaves  of 
every  description  (qinn,  mudabbar,  umm  walad,  ummah, 
or  mukatab)  do  not  pay  the  jizyah,  nor  is  the  jizyah 
paid  by  their  masters,  who  on  their  account  already  pay  a 
higher  rate  of  jizyah  than  they  would  otherwise  do.  The  sick 
as  well  are  free  from  the  tax.  According  to  al-Shafi'i,1  the 
jizyah  is  levied  on  every  male  dhimmi  who  is  of  age  and 
sane  of  mind  and  of  free  status ;  the  priests,  the  senile  old 
people,  the  paralytics,  etc.,  included.  The  poor  who  are 
unable  to  engage  in  business  are  to  be  ousted  from  the  Mos- 
lem country  according  to  one  view;  in  another  view,  they 
are  exempted  from  the  jizyah;  however,  in  a  third  view  they 
are  subject  to  it  like  others. 

According  to  the  Ikhtiyar,  if  the  cause  of  exemption  dis- 
appears in  the  case  of  the  above-mentioned  people,  except- 
ing the  poor,  before  the  tax  was  yet  imposed  on  them,  they 
become  subject  to  it;  but  if  the  cause  disappears  after  the 
tax  was  imposed  for  that  year,  they  are  exempt  from  it  for 
that  year,  because  the  cause  of  exemption  is  considered 
with  reference  to  the  time  of  the  imposition  of  the  tax. 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah,  the  jizyah  becomes  due  at 
the  beginning  of  the  year,  but  is  collected  at  the  end  of  the 
year,  two  or  three  days  before  it  runs  out ;  Abu  Yusuf  main- 
tains that  it  should  be  collected  by  instalments  every  two 
months  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  every  month,  in 
order  that  the  tax  may  become  more  onerous  for  the  tax- 

1  Umm,  vol.  iv,  pp.  98,  101 ;  cf.  Wajlz,  vol.  ii,  p.  198. 


406  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

payers  and  more  beneficial  to  the  Moslems.  The  view  gen- 
erally accepted  is  that  it  is  collected  at  one  time  at  the  end 
of  the  year.1  This  is  also  the  opinion  of  al-Shafi'i,  and  the 
Malikites.2 

The  jizyah  is  canceled  by  conversion  to  Islam,  by  death, 
and,  according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  also  by  non-collection 
(tadakhul).  It  is  canceled  by  conversion  to  Islam,  because 
the  dhimmi  after  this  can  serve  in  person  for  the  de- 
fence of  the  state.  According  to  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muham- 
mad Ibn  al-Hasan,  the  jizyah,  like  other  debts,  is  collected 
even  if  it  has  been  allowed  to  remain  uncollected  for  many 
years.  Abu  Hanifah's  argument  in  support  of  the  con- 
trary view  is  that  the  jizyah  is  imposed  by  way  of  punish- 
ment, and,  like  other  penalties  imposed  for  the  sake  of  God, 
it  is  canceled  if  allowed  to  fall  into  arrears.  Besides,  from 
the  Moslem  standpoint,  the  jizyah  is  a  financial  aid  to  the 
state  in  lieu  of  the  bodily  assistance  every  citizen  is  obliged 
to  tender  for  the  defence  of  the  state,  and  in  collecting  the 
tax  for  only  one  year  the  meaning  (mafna)  of  assistance  is 
realized.  Moreover,  the  main  object  in  levying  the  tax  is 
the  subjection  of  infidels  to  humiliation  and  this  object  is 
secured  by  collecting  the  tax  for  the  current  year  only  and 
letting  that  of  the  former  years  lapse.3 

According  to  the  Shafiites,4  conversion  or  death  are  a 
bar  to  the  jizyah  only  as  regards  the  future,  but  such  part  of 
it  as  has  already  accrued  is  collected.  According  to  the 
Malikites,5  they  constitute  a  bar  even  as  regards  arrears. 

When  the  jizyah  is  collected  from  the  dhimmi  he  is 
obliged  to  stand  while  the  collector  is  seated,  and  he  must 

1  Mabstit,  part  x,  p.  82. 

1  Kharashi,  p.  443.  s  Ibid. 

4  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  280. 

6  Kharashi,  p.  443;  Dardlr,  p.  204;  Ibn  Rushd.,  £.,  p.  327. 


THE  JIZYAH  OR  POLL  TAX 


407 


wear  the  distinctive  dress  prescribed  for  the  dhimmis. 
During  the  process  of  payment,  the  dhimmi  is  seized  by  the 
collar  and  vigorously  shaken  and  pulled  about  in  order  to 
show  him  his  degradation,  and  he  is  rebuked  in  these  words  : 
"  Oh,  dhimmi,  or,  Oh,  enemy  of  God,  pay  the  jizyah\  ",  but 
he  is  not  addressed,  "  Oh,  infidel  ".  The  dhimmi,  there- 
fore, may  not  pay  his  jizyah  by  proxy,  because  this 
would  defeat  one  of  the  objects  of  the  tax,  namely,  his 
humiliation.  However,  in  the  opinion  of  the  two  disciples, 
this  is  allowed.1  It  should  be  noted,  however,  that  Abu 
Yusuf,2  far  from  subscribing  to  these  extreme  views  of 
later  Hanifites,  recommends  to  the  calif  Harun  al-Rashid 
gentleness  (rifq)  in  the  treatment  of  the  dhimmi. 

Al-Shafi'i,8  on  the  strength  of  the  opinions  held  by  a 
number  of  people  of  knowledge  ('Urn),  concludes  that  the 
humiliation  referred  to  in  the  Koran  consists  in  the  sub- 
mission of  the  infidels  to  Moslem  rule  (hukm  al-islam), 
and  that  consequently  a  people  may  not  be  admitted  into  the 
status  of  dhimmi  except  on  condition  of  submission  to  Mos- 
lem law.  Some  of  the  later  Shafiites  hold  that  the  reference 
to  humiliation  in  question  requires  that  the  dhimmi  should 
be  humiliated  literally  in  paying  the  jizyah  by  placing  it  in 
the  balance  while  he  is  standing  with  the  head  bent  and  the 
shoulders  stooped  and  while,  on  the  other  hand,  the  col- 
lector, who  is  seated,  seizes  the  dhimmi  by  his  beard  and 
slaps  his  face  on  both  sides,  saying :  "  Oh,  enemy  of  God, 
give  the  right  of  God  ".  However,  the  prevalent  Shafiite 
doctrine  severely  condemns  such  a  construction  of  the 
Koranic  reference  to  humiliation.4 

1  Mabsat,  part  x,  p.  81 ;  Jdmi',  vol.  ii,  p.  577;  Bahr,  vol.  v,  p.  121. 

2  Yusuf,  pp.  70,  71,  72. 
8  Umnt,  vol.  iv,  p.  99. 

4  Minhdj,  vol.  in,  p.  281 ;  Fat h  al-Qarib,  p.  624 ;  Wajis,  vol.  ii,  p.  200 ; 
Mugni,  vol.  iv,  p.  230. 


4o8  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,1  the  humiliation  of 
the  dhimmis  is  a  matter  of  obligation  (wujub),  and,  there- 
fore, they  may  not  settle  their  jizyah  by  proxy;  for  it  is 
essential  that  they  taste  humiliation,  and  "  perhaps  they 
will  then  decide  to  get  rid  of  it  by  becoming  Moslems." 
According  to  the  most  extreme  view  quoted  by  al-'Adawi, 
the  humiliation  of  the  dhimmi  is  necessary  in  order  to 
demonstrate  their  inborn  hatred  of  the  Moslems,  their  re- 
futation of  the  Prophet,  and  the  fact  that  if  they  had  the 
power  they  would  exterminate  the  Moslems  gradually. 

1  Kharashi,  p.  443 ;  Dardir,  p.  204. 


CHAPTER  VIII 
OTHER  SOURCES  OF  REVENUE 

SECTION   I 

The  Spoils  of  War  ' 

THE  word  spoil  (ganlmah,  plural,  gana'im)  technically 
means  property  taken  by  force  from  infidels  during  war. 
Hence  property  taken  from  the  infidels  by  Moslems  who 
entered  the  enemy  land  without  the  imam's  permission  is 
not  spoil,  because  such  property  has  been  seized  not  by 
force,  but  by  theft.  If,  however,  the  Moslems  entered  the 
enemy's  country  in  "  force  "  (bi  mana'ah)  then  the  im&m's 
permission  is  not  necessary.  The  lowest  number  of  raiders 
that  constitutes  a  "  force  "  is  four,  or,  according  to  a  report 
from  Abu  Yusuf ,  nine.  The  case  of  entering  in  "  force  " 
is  clear.  As  regards  the  case  of  permission  by  the  imam, 
the  latter  by  permitting  the  raid  has  virtually  engaged  to 
assist  the  raiders  in  case  of  need.2 

According  to  the  Shafiites,8  all  property  taken  from  the 
infidels  while  war  is  going  on,  even  property  taken  by  theft, 

1  Majma',  p.  499 ;  Hiddyah,  vol.  v,  p.  215 ;  Mabsu},  part  x,  pp.  37,  136 ; 
'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  ii,  p.  290;  Kasani,  vol.  vii,  p.  117;  Bahr,  vol.  v,  p. 
89;  Durar,  p.  167;  Durr,  p.  356;  Mawardi,  p.  217;  Utnnt,  vol.  iv,  p.  64; 
Muzani,  vol.  iii,  p.  179;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  297;  Wajiz,  p.  290;  Dardir, 
p.  198;  Yahya,  p.  3. 

1  Majma1,  p.  505 ;  Durr,  p.  359. 

*  Mugni,  vol.  iii,  p.  93;  Kasani,  vol.  vii,  p.  117;  cf.  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p. 
297;  Wajlz,  p.  290;  Umnt,  vol.  iv,  p.  64. 

409 


4io  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

is  spoil.  The  Malikite  view  *  is  like  the  Hanifite.  The 
Malikites  give  the  name  of  mukhtass  (proper)  to  prop- 
erty which  is  neither  spoil  nor  fa'y,  but  belongs  entirely  to 
the  person  who  took  it,  such  as  property  stolen  from  the 
enemy. 

When  the  imam  conquers  a  place  or  a  city  by  force  of 
arms  (fanwat),  he  may  divide  the  property  taken,  whether 
lands  or  chattels,  after  the  deduction  of  the  state's  share  of 
one-fifth,  among  the  victorious  army,  since  the  Prophet  had 
done  so  with  respect  to  Khaybar.  Or  the  imam,  if  he 
so  chooses,  may  leave  the  lands  in  the  hands  of  their  original 
holders,  and  impose  upon  their  persons  the  jizyah,  and  upon 
their  lands  the  kharaj.  The  imam's  right  to  relinquish  to 
the  enemy  his  property  applies  only  to  landed  property,  not 
to  chattels,  except  in  so  far  as  they  are  indispensable  for 
the  exploitation  of  the  lands  and  the  real  estates  which 
have  been  left  in  the  enemy's  possession.  Thus  the  calif 
Omar  left  the  lands  and  houses  of  Sawad  to  the  original 
owners.  Or  finally,  the  imam  may  expatriate  the  original 
settlers,  bring  other  infidels  in  their  place,  and  impose  on 
them  the  jizyah  and  the  kharaj. 

Al-Shafi'i  objects  to  making  a  present  of  their  lands  to 
the  owners  when  the  lands  have  been  conquered  by  force, 
because,  according  to  him,  they  are  a  booty  of  war,  in  such 
case,  and,  like  chattels,  are  the  property  of  the  soldiers; 
he  maintains  that  although  the  imam  may  set  the  unbelievers 
free,  or  even  kill  them,  if  he  chooses  (for  the  right  of  the 
soldiers  to  them  is  not  so  clear-cut)  he  has  no  right  to  de- 
prive the  soldiers  of  their  unquestioned  property.  The 
Hanifites  reply  that  the  exercise  of  an  option  by  the 
imam  in  this  case  is  only  in  accordance  with  the  interests 
of  the  Moslems,  for  if  he  distributed  these  lands  among 

1  'Adawi,  p.  426. 


OTHER  SOURCES  OF  REVENUE  41j. 

the  soldiers  they  would  settle  down  on  them  in  order  to 
cultivate  them,  and  so  they  would  stay  away  from  the  holy 
war  and  the  enemy  would  then  return  to  the  charge  upon 
the  Moslems.  Moreover,  Moslems  are  often  ill-adapted 
to  agriculture.  Consequently,  if  the  lands  are  returned  to 
the  unbelievers  who  are  more  familiar  with  this  art  and  are 
made  subject  to  payment  of  kharaj,  the  Moslems  can  de- 
vote their  time  to  the  holy  war.  Furthermore  there  is  no 
prejudice  in  this  for  the  soldiers'  interests,  for  although  in 
the  case  of  distribution  the  benefits  are  more  immediate,  in 
the  other  case  they  are  more  persistent.  Then,  too,  future 
generations  also  have  a  right  in  these  lands,  and  should 
the  lands  be  distributed  among  the  victorious  army,  future 
Moslems  would  have  been  wronged.1 

The  imam  has  also  several  options  concerning  the  people 
themselves  inhabiting  the  country  conquered.  Thus  he 
may  kill  the  captives,  or  he  may  make  them  slaves,  or  he 
may  do  them  a  favor  by  allowing  them  to  remain  free  as 
dhimmis  of  the  Moslem  state,  except  when  they  are  Arab 
idolaters  or  renegades,  who  have  to  choose  between  the 
sword  and  Islam.  The  captives  however  may  not  return  to 
their  country,  because  it  would  result  in  the  strengthening 
of  the  enemy.  According  to  the  Jami',  women  and  children 
are  not  killed,  but  are  made  slaves  for  the  benefit  of  the 
fighters.2 

It  is  not  allowed  to  divide  the  spoils  in  the  land  of  the 
enemy,  although  Abu  Yusuf  says  this  is  permissible.  How- 
ever, if  the  imam  does  not  possess  the  means  of  carrying  the 
spoils  to  the  Moslem  land  he  may  then  divide  the  spoils 
provisionally  in  order  that  they  may  be  carried  to  the  Moslem 
land,  where  they  are  redivided  definitely.  In  such  case  the 

*Mabsut,  part  x,  p.  40 ;  Umnt,  vol.  iv,  pp.  103-4,  *93- 

*  Cf.  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  264;  Mawardi,  pp.  226,  232;  Kharashi,  p.  410. 


4I2  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

soldiers  are  entitled  to  wages  for  carrying  the  spoils  en- 
trusted to  them.  According  to  the  Shafiites,1  the  spoils  are 
divided  in  the  enemy's  country.  The  fighters  and  their 
helpers  are  equally  entitled  to  a  share  in  the  spoils,  but  not 
the  persons  who  have  not  fought.  Thus  the  traders  fol- 
lowing in  the  wake  of  the  army  are  not  entitled  to  a  share. 
The  fighters  may  use  the  spoils  in  the  land  of  the  enemy 
before  the  spoils  have  been  yet  divided,  if  there  is  need  for 
doing  so,  e.  g.f  they  may  use  the  horses  or  arms  taken  from 
the  enemy.  As  regards  forage,  wood,  oil,  perfumes  and 
the  like,  these  may  be  used  by  the  soldiers  even  if  they 
should  not  need  them.2  The  fighters,  however,  may  not 
sell  the  spoils  or  appropriate  them.  Neither  may  they  use 
them  after  they  have  left  the  enemy's  land ;  on  the  contrary, 
they  must  return  to  the  spoil  fund  whatever  remains  in 
their  possession. 

The  imam  may  promise  (tanfil)  &  the  army  more  than 
their  regular  shares  in  the  spoils  before  the  spoils  have  been 
taken,  and  the  war  has  ended,  in  order  to  induce  them  to 
greater  ardor  in  the  fight.  Thus  the  imam  may  promise  the 
soldiers  the  personal  effects  (salab)  of  the  persons  slain  by 
them,  or  a  certain  proportion  of  the  property  taken  by  them. 
The  personal  effects  of  persons  who  are  not  killed  in  war, 
such  as  women  and  children  may  not  be  promised,  because 
such  a  policy  would  encourage  their  killing.  However  it 
is  allowed  to  promise  the  personal  effects  of  the  traders  who 
follow  the  enemy  or  of  the  dhimmis  who  fight  on  the  side 
of  the  enemy.  It  is  not  permissible  to  promise  extra  shares 
after  the  spoils  have  been  taken,  unless  it  be  from  the  fifth 
set  apart  as  the  state's  share.  The  personal  effects  of  the 

1  Mawardi,  p.  240 ;  Wajiz,  p.  291. 

*  Cf.  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  267. 

8  Cf.  Wajiz,  p.  290 ;  Kharashi,  p.  427. 


OTHER  SOURCES  OF  REVENUE 

slain  belong  in  the  spoils,  if  they  have  not  been  promised  by 
the  imam  as  extra  shares ;  this  being  also  the  Malikite  view. 
The  Shafiites,  however,  hold  that  the  personal  effects  (salab) 
of  the  killed  belong  to  the  soldier  who  killed  him  irrespective 
of  whether  or  not  the  imam  had  so  stipulated.1 

The  spoils  are  divided  among  the  army  after  the  deduc- 
tion of  one-fifth  as  the  state's  share,  according  to  Abu  Hani- 
fah  and  Zufar,  at  the  rate  of  two  shares  to  the  horseman, 
and  one  share  to  the  footsoldier,  but  according  to  the  two 
disciples,  al-Shafi'i  and  the  Malikites,  at  the  rate  of  three 
shares  to  the  horseman;  one  for  himself  and  two  for  his 
horse.2  In  Abu  Hanifah's  opinion,  the  footsoldiers  who 
bought  a  horse  after  entering  the  land  of  the  enemy,  and 
the  horseman  whose  horse  died  before  the  battle  are  en- 
titled to  a  full  horseman's  share.  No  shares,  however,  are 
assigned  to  mules  and  animals  used  for  transporting.  The 
slaves,  mukatabs,  minors,  women  and  dhimmis,  if  they 
have  been  helpful  in  bringing  about  the  victory,  do  not  re- 
ceive a  full  share,  but,  at  the  imam's  discretion,  a  small  gift 
(radkh)  less  than  four-fifths  of  a  full  share. 

SECTION   II 

The  Tax  on  Mines  and  Treasure-trove  * 

The  doctors  have  disagreed  about  the  nature  of  the  tax 

levied  on  mines  *  and  treasure-trove.  The  Shafiites  con- 
sider this  tax  as  a  case  of  zakat.  So  do  the  Hanbalites,  who 

1  Mawardi,  p.  241. 

'C/.  Wajls,  p.  292;  Mawardi,  p.  243;  Kharashi,  p.  432. 

*  Majma',  p.  173;  Hiddyah,  p.  178;  Durar,  p.  121 ;  Umnt,  p.  36;  Minhdj, 
p.  247;  Mawardi,  p.  207;  Mudawwanah,  p.  50;  Dardir,  p.  124. 

4  Following  the  usage  of  the  doctors,  mine  is  used  in  the  sense  of  the 
mineral  produce  extracted  from  a  mine,  since  in  that  way  only  a  mine 
becomes  an  object  of  taxation. 


414  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

tax  at  the  same  rate  as  zakat,  namely,  one- fortieth.  The 
Hanifites,  on  the  other  hand,  consider  this  tax  as  a  case  of 
spoils  and,  as  in  the  rest  of  spoils  impose  the  rate  of  one-fifth. 
Finally,  Malik  is  said  to  have  held  both  views.1  The  author 
of  the  Majma'  says  in  this  connection  that  according  to  the 
Hanifites  the  proceeds  of  this  tax  are  disbursed  in  the  same 
way  as  the  spoils,  and  that  they  should  have  been  treated  by 
the  author  (musannif)  of  the  text  under  the  section  of 
holy  war  rather  than  under  zakat,  except  possibly  for  the 
fact  that  according  to  al-Shafi'i  this  tax  is  a  kind  of  zakat 
provided  for  by  special  prescription  (nass).  Al-Zarqani,2 
likewise,  observes  that  the  name  zakat  is  used  with  respect 
to  this  tax  by  way  of  metaphor,  or  because  in  some  cases 
it  is  subject  to  the  zakat. 

Much  of  the  dispute  concerning  this  tax  turns  upon  the 
determination  of  the  meaning  of  the  word  rikaz  which 
occurs  in  the  hadith :  "  And  in  the  rikaz  one-fifth  ".  Ac- 
cording to  the  doctors,8  the  word  rikaz  means  any  property 
buried  underground;  whether  by  God,  as  the  mine  (mae- 
dan),  or  by  man,  as  treasure-trove  (kanz).  The  Path  4 
says  that  rikaz  has  both  meanings  literally  (mushtarak)  ; 
but  according  to  the  Hidayah  and  the  Bada?if,  rikaz  means 
literally  only  a  mine.5  The  'Inayah  says  that  God  created 
mines  in  the  Earth  on  the  day  He  created  the  Earth.  Sa'di 
Efendi,  however,  objects  to  this  additional  qualification  on 
the  ground  that  it  is  not  known.  The  Majma'  remarks  that 
the  matter  is  open  to  discussion  because  there  is  a  hadith 

1  Qastallani,  vol.  iii,  p.  83. 

2  Vol.  ii,  p.  47. 

3  Cf.  Mabsut,  p.  211 ;  Durar,  p.  121. 
*Majma',  p.  173. 

8  The  Shafiites  and  Malikites  use  ma' dan  for  mine  and  rikdz  for 
treasure-trove  only.  The  Hanifites  in  general  use  rikdz  for  both 
meanings  and  differentiate  treasure-trove  by  the  use  of  the  word  kanz. 


OTHER  SOURCES  OF  REVENUE 

in  which  the  Prophet  said  that  gold  and  silver  were  created 
on  the  day  the  Earth  was  created.  The  dispute  on  the 
meaning  of  the  word  rikaz  has  an  important  bearing  be- 
cause, as  al-Qastallani  observes,  in  case  rikaz  means  treas- 
ure-trove alone,  mines  would  be  exempt  from  the  tax  of 
one-fifth. 

Mines.  According  to  the  Hanifites,  mines  are  of  three 
kinds:  those  which  are  solids  which  may  be  melted  and 
which  admit  of  imprints,  like  gold,  silver,  iron,  copper,  lead, 
etc. ;  those  which  are  solids  which  do  not  melt  and  do  not 
admit  of  imprints,  like  gypsum,  arsenic,  coal,  etc. ;  those 
which  are  liquids  which  do  not  become  solid,  like  water 
oil,  etc.* 

In  the  case  of  mines  of  the  first  kind, — the  only  kind 
subject  to  tax, — according  to  the  Hanifites,  the  fifth  belongs 
to  the  state.  Al-Sarakhsi,  in  justification  of  this,  says 2 
that  the  veins  in  which  mines  are  found  have  once  been  like 
treasures,  in  the  possession  of  the  infidels  before  they  came 
under  Moslem  jurisdiction  by  force  of  arms,  and  therefore 
they  are  a  spoil  of  war  and  one-fifth  of  them  belongs  to  the 
state. 

According  to  the  Hanifites,  if  a  Moslem  or  a  dhimmi, 
whether  a  freeman  or  a  slave,  minor  or  adult,  man  or 
woman,  should  discover  a  mine  of  the  first  kind,  like  gold 
or  silver,  in  a  land  subject  to  tithe  or  kharaj,  one-fifth  of 
the  find  is  taken  as  tax,  and  the  remaining  four-fifths  be- 
longs to  the  finder,  unless  he  is  a  musta'min ;  the  latter  is  ex- 
cepted  because  he  is  a  harbi  and  the  harbis  are  not  entitled 
to  a  share  in  the  spoils  even  when  they  have  fought  the 
enemies  of  Islam  with  the  imam's  permission.  However, 
according  to  the  Minah,  the  harbis  and  the  musta'mins  in  the 

1  'Indyah,  p.  179. 
p.  211. 


4I6  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

last  case  should  be  entitled  to  the  share  agreed  upon  between 
them  and  the  imam.  According  to  the  Mabsut,1  this  should 
also  apply  in  case  the  harbi  works  a  mine  with  the  imam's 
permission. 

The  finder  gets  the  four-fifths  as  mentioned  only  in  case 
the  land  where  the  mine  was  discovered  is  not  private 
property  (mamlukah),  for  in  the  latter  case,  after  the  de- 
duction of  the  state's  share  of  one-fifth,  the  four-fifths 
belongs  to  the  owner  of  the  land  instead  of  to  the  finder. 

If  the  find  is  made  in  the  finder's  own  habitation,  or  store, 
according  to  Abu  Hanifah,  no  tax  is  levied  on  the  find,  but 
in  the  opinion  of  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan 
there  is  levied  a  tax  of  one-fifth  on  the  find  because  the 
tenor  of  the  respective  hadlth  is  general.  If,  however,  the 
mine  was  discovered  by  the  finder  in  his  own  land  (milk), 
there  are  two  different  views  reported  from  Abu  Hanifah. 
The  view  cited  in  the  Mabsut  is  that  no  tax  is  levied,  but  the 
view  cited  in  the  Jamif  Saglr 2  is  to  the  contrary.  The  dis- 
tinction between  land  and  habitation  is  due  to  the  consider- 
ation that  land  is  owned  subject  to  public  charges  like  tithe 
and  kharaj,  whereas  houses  are  owned  subject  to  no  taxes 
whatever. 

According  to  al-Shafi'i,  mines  do  not  pay  this  tax  because, 
like  game,  they  were  the  property  of  no  one  when  found, 
and  so  they  belong  to  the  person  who  first  found  and  seized 
(ihras)  them.  Consequently,  according  to  him,  mines  pay 
a  tax  only  in  so  far  as  they  are  subject  to  zakat,  namely,  if 
they  are  gold  or  silver,  provided,  however,  the  nisab  re- 
quirements have  been  met.  As  regards  the  lapse  of  a  year, 
in  one  view  of  the  matter  he  requires  it,  but,  in  another  view, 
he  does  not  require  it,  since  this  requirement  is  in  order  that 
productivity  might  materialize,  and  in  the  case  of  mines  the 

1  P.  215.  2  Cf.  al-Jdmi'  al-Saglr,  p.  22. 


OTHER  SOURCES  OF  REVENUE 

whole  thing  is  a  product  (numa).  This  second  view  is 
the  prevalent  one.1  According  to  the  Shafiites,  gold  or 
silver  extracted  from  a  mine  at  one  time  may  be  added  to 
that  extracted  at  another  in  order  to  complete  the  nisab,  so 
long  as  the  exploitation  of  the  mine  has  not  been  definitively 
abandoned.  The  nisab  may  be  also  completed  by  gold, 
silver,  and  articles  of  trade  which  the  miner  may  already 
possess,  even  if  their  year  has  not  completely  run  out. 
Mines  worked  by  dhimmis  are  not  subject  to  tax,  because 
the  tax  levied  on  mines  is  zak&t,  which  may  be  levied  on 
Moslems  alone. 

According  to  Malik,  mines,  like  crops,  are  a  kind  of  pro- 
duce derived  from  the  earth,  and  therefore  if  they  are  gold 
or  silver  they  pay  zakat  subject  to  the  requirement  of 
nisab f  though  not  that  of  the  lapse  of  a  year.2  According 
to  the  Malikites,3  the  nisab  may  be  completed  from  gold  or 
silver  extracted  from  the  same  vein  ((irq),  regardless  of 
continuity  of  extraction.  Once  the  nisab  has  been  reached, 
later  findings,  no  matter  how  little,  pay  zakat  pro  rata.  If 
the  mine  extracted  falls  under  the  description  of  nadrah 
(literally,  rarety),  namely,  pure  gold  or  silver  which 
does  not  need  smelting,  it  is  considered  a  treasure-trove 
(rikaz).  Consequently,  such  finds  are  not  subject  to 
zakat  but  pay  the  tax  of  one-fifth  levied  on  treasure-trove, 
irrespective  of  the  nisab  requirement,  even  if  they  are  dis- 
covered by  an  infidel  or  slave.  If,  however,  the  extraction 
of  the  nadrah  involves  great  expense  or  labor,  then,  as  in 
treasure-trove,  it  is  subject  to  zakat  as  a  mine. 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al- 
Hasan,  there  is  no  tax  of  one-fifth  on  pearls  and  amber- 

1  Wajiz,  p.  96;  Mawardi,  p.  207. 
1  Ibn  Rushd,  A/.,  p.  226. 
1  Kharashi,  pp.  112-3. 


4Ig  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

gris,  and,  in  general,  on  anything  taken  out  of  the  sea,  even 
if  it  is  gold  or  sliver,  because,  being  at  the  bottom  of  the 
sea,  these  things  are  proof  against  conquest,  but  the  tax 
applies  to  the  spoils  of  war  only.  Likewise,  there  is  no 
tax  on  stones,  like  turquoise,  sapphires,  topaz,  emeralds, 
etc.,  when  they  are  found  in  the  mountains,  because  the 
Prophet  said :  "  There  is  no  fifth  on  stones  ".  Both  sea 
products  and  stones  are  taxed,  however,  if  found  in  the 
treasure  store  of  the  enemy.  There  is  a  tax  on  quicksilver, 
according  to  the  last  opinion  of  Abu  Hanifah.  According 
to  Abu  Yusuf,  however,  quicksilver  is  not  taxed;  but  on 
the  contrary,  products  of  the  sea  used  as  ornaments,  such 
as  pearls,  are  taxed,  since  Omar  taxed  ambergris.1  Ac- 
cording to  the  Shafiites  and  the  Malikites,2  none  of  them 
pay  zokat  as  such,  though  they  may  pay  as  articles  of  trade- 

Treasure- trove  (kanz).  Treasures  are  of  three  kinds: 
Treasures  which  bear  a  sign  of  Islam,  such  as  the  sentence 
of  testimony  to  the  existence  of  one  God;  those  which  do 
not  bear  any  sign;  thirdly  those  which  bear  a  sign  of  the 
pre-Islamic  age,  such  as  a  picture  of  a  god,  or  the  cross. 

Treasures  of  the  first  kind  legally  are  property  lost  and 
found  (luqatah),  that  is,  property  owned  by  a  Moslem, 
and  therefore  they  are  not  subject  to  tax.  Treasures  of 
the  second  kind,  according  to  the  most  reliable  Hanifite 
report  (Zahir-al-madhhab),  are  considered  to  be  like  those 
of  the  third  kind,  since  the  presumption  (as/)  is  that  they 
are  of  pre-Islamic  origin;  but  some  hold  that  they  are  like 
those  of  the  first,  because,  they  argued,  treasures  found  now- 
adays are  probably  of  Islamic  origin,  owing  to  the  long 
standing  of  Islam. 

Finally,  treasures  of  the  third  kind  are  subject  to  a  tax 


1  Hiddyah,  p.  184;  Jdmi',  p.  319. 
3  Minhdj,  p.  246;  Kharashi,  p.  116. 


OTHER  SOURCES  OF  REVENUE        419 

of  one-fifth,  the  remaining  four-fifths  belonging  to  the 
person  who  found  them;  provided  he  is  not  a  musta'min, 
and  the  treasure  has  been  found  in  a  land  which  is  not 
owned  (mamlukah)  by  any  one,  e.  g.,  in  the  country,  or  the 
mountains.  It  makes  no  difference  whether  the  finder  is 
adult  or  minor,  free  or  slave,  Moslem  or  dhimmi,  man  or 
woman.  In  case  the  treasure  has  been  found  by  a  musta'- 
min,  the  entire  treasure  belongs  to  the  state. 

If,  however,  the  treasure  has  been  found  in  a  land  owned 
(mamlukah)  by  a  private  individual,  according  to  Abu 
Yusuf,  the  remainder  after  deduction  of  the  state's  share  of 
one-fifth  still  belongs  to  the  person  who  found  the  treasure ; 
but  according  to  Abu  Hanifah  and  Muhammad  Ibn  al- 
Hasan,  it  belongs  to  the  person  to  whom  the  land  was  given 
(khittah)  at  the  time  of  its  conquest,  or  to  his  heirs,  if  they 
are  known,  otherwise,  following  al-Sarakhsi,  to  the  earliest 
known  owner  of  the  land;  according  to  Abu  '1-Layth, 
however,  it  belongs  to  the  public  treasury;  this  last 
view  being  approved  by  the  Majma'.  The  above  applies 
in  case  the  two  parties  agree  that  the  thing  found  is  a  treas- 
ure-trove, for  if  the  owner  of  the  land  says  that  he  had  him- 
self buried  it,  his  statement  is  believed  after  he  has  sworn  to 
it.  The  argument  of  Abu  Hanifah  and  Muhammad  is 
that  the  person  to  whom  the  land  was  given  after  conquest 
owns  both  its  surface  and  what  is  below  the  surface,  and 
when  later  he  sells  it  to  others,  he  transfers  the  ownership 
of  the  surface  of  the  land  only,  not  the  inside  of  it;  hence 
the  treasures  buried  in  the  land  remain  the  property  of  the 
original  owner,  exactly  as  the  pearl  found  in  the  belly  of  a 
fish  belongs  to  the  person  who  caught  it,  not  the  party  who 
bought  the  fish  from  him.  The  reasons  for  the  view  of  Abu 
Yusuf  who  in  this  connection  departs  from  analogy  and 
judges  by  istihsan,  is  that  the  person  who  found  the  treas- 
ure is  the  one  who  really  discovered  and  occupied  it.  Be- 


42O 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


sides,  it  may  not  be  said  that  the  imam,  in  dividing  the  lands 
after  conquest,  also  transferred  the  ownership  of  the  treas- 
ures possibly  buried  in  the  lands,  because  the  imam  is  just, 
and  such  a  thing  would  result  in  injustice,  since  all  lands 
are  not  alike  in  respect  to  treasures.  Consequently  the 
treasures  continue  to  be  property  of  no  one,  and  the  person 
who  discovers  them  owns  them.  The  others  reply  that  the 
imam  is  only  obliged  to  be  just  within  the  bounds  of  the 
possible,  and  he  cannot  possibly  be  so  with  respect  to  the 
treasures ;  moreover,  it  is  not  claimed  that  the  imam  actually 
transfers  the  ownership  of  the  treasures  buried  in  the  land, 
but  simply  that  he  prevents  other  soldiers  from  encroach- 
ing on  them  and  that  for  this  reason  they  become  the  prop- 
erty of  the  person  to  whom  the  land  including  them  was 
given.1  Mines  lying  in  a  piece  of  land,  however,  belong  to 
the  present  owner,  because,  according  to  the  Hidayah,2  un- 
like treasures  which  are  distinct  from  the  land  where  they 
are  buried  and  are,  as  it  were,  trusts  to  the  land,  mines  are 
intimately  mixed  with  the  particles  of  the  land,  and  there- 
fore when  the  land  is  sold  the  mines  are  also  sold. 

If  a  person  enters  the  land  of  the  harbis  by  way  of 
aman  and  finds  in  the  country,  that  is,  in  a  land  which  is 
not  owned  by  any  one,  a  mine  or  a  treasure,  (according 
to  some,  a  mine  only),  the  whole  of  the  find  belongs  to  the 
finder,  since,  not  being  in  the  possession  of  any  one,  no 
injustice  is  involved.  According  to  Abu  Yusuf,  one-fifth 
of  the  find  is  taken  as  a  tax.  If,  however,  the  find  is 
discovered  in  a  house  or  land  owned  by  a  harbi,  the  find 
is  then  returned  to  the  owner  of  the  house  or  the  land,  since 
he  owns  what  is  in  them  also.  If  the  finder  fails  to  return 
the  find  to  its  owner,  but  brings  it  with  him  on  his  return 

1  Mabsiit,  p.  214. 
*  P.  183. 


OTHER  SOURCES  OF  REVENUE         421 

to  the  Moslem  country,  the  find  becomes  his  property, 
but  it  is  an  impure  (kliabith)  property.  With  respect  to 
property  found  by  a  Moslem  in  the  territory  of  the  harbis, 
the  Path  *  observes  that,  although  property  found  under 
similar  circumstances  by  a  harbl  in  Moslem  territory  be- 
longs to  the  Moslem  state,  property  found  in  the  territory 
of  the  harbis  by  a  Moslem  belongs  to  the  latter,  because, 
the  land  of  the  harbis  being  one  where  law  does  not  rule, 
only  actual  possession  there  counts ;  the  Moslem  land  on  the 
contrary,  is  one  of  law,  and  in  the  eyes  of  the  law,  hypo- 
thetical (hukmi)  possession  is  like  actual  possession.  The 
above  applies  in  case  the  Moslem  entered  the  territory  of 
the  harbis  after  having  obtained  aman  from  the  harbis; 
for  if  he  entered  without  aman  for  the  purpose  of  robbing, 
such  property  as  he  finds  in  the  country  is  not  taxed,  since 
the  tax  is  levied  on  spoils  only  and  this  property  is  not  a 
spoil  of  war. 

According  to  the  Shafiites,2  treasure-trove  of  pre-Islamic 
origin  is  subject  to  zakat  at  the  rate  of  one-fifth,  if  it 
consists  of  gold  or  silver  and  is  of  nisdb  quantity.  The 
lapse  of  a  year,  however,  is  not  required.  Because  the  tax 
levied  on  treasure-trove  is  zakat,  the  dhimmis  do  not  pay  it. 

According  to  the  Malikites,3  treasure-trove  of  pre- 
Islamic  or  doubtful  origin  is  subject  to  a  tax  of  one-fifth, 
whether  it  is  in  large  or  small  quantity,  gold  or  silver  or 
other  than  gold  or  silver,  found  by  Moslems  or  found  by 
infidels.  Treasure-trove  is,  however,  subject  to  zakat  if 
its  unearthing  involved  great  labor  or  expense,  and  in  such 
case  all  the  conditions  of  zakat  must  be  met  excepting  the 
one  concerning  the  lapse  of  a  year. 

1  P.  184. 

*  Minhdj,  p.  248;  Wajlz,  p.  97;  Mawardi,  p.  207. 

3Kharashi,  p.  113. 


422  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

SECTION  III 

The  Tax  on  non-Moslem  Traders,  and  the  Estates  of 
Deceased  Persons 

The  tax  on  non-Moslem  traders,  whether  they  are  dhim- 
mis,  or  harbis  who  entered  the  Moslem  state  with  aman 
(mustafmin)  for  trade,  is  collected  by  the  'ashirs,  who  also 
collect  from  Moslems,  who  pass  them  on  the  public  road, 
their  zakat  dues.  As  the  details  pertaining  to  the  rates 
and  the  method  of  collection  have  been  already  explained  in 
the  first  two  sections  of  chapter  III  on  Collection,  they  will 
not  be  repeated  here. 

The  estates  of  deceased  persons  or  the  blood  price  of 
murdered  persons  who  left  no  lawful  heirs,  or  left  only  a 
husband  or  a  wife,  and  who  have  not  disposed  of  these 
estates  by  will  are  a  source  of  negligible  importance,  and 
therefore  need  only  to  be  enumerated  here  in  order  to 
complete  the  list.1 

1  Kasani,  p.  68. 


CHAPTER  IX 

THE  PUBLIC  TREASURY  AND  THE  MOHAMMEDAN  COUN- 
TERPART OF  A  BUDGET 

EVERY  property  (mal)  which  belongs  to  Moslems  in 
general  and  not  to  any  Moslem  in  particular  constitutes  a 
part  of  the  assets  (huquq)  of  the  public  treasury  (bayt-al- 
mal).  It  is  not  necessary  that  the  property  should  be  actu- 
ally in  the  vaults  (Jjirs)  of  the  treasury  for  it  to  be  con- 
sidered an  asset  of  the  treasury,  because  the  conception  of 
bayt-al-mal  refers  to  the  destination  (jihah)  of  the  prop- 
erty, not  to  its  actual  location.  Therefore  every  expendi- 
ture (haqq)  which  must  be  incurred  in  the  interests  of 
Moslems  in  general  (masalih  al-muslimin)  is  a  liability  of 
bayt-al-mal  and  when  it  is  made,  it  is  considered  to  have 
been  made  by  it,  whether  or  not  it  has  actually  been  paid  out 
of  the  vaults  of  bayt-al-mal ;  this  is  for  the  reason  that  a 
revenue  which  has  gone  into  the  hands  of  the  public  col- 
lectors or  has  been  spent  directly  by  them  is  really  a  part 
of  the  income  and  outgo  of  the  bayt-al-mal  itself,  and  is 
therefore  subject  to  the  regulations  governing  the  same. 

In  other  words,  according  to  the  Shafiite  conception,  the 
term  "public  treasury"  applies  only  to  those  revenues  of  the 
Moslem  community  or  state  whose  disbursement  has  not 
been  prescribed  by  the  sharl'ah  in  favor  of  definite  classes 
of  Moslems,  but  which  belong  to  the  Moslem  community 
at  large  and  are  disbursed  by  the  imam,  its  lawful  head, 
for  the  common  Moslem  interests,  namely,  in  meeting  the 

1  Mawardi,  p.  366. 

423 


424  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

general  expenses  of  the  state.  The  "  public  treasury  ",  then, 
does  not  exhaust  the  various  items  of  revenue  accruing  to 
the  Moslem  community  or  state,1  for  a  revenue  might  be 
a  source  of  income  to  the  state  to  meet  its  obligations  and 
yet  technically  not  be  a  part  of  the  assets  of  the  public  treas- 
ury. Consequently,  the  distinction  of  revenue  between  these 
two  classes  does  not  mean  that  because  an  item  of  revenue 
is  not  an  asset  of  the  public  treasury  it  is  not  also  a  revenue 
of  the  state;  in  the  last  analysis  it  amounts  to  this,  namely, 
that  certain  of  the  activities  of  the  Moslem  state,  as  well  as 
the  revenues  and  the  expenses  necessary  for  them,  owing  to 
their  importance,  have  been  defined  and  prescribed  by  the 
shari'ah  itself,  while  other  activities  considered  less  im- 
portant, and,  as  it  were,  matters  of  course,  were  left  to  the 
discretion  of  the  constituted  authorities  of  the  Moslem  state. 
The  revenue  necessary  for  these  latter  activities  constitutes 
the  assets  of  the  public  treasury. 

The  Malikites,  although  they  do  not  expressly  state  the 
meaning  of  bayt-al-mal,  nevertheless  imply  by  their  use 
of  the  term,2  that  they  hold  a  similar  view  of  the  matter. 
Finally,  the  Hanifites,  likewise  fail  expressly  to  define  their 
position,  but  the  fact  that  they  apply  the  expression  to  all 
the  revenue  of  the  state  *  would  force  one  to  the  conclusion 
that  they  mean  by  it  every  revenue  which  accrues  to  the 
state,  whether  or  not  the  imam  has  a  free  hand  in  its  dis- 
bursement. 

1  One  may  distinguish  three  kinds  of  re  venue:  revenue  for  the  Moslem 
community  proper,  such  as  the  four-fifths  of  the  spoils  divided  among 
the  victorious  army;  revenue  for  the  state,  such  as  the  fifth  part  of 
the  spoils  set  apart  for  the  state;  finally,  there  is  revenue  for  the 
public  treasury  as  distinct  from  either. 

J  Kharashi,  p.  121,  1.  3;  pp.  127,  427;  'Adawi,  p.  123;  Ibn  Rushd,  B., 
P-  329- 

8  Bahr,  vol.  v,  p.  128 ;  Majtna',  p.  520 ;  Kasani,  p.  68. 


THE  PUBLIC  TREASURY  425 

There  are  *  three  distinct  classes  of  revenue  (tnal)  which 
accrue  to  the  Moslem  community  or  the  Moslem  state  as 
distinct  from  the  public  treasury  (bayt-al-mal).  They  are: 
(i)  the  sadaqah  or  zakat  revenue  (amwal  al-sadaqat), 
such  as  the  zakat  and  tithe;  (2)  the  booty  revenue  (garii- 
mah),  namely,  the  spoils  of  war;  (3)  the  fa'y  revenue, 
such  as  the  jisyah  and  the  kharaj.  The  first  applies  to 
revenue  derived  from  Moslems,  the  other  two  apply  to 
revenue  taken  from  infidels.  Gammah  means  property 
taken  from  the  infidels  by  assault  ('anwat)  with  arms  in 
hand,  whereas  fa'y  2  is  property  given  by  the  infidels  "spon- 
taneously ('afzua)  3  without  fighting  and  without  making 
horses  and  riders  run."  4 

These  three  classes  of  revenue  differ 5  from  one  another 
as  follows:  The  sadaqah  revenue  differs  from  the  other 
two  classes  in  four  respects : 

( i )  The  sadaqah  is  received  from  the  Moslems  for  their 
purification;  the  others  are  taken  from  the  infidels  for  re- 
venge. 

1  Mawardi,  p.  217;  (7mm,  vol.  iv,  p.  63. 

3  Fa'y  literally  means  "  that  which  came  back,"  in  this  instance,  as  al- 
ShafVi  (Muzani,  vol.  iii,  p.  183)  remarks,  "that  which  God  returned  to 
His  people  (without  fighting  on  their  part)  from  those  who  opposed 
His  religion,"  the  theory  implied  being  that  property  taken  as  spoils,  as 
a  matter  of  law,  belongs  to  the  Moslems.  (Cf.  Berchem,  p.  9.)  Ac- 
cording to  some,  fa'y  is  spoils  taken  without  difficulty  (al-Ragib). 
According  to  Abu  'Ubayd,  it  is  property  taken  from  the  enemy  after 
the  cessation  of  hostilities,  such  property  belonging  to  all  the  Moslems. 
According  to  the  Mafdtlh  (p.  58),  it  is  the  revenue  derived  from  a 
country  conquered  by  force.  According  to  'Ali  Ibn  'Isa,  fa'y  is  more 
general  than  ganintah  (spoils),  applying  to  everything  accruing  to  the 
Moslems  from  the  enemy  (Mugrib,  vol.  ii,  p.  80).  Finally,  according 
to  the  Mijbdh,  it  is  the  kharaj  and  the  spoils. 

1  According  to  Ibn  Rushd,  B.  (p.  325),  "through  terror  and  fear." 

'Cf.  Yahya,  p.  3. 

6  Mawardi,  p.  217;  cf.  Umtn,  vol.  iv,  p.  614. 


426  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

(2)  The  destination  of  the  sadaqah  has  been  entirely  de- 
termined by  special  provision  (nass),  whereas  that  of  the 
others  is  partly  determined  by  the  imam's  ijtihad. 

(3)  In  the  case  of  sadaqah,  the  taxpayers  may  themselves 
pay  it  directly  to  the  beneficiaries,  while  this  is  not  allowed 
in  the  others. 

(4)  The  destination  of  the  sadaqah  is  different  from  that 
of  the  others. 

As  regards  the  ganimah  and  fafy  revenues,  they  agree  and 
differ  in  two  points  respectively: 

(1)  The  points  of  agreement:  both  are  taken  from  in- 
fidels, and  one-fifth  of  both  is  disbursed  alike. 

(2)  The  points  of  difference:  ganimah  is  taken  by  force 
of  arms  (qahra),  whereas  fa'y  is  taken  peacefully  (fafwa), 
and  secondly,  the  beneficiaries  of  the  four-fifths  of  the 
ganimah  are  different  from  the  beneficiaries  of  the  four- 
fifths  of  the  fa'y.1 

2  Of  the  above  three  classes  of  revenue  which  may  ac- 
crue to  the  Moslem  community  or  the  state,  namely,  the 
sadaqah,  booty,  and  fa'y  revenues,  the  (four-fifths  of)  fa'y 
revenue  is  a  part  of  the  public  treasury  because  its  dis- 
position is  made  according  to  the  personal  judgment  of  the 
imam.  On  the  contrary,  the  (four-fifths  of)  booty  reve- 
nue is  not  a  part  of  the  treasury — and  on  this  point  the 
Hanifite  and  Malikite  views  are  at  one, — for  the  benefic- 
iaries of  the  booty  revenue  have  been  prescribed  by  express 
revealed  provision  (nass),  and  are  definite  persons,  namely, 
the  army  who  fought  the  battle,  and  the  imam  may  not  dis- 
pose of  the  booty  in  any  other  way. 

As  regards  the  fifth  part  of  the  fa'y  revenue,  and  the 

1  The  above  is  according  to  the  Shafiites.  The  Hanifite  and  Malikite 
views  somewhat  differ. 
8  Mawardi,  p.  367. 


THE  PUBLIC  TREASURY 


427 


state's  part  of  one-fifth  of  the  booty  revenue,  each  con- 
sists of  three  distinct  parts:  (a)  part  of  it,  the  Prophet's 
share,  belongs  to  the  treasury,  since  it  is  disposed  of  by  the 
imam  of  the  community  for  the  time  being  according  to  his 
own  judgment;  (b)  part  of  it,  namely,  the  share  of  the 
Prophet's  relations  (dhawu  al-qurba)  does  not  belong  to 
the  treasury,  since  its  beneficiaries  are  known,  and  the  imam 
has  no  voice  in  its  disposition;  (c)  finally,  a  third  part  is 
kept  in  the  treasury  as  a  trust  fund  on  account  of  the  var- 
ious purposes  for  which  it  is  destined.  This  last  part  con- 
sists of  the  shares  set  aside  for  orphans,  the  indigent,  and 
wayfarers.  They  receive  their  shares,  if  they  are  present; 
otherwise  their  shares  are  kept  for  them. 

Applying  the  Shafiite  conception  of  public  treasury  to 
the  Malikite  view,1  the  entire  fa'y  and  the  state's  part  of 
one-fifth  of  the  booty  revenue  would  be  assets  of  the  public 
treasury,  for,  according  to  the  Malikites,  both  are  disposed 
of  by  the  imam  according  to  his  own  proper  judgment. 
Finally,  applying  the  same  test  to  the  Hanifite  views,  the 
entire  fa'y  revenue  would  be  distinctly  an  asset  of  the  public 
treasury.  On  the  other  hand  the  state's  part  of  one-fifth 
of  the  booty  revenue  would  be  outside  of  the  public  treas- 
ury to  the  extent  that  it  must  be  disbursed  to  definite 
classes  of  people,  such  as  orphans;  though,  in  so  far  as  it 
may  be  disbursed  by  the  imam  to  any  one  of  those  classes 
exclusively,  it  might  properly  be  classed  as  an  asset  of  the 
public  treasury. 

Finally,  the  sadaqah  revenue  is  of  two  kinds:  the 
sadaqah  revenue  levied  on  non-apparent  property,  which 
does  not  form  a  part  of  the  treasury's  income,  since 
the  property  owners  may  themselves  disburse  their  zakat 
dues  directly  to  the  beneficiaries,  such  as  the  poor,  with- 

1  Kharashi,  p.  427. 


428  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

out  resorting  to  the  intermediary  of  the  public  collectors; 
secondly,  the  sadaqah  revenue  derived  from  apparent  prop- 
erty; namely,  the  tithe  and  the  zakat  collected  from 
cattle.  This  second  kind  of  sadaqah  revenue,  according  to 
al-Shafi'i,  is  not  a  part  of  the  treasury,  because  the  bene- 
ficiaries are  known  and  the  funds  may  not  be  disposed  of  in 
any  other  way.  Al-Shafi'i,  however,  holds  two  different 
views  concerning  the  lawfulness  of  keeping  this  revenue 
in  the  treasury  as  a  trust  when  it  is  not  possible,  for  some 
reason  or  other,  to  disburse  it  to  its  beneficiaries.  His 
earlier  opinion  was  that  such  funds  should  be  kept  in  the 
treasury  as  a  trust  until  the  appearance  of  the  rightful 
claimants.  Later,  al-Shafi'i  abandoned  this  opinion  in  favor 
of  his  later  opinion  which  is  that  the  treasury  may  not  keep 
these  funds  in  its  vaults  as  a  matter  of  right,  although  they 
may  be  entrusted  to  the  treasury  for  safekeeping. 

Applying  the  Shafiite  conception  of  public  treasury  to 
the  Hanifite  views  concerning  the  disbursement  of  zakat 
revenue  from  apparent  property,  we  may  say  that  to  the  ex- 
tent that  such  revenue  must  be  disbursed  to  certain  specified 
classes  of  people  it  is  not  a  part  of  the  public  treasury,  but  in 
so  far  as  the  imam  may  disburse  it  to  any  one  or  more  of 
those  classes  exclusively,  and  in  view  of  the  comprehensive 
and  loose  meaning  which  has  been  given  to  those  classes, 
such  revenue  may  properly  be  said  to  be  a  part  of  the  public 
treasury.  The  zakat  from  non-apparent  property,  however, 
is  in  no  way  a  part  of  the  public  treasury.  What  is  true 
of  the  Hanifites  as  regards  zakat  from  apparent  property 
is  even  more  true  of  the  Malikites,  for,  according  to  the 
latter,  the  imam  might  disburse  the  entire  sadaqah  revenue 
to  public  functionaries  exclusively,  even  if  they  should  be 
rich.  Moreover,  as  we  have  already  seen,  the  Malikites 
practically  assimilated  the  zakat  of  non-apparent  property  to 


THE  PUBLIC  TREASURY 


429 


that  of  apparent  property  by  requiring  the  payment  of  the 
former  to  the  state  officials.1 

A  detailed  description  of  the  various  items  of  revenue, 
classed  by  the  three  schools  under  one  or  the  other  of  the 
three  classes  of  revenue  above  mentioned,  follows : 

(i)  The  sadaqah  or  zakat  revenue  designated  in  this 
dissertation  under  the  expression  of  zakat  taxes,  according 
to  the  Hanifites,2  consists  of  the  zakat  of  non-apparent  prop- 
erty disbursed  to  the  zakat  beneficiaries  directly  by  the 
owners,  namely,  the  zak&t  of  gold  and  silver  and  the  zakat 
of  the  articles  of  trade;  as  well  as  the  zakat  of  apparent 
property  collected  and  disbursed  by  the  state,  as  the 
zakat  of  animals,  the  zakat  collected  by  the  'ashirs  from 
apparent  and  non-apparent  property  of  Moslems  only,  and 
the  zakat  of  produce  or  tithe.  According  to  the  Shafiites,* 
the  tax  of  one-fifth  levied  on  treasure-trove  (rikaz}  and 
the  tax  collected  on  mines  (ma'dan)  also  form  a  part  of 
zakat  revenue.  Al-Shafi'i,  in  this  connection,  remarks  that 
whatever  is  due  on  a  Moslem's  property  in  virtue  of  a  pre- 
scription found  in  the  Koran,  or  the  sunnah,  or  an  ijmaf  of 
Moslem  laymen  ('awamm  al-muslimin,  that  is,  all  Moslems, 
laymen  or  mujtahids),  "its  meaning  is  one,  namely,  it  is 
zakat,  and  zakat  is  sadaqah,  and  its  disbursement  is  always 
one  and  the  same  as  God  divided  the  sadaqahs."  Accord- 
ing to  the  Malikites,  on  the  other  hand,  taxes  levied  on 
mines  and  treasure-trove  are  a  part  of  sadaqah  revenue 
only  in  so  far  as  they  are  levied  at  the  regular  zakat  rate 
of  one-fortieth.4 

^Adawi,  p.  120. 

1  Majma',  p.  520;  Kasani,  p.  68;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  268;  Bafrr,  vol.  v, 
p.  128. 

3  Utntn,  p.  71 ;  Wajlz,  pp.  96,  97;  Minhdj,  pp.  247,  248. 
4Kharashi,  pp.  in    113,  427. 


430 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


(2)  Booty  (gammah)  revenue  consists  of  spoils  of  war, 
mines,  and  treasure-trove.     One-fifth  of  the  booty  revenue 
is  levied  by  the  state  as  a  tax.    According  to  the  Shafiites, 
booty  revenue  consists  of  the  spoils  of  war  alone.    The  tax 
levied  on  mines  and  treasure-trove  is  considered  by  them 
as  zakat.    Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,  the  tax  levied 
on  mines  and  treasure-trove  is  considered  booty  revenue 
only  if  levied  under  the  name  of  one-fifth  (khums).1     This 
tax  applies  to  the  treasure-trove,  and,  in  mines,  to  the  gold 
or  silver  ingots  called  nadrat,  provided  the  unearthing  of 
neither  has  involved  great  expense  or  labor.    In  the  latter 
case,  treasure-trove,  as  well  as  nadrats,  are  subject  to  zakat. 

(3)  The  fa'y  revenue  consists  of  the  kharaj,  the  jizyah, 
the  dresses   (hullah)   paid  by  the  people  of  Najran,  the 
double  rate  of  zakat  paid  by  the  tribe  of  Taglib,  the  tolls 
collected  by  the  'ashirs  from  the  dhimmi  and  harbi  traders, 
and   the   estates   of   dhimmis  who   left  no  will   and   no 
heirs,  or  only  a  husband  or  wife,2  also 8  the  payment  for  a 
truce    (hudnah),  property  taken   from  a  country  whose 
population  has  fled,  property  given  to  the  Moslems  by  the 
harbis  as  a  gift,  property  belonging  to  apostates  (murtadd), 
etc.    The  Malikites  merge  this  and  the  preceding  class  into 
one  single  class  so  far  as  disbursement  is  concerned.4 

(4)  According  to  the  Hanifites,  there  is  a  fourth  class 
of  revenue  consisting  of  property  lost  and  found  (luqaiati), 

1  Because  the  rate  of  one-fifth  is  the  rate  prescribed  for  the  spoils  of 
war,  the  Malikites,  unlike  the  Shafiites,  consider  every  revenue  collected 
on  the  basis  of  such  a  rate  as  identical  with  the  revenue  derived  from 
the  spoils  of  war. 

2  Bahr,  vol.  v,  p.  127;  but  cf.  Path  al-Mu'ln,  vol.  ii,  p.  456;  Majma', 
p.  520;  Kharashi,  p.  427.    On  wills  of  dhimmis,  see  Majma',  vol.  ii,  pp. 
564-5;  Path  al-Mu'ln,  vol.  iii,  p.  546;    Wajiz,  p.  269;   Kharashi,  pp. 
444-5- 

8  Umm,  vol.  iv,  p.  77 ;  Wajlz,  p.  288. 
*  Kharashi,  p.  427. 


THE  PUBLIC  TREASURY  43 x 

and  the  estates  (tarakah)  left  by  Moslems,1  who  leave  no 
heirs,  or  leave  only  a  husband  or  wife.2 

As  the  appropriation  of  the  first  three  classes  owing  to 
their  importance  will  be  discussed  separately,  only  the  ex- 
penditure of  the  fourth  class  will  be  explained  here.  The 
revenue  from  this  source  is  appropriated  for  the  support 
of  sick  people  who  are  poor,  and  for  the  buying  of  their 
medicines,  for  the  funeral  expenses  of  the  dead  who  leave 
no  estates,  for  the  support  of  foundlings  (laqlt),  for  com- 
pensation for  crimes  committed  by  them,  for  the  support 
of  persons  who  are  unable  to  earn  a  living  and  who  do  not 
have  a  relation  on  whom  their  support  legally  rests,  and 
for  similar  purposes.3 

It  is  the  duty  of  the  imam  to  keep  each  of  the  above- 
mentioned  four  classes  of  revenue  apart  from  the  others  in 
separate  treasuries,  because  each  has  certain  peculiarities  of 
its  own.  If  no  property  is  available  in  one  of  them,  the 
imam  may  borrow  funds  on  its  account  from  the  others. 
When  he  does  so;  if  for  instance,  he  borrows  money  on 
account  of  the  kharaj  treasury  from  the  zakat  treasury;  he 
must  return  the  amount  borowed  from  the  latter  when  the 
kharaj  is  collected,  unless  the  fighters  who  are  beneficiaries 
of  the  kharaj  are  poor;  in  the  latter  case  the  fighters  by 
being  poor  have  a  share  also  in  the  proceeds  of  zakat,  and 
therefore  the  amount  taken  from  the  treasury  of  sakat  is 
not  really  a  loan.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  imam  borrows 

1  Bahr,  vol.  v,  p.  127;  but  cf.  Path  al-Mu'in,  vol.  ii,  p.  456;  also, 
Kasani,  p.  68;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  268;  Majma',  p.  520. 

a  When  the  husband  or  the  wife  is  the  only  heir,  he  or  she  is  entitled 
to  the  prescribed  share  (faridah)  only,  the  rest  devolving  to  the  state. 
It  would,  however,  be  a  different  matter  if  the  only  heir  were  another 
relative,  say,  a  sister,  for  she  being  of  the  class  of  heirs  called  sahib 
al-radd  (literally,  one  to  whom  the  balance  is  turned  over),  receives 
also  the  balance  after  the  deduction  of  her  prescribed  share. 

*  Majma',  p.  520;  Kasani,  p.  68;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  268. 


432  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

money  on  behalf  of  the  zakat  account  from  that  of  the 
kharaj  and  distributes  it  to  the  poor,  it  does  not  become  a 
loan  on  the  charge  of  the  poor,  because,  the  kharaj  being 
treated  like  (lahu  hukm  al-fa'y)  the  fa'y  and  the  gariimah, 
which  are  disbursed  to  provide  for  the  needs  of  the  Moslems, 
the  poor  have  a  share  in  them,  and  if  they  do  not  actually 
receive  a  share  from  them,  it  is  only  because  the  proceeds 
of  the  zakat  revenue  are  sufficient  for  their  needs.1 

According  to  al-Mawardi,2  if  the  treasury  has  to  meet 
two  claims,*  while  there  are  sufficient  funds  for  only  one 
of  them,  that  claim  is  settled  first  which  is  a  debt  (dayn) 
upon  the  treasury.  If  the  funds  are  not  sufficient  for  either 
claim,  then  it  is  allowed  to  the  official  in  charge  to  borrow 
money  on  account  of  the  treasury  in  order  to  settle  the 
debts,  if  he  fears  that  a  contrary  policy  would  result  in 
evils;  but  he  may  not  borrow  money  to  settle  claims  which 
are  in  the  nature  of  donations  (irtifaq).  When  he  bor- 
rows money,  his  successor  is  obliged  to  pay  back  the  loans 
as  soon  as  the  treasury  has  sufficient  funds.  If,  on  the 
contrary,  the  funds  of  the  treasury  are  more  than  sufficient 
for  the  settlement  of  the  claims,  opinion  varies  as  to  the  man- 
ner in  which  the  surplus  should  be  disposed.  Abu  Hani- 
f ah  holds  that  the  surplus  must  be  laid  aside  in  the  treasury 
in  order  to  meet  future  emergencies,  but  al-Shafi'i  thinks 
that  the  surplus  is  not  laid  aside,  because  the  meeting  of 
future  emergencies  becomes  an  obligation  only  after  the 
emergencies  have  occurred.  A  similar  view  is  expressed 
in  the  'Alamklriyyah,  where  it  is  stated  that  when  there  is 
any  surplus  left  it  is  divided  among  the  Moslems  at  large, 

1  'Alantkiriyyah,  p.  268;  Mabsut,  part  iii,  p.  17;  cf.  p.  18. 

1  P.  369. 

8  Of  course,  here  it  is  a  question  of  claims  which  have  to  be  paid  out 
of  the  same  class  oT  revenue. 
4 'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  268. 


THE  PUBLIC  TREASURY  433 

and  if  the  im&m  fails  to  do  this,  he  suffers  the  evil  conse- 
quences of  his  failure.  It  is  the  duty  of  the  imam  to  dis- 
burse the  revenues  to  their  rightful  claimants  and  not  to 
deprive  them  of  their  rights.  The  imam  and  his  assistants 
are  not  allowed  to  take  from  these  revenues  more  than 
the  needs  of  their  families  and  themselves,  and  they  are  not 
allowed  to  hoard  the  revenues.  It  is  recommended  that 
the  imam  and  the  collector  do  not  advance  to  themselves 
their  salaries  for  the  coming  month,  but  that  they  take  their 
salaries  only  for  the  current  month. 

The  dhimmis  have  no  share  in  the  revenues  of  the 
treasury,  except  when  the  imam  sees  a  dhimmi  starving 
from  hunger,  in  which  case  it  is  his  duty  to  give  him  some- 
thing from  the  treasury,  because  the  dhimmi  is  residing  in 
the  Moslem  state  and  the  imam  is  under  obligation  ('atoyhi) 
to  keep  him  alive.1 

According  to  al-Shafi'i,s  the  imam  may  not  disburse  to 
dhimmis  from  the  fa'y  revenue,  any  more  than  he  may  do 
so  from  spoils  and  sadaqah  revenue.  For  all  these  revenues 
(mal  allah)  belong  to  Moslem  beneficiaries  and  "  it  is  pro- 
hibited (har&m)  for  the  imam — but  God,  may  He  be  ex- 
alted, knows  better — to  take  a  Moslem's  right  and  give  it 
to  another,  and  how  (might  he  give  it)  to  a  dhimmi\" 
for  whom  God  assigned  no  share  in  any  one  of  those 
revenues. 

There  has  been  difference  of  opinion  among  the  dis- 
ciples of  al-Shafi'i*  on  the  question  as  to  whether  real 
estate  devolving  to  the  public  treasury  by  that  very  fact 
becomes  immobilized  (waqf).  Some  hold  that  these  estates 
by  becoming  a  part  of  the  treasury  assets  become  immo- 

1  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  260;  but  cf.  al-Sarakhsi  (Mabstf,  part  iii,  p.  19). 
1  Umm,  vol.  iv,  p.  102. 
*  Mawardi,  p.  336. 


434  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

bilized  in  order  that  their  income  may  be  used  for  the  gen- 
eral expenses  of  the  treasury,  and  that  therefore  their  sale 
and  concession  (iqtaf)  are  unlawful.1  Others  hold  that  they 
do  not  become  immobilized  until  they  are  so  constituted  by 
the  imam,  and  that  hence  the  imam  may  sell  them  if  he  sees 
fit  for  the  interests  of  the  treasury.  The  price  realized  is 
expended  for  the  general  needs  of  the  treasury  and  for  those 
of  the  beneficiaries  of  fa'y  and  sadaqah  who  are  in  need. 
With  regard  to  the  concession  (iqta')  of  the  ownership  of 
such  estates,  it  is  said  that  such  concession  is  lawful  since 
it  is  lawful  to  sell  them  and  give  away  their  price  to  people 
who  are  in  need  and  for  other  general  needs  approved  by  the 
imam.  In  fact,  there  is  no  difference  between  alienating 
the  ownership  of  real  estate  and  giving  away  the  price  real- 
ized from  its  sale.  Others  contend  that  such  estates  may 
be  sold  because  a  sale  is  a  bilateral  transaction,  but  that 
their  concession  is  unlawful,  because  that  is  a  case  of  dona- 
tion (sttah)  and  in  the  matter  of  donations,  fleeting  cash  dif- 
fers from  the  permanent  real  estate  of  which  it  is  the  price. 
According  to  the  Hanifites,  real  estate  ((aqar)  such  as 
lands  devolving  to  the  public  treasury  becomes,  according 
to  one  opinion,  a  perpetual  waqf  (waqf  mu'abbad),2  but 
the  general  view  is  that  such  real  estate  is  like  that  of  the 
orphan;  the  authority  of  the  imam  or  the  guardian  (wali) 
being  valid  with  respect  to  the  real  estate  of  the  public  treas- 
ury or  the  orphan  respectively,  only  in  so  far  as  it  is  con- 
ducive to  their  interests.  According  to  one  view,  real  estate 
of  the  public  treasury  differs  from  that  of  orphans  as  well 
as  from  waqf  estates  in  that,  unlike  them,  it  may  be  leased 
for  indefinite  terms.3 

1  Cf.  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  297 ;  Wajiz,  pp.  248,  289. 

*Al-'Uqud  al-Durriyyah,  p.  176. 

*  Itkdf  al-Absdr,  p.  191 ;  Durr,  p.  364;  Fatb  al-Mu'lnt  vol.  ii,  pp.  446-7. 


THE  PUBLIC  TREASURY  435 

Finally,  the  Malikite  view  in  regard  to  real  estate  con- 
quered by  force  from  the  infidels,  as  we  have  already  seen,  is 
to  the  effect  that  such  estate  by  the  very  fact  of  conquest 
becomes  waqf  property.1 

According  to  the  Malikites,2  the  sale  by  the  state  of  its 
waqf  estates  is  unlawful.  According  to  the  earlier  Hani- 
fite  authorities,  the  alienation  by  sale  of  the  real  estate  of 
orphans,  and,  by  analogy,  that  of  the  public  treasury  is  only 
allowed  ( I )  in  case  of  need  for  funds  which  could  not  other- 
wise be  procured.  Later  authorities  however  allow  it  in 
six  other  contingencies;  (2)  if  there  is  a  demand  for  it  at 
double  its  value;  (3)  if  the  deceased  left  debts  to  be  settled; 
(4)  if  the  deceased  left  a  will  (wasiyat  mursalah)  which 
can  only  be  executed  by  selling  the  real  estate;  (5) 
if  the  income  from  the  estate  does  not  exceed  its  expense; 
(6)  if  the  estate  consists  in  a  house  or  store  whose  depre- 
ciation is  feared;  (7)  finally,  if  the  estate  is  in  the  hands  of 
a  person  of  power  (mutagallib),  and  it  is  feared  that  he  will 
appropriate  it,  it  may  be  sold  to  him.1 

It  is  not  lawful  for  the  imam  to  buy  a  land  of  the  public 
treasury  from  the  agent  (wakll)  of  the  latter,  but  if  he 

1  It  must  be  pointed  out  that  while  the  Shafiite  and  Hanifite  views 
above  quoted  refer  to  any  real  estate  which  became  an  asset  of  the 
public  treasury,  the  Malikite  view  refers  only  to  such  estate  as  has 
been  conquered  from  the  infidels  by  force  ('anwat).    What  the  Mali- 
kite  view  is  concerning  real  estate  in  general,  I  have  been  unable  to 
discover,  but  the  fact  that  the  Malikite  doctors,  speaking  of  lands  of 
deceased  dhimntis,  refer  to  their  devolving  to  "the  Moslems  in  gen- 
eral" rather  than  to  their  being  made  waqf  (Kharashi,  p.  427;   Ibn 
Rushd.,  M.,  p.  280),   as  occurs  with  respect  to  lands   conquered   by 
force,  would  seem  to  indicate  that  according  to  the  Malikites  the  dis- 
position of  such  lands  is  left  to  the  judgment  of  the  imdm.     Such  a 
construction  is  also  borne  out  by  the  Malikite  policy  of  allowing  the 
imdm  greater  latitude  than  is  customary  with  the  other  schools. 

2  Kharashi,  vol.  v,  pp.  94-5. 

1  Majma',  vol.  ii,  p.  571 ;  also  vol.  i,  p.  561 ;  Quduri,  p.  65. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

desires  to  buy  a  certain  land,  according  to  an  opinion  cited 
in  the  Waqi'at,  he  first  orders  the  sale  of  the  land  to  a  third 
party  and  then  buys  it  from  that  party.  If  the  conditions  of 
the  purchase  of  a  public  treasury  land  are  not  known,  the 
presumption  is  that  the  purchase  was  valid.  It  is  lawful 
to  constitute  a  waqf  of  a  land  bought  from  the  public  treas- 
ury, and  in  such  case  the  conditions  of  the  waqf  founder 
are  valid,  and  the  land  is  exempt  from  kharaj. 

The  liabilities  x  of  the  public  treasury  are  of  two  kinds: 
( i )  Liabilities  resulting  from  property  kept  in  the  treasury 
for  safe-keeping  (hirs)  as  trust.  Such  liabilities  are  en- 
forceable by  the  claimants  only  when  the  funds  are  present 
in  the  treasury,  but  the  claimants  have  no  action  against 
the  treasury  when  there  are  no  funds.  (2)  Liabilities 
arising  with  respect  to  revenues  which  are  the  treasury's 
own  assets,  (a)  One  part  of  these  liabilities  is  incurred 
for  value  received  (badal),  e.  g.,  by  way  of  compensation, 
for  the  pay  of  soldiers,  or  the  price  of  horses  and  arms; 
and  these  claims  may  be  demanded  by  the  persons  entitled  to 
them,  irrespective  of  whether  or  not  there  are  funds  in  the 
treasury.  If  there  are  available  funds  the  claims  are  settled 
at  once.  But  if  there  are  no  funds  available,  the  creditors 
must  wait. 

The  Shafiites  *  have  answered  in  four  ways  the  question 
as  to  whether  a  person  may  himself  collect  from  the 
public  treasury  funds  which  came  into  his  hands  a  claim 
of  his  which  the  sultan  had  failed  to  settle.  In  one 
view  of  the  matter,  he  may  not  take  anything  for  his  claim 
because  the  funds  of  the  public  treasury  are  the  joint  prop- 
erty of  many  persons  and  he  does  not  know  what  his  share 
is.  A  second  view  is  that  he  takes  every  day  enough  for 

1  Miwardi,  p.  368. 
1  Mugni,  vol.  iii,  p.  88. 


THE  PUBLIC  TREASURY  437 

the  food  of  that  day.  A  third  view  is  that  he  takes  enough 
for  one  year.  A  fourth  view  is  that  he  takes  his  stipend, 
which  is  his  share.  This  last  view  is  in  accordance  with 
analogy,  because  the  treasury  funds  are  not  joint  property 
of  the  Moslems  in  the  sense  in  which  spoils  are  the  joint 
property  of  the  army,  or  the  estate  of  the  deceased  is  the 
joint  property  of  the  heirs,  for,  unlike  the  case  of  spoils  and 
estates,  should  the  person  in  question  die,  his  heirs  are  not 
entitled  to  his  stipend. 

According  to  the  Hanifites,1  if  a  person  who  has  a  claim 
on  the  public  treasury  happens  to  lay  hands  on  a  public 
fund,  he  may  keep  it  on  account  of  his  claim,  so  far  as  his 
religious  duties  are  concerned,  but  the  imam-  may  prevent 
him  from  so  doing,  if  he  chooses. 

(b)  The  other  part  consists  of  the  liabilities  which  have 
been  incurred,  for  the  general  interest  or  by  way  of  assist- 
ance (irfaq),  for  no  consideration  of  value  whatever.  The 
settlement  of  these  liabilities  is  conditioned  upon  the  exist- 
ence of  funds  in  the  treasury.  Consequently,  when  there  are 
funds  in  the  treasury  these  liabilities  must  be  met,  and  in 
such  case  the  obligation  (fard)  of  the  Moslems  at  large  in 
this  respect  lapses.  If,  however,  there  are  no  available 
funds  in  the  treasury,  the  liability  of  the  treasury  is  ipso 
facto  canceled  but,  if  the  need  to  be  met  by  that  liability  was 
such  that  its  neglect  would  affect  the  entire  Moslem  com- 
munity, the  liability  becomes  a  fard  kifayah  obligation  upon 
all  the  Moslems,  and  ceases  to  be  so  only  after  a  sufficient 
number  of  them  have  met  the  liability.  For  example,  the 
holy  war  must  be  financed  by  the  treasury  so  long  as  there 
are  funds  in  it,  but  if  no  funds  are  available,  then  the  obli- 
gation of  the  treasury  ceases  to  exist  by  that  very  fact,  and 
the  financing  of  the  jihad  becomes  a  duty  of  the  Moslems 

1  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  269. 


438  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

at  large,  until  a  sufficient  number  of  them  have  volunteered 
to  finance  and  carry  out  the  holy  war.  If,  however,  the 
need  to  be  met  by  the  liability  is  one  whose  neglect  does  not 
result  to  the  injury  of  all  the  Moslems ;  such  as  the  bad  con- 
dition of  a  road  which  however  may  be  replaced  by  another 
road,  or  such  as  the  cutting-off  of  a  city's  water  supply  for 
which  however  another  water  supply  may  be  substituted; 
then  the  obligation  of  making  the  necessary  repairs  is  re- 
moved from  both  the  treasury  and  the  Moslem  community.1 

1  See  supra,  pp.  35O-353- 


CHAPTER  X 
EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  x 

The  various  beneficiaries  of  the  zakat  taxes  have  been 
determined  on  the  basis  of  the  following  Koran  verse  2  re- 
specting the  disbursement  of  sadaqah  3  in  general :  "  Verily 
the  sadaqahs  are  for  (/*)  the  poor,  the  indigent,  the  respec- 
tive public  agents,  the  mu'allafah  qulubuhum,  and  [are  dis- 
bursed] with  respect  to  (fi)  the  slaves  (riqab)  and  the 
debtors  and  with  respect  to  '  the  way  of  God  ',  and  the  way- 
farers." 

According  to  the  Jami',  the  beneficiaries  of  the  zakat  do 
not  have  the  right  to  demand  settlement  of  the  zakat,  nor 
may  they  themselves  take  the  zakat  without  the  zakat 

1  Mo/ma',  p.  179;  Hiddyah,  p.  200;  Bahr,  p.  258;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p. 
263;  /ami',  p.  334;  Durr,  p.  144;  Durar,  p.  123;  Mabstt,  part  iii,  pp.  8- 
15;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  302;  Mugni,  vol.  iii,  p.  99;  Mawardi,  p.  210; 
Umm,  pp.  60-80;  Wajls,  p.  292;  Kharashi,  p.  116;  Muwatta,  p.  115; 
Mudawwanah,  pp.  46,  55-61 ;  Zarqani,  p.  63. 

1  Chap.  9,  verse  60. 

8  The  Mohammedan  writers  consider  sakdt,  as  we  have  already  seen, 
as  a  special  case  of  sadaqah,  which  by  extension  applies  in  general  to 
any  disbursement  made  with  a  view  to  earning  religious  merit  (thawdb}. 
Inasmuch  as  the  Koranic  verse  relates  to  the  disbursement  of  sadaqahs, 
in  general,  the  disbursement  of  sakdt  is  treated  by  the  doctors  under 
the  heading  of  ma$rif  al-sadaqdt  (beneficiaries  of  the  sadaqahs*) ;  the 
principles  set  forth  in  this  chapter  apply,  therefore,  equally  well  to 
other  kinds  of  sadaqah  such  as  the  sadaqat  al-fifr,  or  the  kaffdrah,  and 
the  vows.  We  are,  however,  concerned  here  with  the  sakdt  only. 
(fdmi1,  p.  334.)  It  must  be  pointed  out  here  that  the  views  concerning 
disbursement  held  by  each  school  apply  only  to  the  revenue  considered 
sakdt  revenue  by  that  particular  school.  This  remark  holds  true  of 
the  other  revenues  as  well. 

439 


440  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

payer's  knowledge;  and  when  they  do  so,  they  may  legally 
be  forced  to  return  it,  although  the  zakat  payer,  as  between 
him  and  God,  is  advised  to  let  it  go,  provided,  however,  that 
he  does  not  happen  to  have  relations  who  need  the  zakat 
more.  The  beneficiaries  are  in  detail  as  follows : 

(i)  The  "poor"  (faqir)  are  those  who  do  not  own  a 
nisab  of  property,  or  who  own  a  nisab  of  unproductive 
property,  which  is  entirely  destined  for  the  satisfaction  of 
first  necessities,  or  of  debts.  Hence  if  a  student  of  law 
should  own  books  to  the  value  of  many  nisabs,  he  is  still 
poor  if  he  needs  those  books,  but  should  the  latter  be  owned 
by  an  ignorant  person,  he  is  barred  from  receiving  a  share 
out  of  the  zakat  proceeds.  What  is  true  of  books  is  also 
true  of  artisan's  tools.  If,  however,  a  student  of  law  has 
two  copies  of  the  same  book  or  two  houses  and  needs  only 
one  of  them,  the  extra  book  or  house  is  taken  into  account 
and  if  its  value  amounts  to  a  nisab ,  its  owner  is  considered 
rich.  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  holds  that  if  the  rental  of 
the  extra  house  is  used  for  the  food  of  himself  and  his 
family,  the  value  of  the  house  is  not  taken  into  account  in 
reckoning  the  nisab.1  According  to  the  Path,2  there  are 
three  different  kinds  of  nisab  which  must  be  distinguished 
from  one  another,  (i)  The  nisab  of  productive  property 
which  is  unencumbered  with  debts;  such  nisab  subjecting 
its  owner  to  the  obligation  of  zakat.  (2)  The  nisab  which 
is  not  productive  or  which  is  encumbered  with  debts.  Such 
nisab  does  not  subject  to  zakat ,  but  bars  from  participation 
in  the  proceeds  of  zakat  if  it  is  not  entirely  destined  for  the 
satisfaction  of  the  first  necessities.  Thus  a  person  owning 
several  articles  of  wearing  apparel  or  several  household  uten- 
sils or  a  horse,  is  barred  from  receiving  zakat  if  he  does  not 

1  Majmo',  p.  182. 

1  P.  202;  cf.  also  Majma',  p.  183,  1.  i. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


441 


need  to  use  all  the  articles  of  wearing  apparel  or  the  utensils, 
or  if  he  does  not  need  to  ride  the  horse ;  otherwise  he  is  poor, 
and  may  receive  a  share.  (3)  The  nisab  which  does  not 
bar  from  participation  in  the  zakat,  but  bars  from  begging. 
This  nisab  consists  in  the  possession  of  sufficient  food  for 
a  single  day  after  covering  one's  nakedness,  or  in  the  ability 
to  earn  one's  living  even  if  one  should  not  own  a  day's 
food;  or  as  some  say,  it  consists  in  the  ownership  of  fifty 
dirhams.  According  to  al-Mawardi,1  if  a  rich  person  goes 
begging  and  the  public  inspector  knows  that  he  is  rich,  he 
rebukes  him,  but  if  he  merely  infers  from  the  fact  that 
he  has  the  signs  of  wealth,  he  informs  him  that  begging  is 
not  allowed  to  the  rich,  but  does  not  rebuke  him,  for  he 
may  in  reality  be  poor.  Finally,  if  he  sees  an  able-bodied 
man  begging,  he  forces  him  to  work  and  learn  a  trade,  and 
if  he  insists  on  begging  he  is  punished.2 

In  computing  the  nisab  to  determine  whether  the  owner  is 
poor,  according  to  some  authorities  the  procedure  is  exactly 
the  same  as  that  to  determine  whether  the  property  should 
pay  zakat  \  for  example,  if  the  property  consists  of  sawaim 
animals,  the  nisab  is  considered  complete  if  the  number  of 
the  animals  amounts  to  the  minimum  number  which  pays 
zakat,  irrespective  of  whether  or  not  their  value  amounts 
to  two  hundred  dirhams.  However,  the  view  generally  ac- 
cepted is  that  the  nisab  is  considered  complete  if  its  value 
amounts  to  two  hundred  dirhams,  whether  or  not  it  is  com- 
plete when  computed  in  kind.  According  to  al-Marginani, 
if  a  person  has  five  camels  worth  less  than  two  hundred 
dirhams,  he  is  "  poor  "  and  is  given  zakat  but,  on  the  other 
hand,  he  pays  a  zakat  of  one  sheep  on  the  camels.  This 
view  is  based  on  a  hadith  in  which  the  Prophet  defined  the 

1  P.  416. 

1  Cf.  'Alantkiriyyah,  p.  263. 


442  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

rich  as  the  persons  owning  two  hundred  dirhams.1  Accord- 
ing to  the  'Alamktriyyah,2  it  is  allowed  to  give  the  poor  a 
share  from  zakat  even  if  they  are  in  good  health  and  are 
engaged  in  business  (muktasib).  In  the  Mi1  raj,  however, 
it  is  stated  that  although  the  zakat  may  be  given  to  such 
persons,  it  is  not  proper  for  them  to  receive  it,  because  it 
does  not  follow  that  because  the  zakat  may  be  disbursed  to 
a  person,  that  person  may  properly  receive  it;  just  as  it  is 
not  proper  for  a  rich  person  to  receive  the  zakat  although 
it  is  allowed  to  disburse  the  zakat  to  him  when  his  state  is 
not  known.  The  Majma' ?  however,  remarks  that  it  is 
allowed  to  the  persons  in  question  to  receive  zakat,  although, 
as  is  said  in  the  Bahr,  it  is  preferable  that  they  should  not 
do  so. 

The  Malikite  and  Shafiite  conceptions  of  the  poor  are 
more  flexible.  Thus,  according  to  Ibn  Rushd,4  Malik  says 
that  the  question  of  deciding  whether  a  person  is  poor  is 
left  to  the  judgment  of  the  imam.  According  to  Khalil,5 
however,  the  poor  are  the  persons  who  lack  sufficient  means 
(kifayah)  to  provide  for  necessities  for  one  year,  even  if 
they  possess  a  trade.  On  the  other  hand,  according  to  al- 
Shafi'i,6  one  is  rich  not  only  by  possessing  wealth,  but  also 
by  being  able-bodied  and  able  to  earn  a  living;  and  if  it  is 
said  that  one  may  become  sick,  it  is  replied  that  one  may  as 
easily  lose  his  wealth.  Consequently,  the  able-bodied  poor 
who  know  a  trade  are  not  given  any  assistance  unless  they 
need  it  in  order  to  make  a  living.  Al-Mawardi 7  says  that  a 

lMajma',  p.  182. 

J  P.  265,  1.  5.  3  P.  180. 

4  Ibn  Rushd,  B.,  p.  251. 

6  Kharashi,  p.  117. 

6  Umm,  p.  64.  i  *•  " 

7  P.  211 ;  cf.  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  302.  .$  *. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES      443 

person  may  be  given  assistance  from  zakat  so  long  as  he 
has  not  attained  the  lowest  stage  of  wealthiness  (gind) ; 
that  there  are  persons  who  can  make  a  living  by  turning 
over  a  capital  of  one  single  dinar,  while  others  are  unable 
to  subsist  on  a  capital  of  less  than  100  dirhanis.  Therefore 
the  latter  must  be  given  more  than  the  former.  Finally, 
there  are  able-bodied  and  strong  artisans  who  can  make  a 
living  without  any  capital,  and  these  are  not  given  assist- 
ance even  if  they  do  not  possess  a  single  dirham.  Accord- 
ing to  the  'Alamkiriyyah,  the  zakat  is  given  to  the  learned 
poor  in  preference  to  the  ignorant  poor. 

(2)  The  "  indigent  "  (miskln)  are  those  who  do  not  have 
anything,  and  who  need  to  resort  to  begging  in  order  to  make 
a  living  and  obtain  enough  clothing  to  conceal  their  naked- 
ness.    Al-ShaiVi,  and  according  to  one  report,  Abu  Hanl- 
fah  also,  define  the  words  "  poor  "  and  "  indigent "  in  just 
the  other  way,  and  on  the  contrary  Abu  Yusuf  holds  that  the 
terms  are  identical.     The  Malikite  view  agrees  with  the  pre- 
valent Hanifite  view  in  considering  the  "  indigent  "  as  the 
needier  of  the  two.     However,  according  to  the  Majma',1 
these  differences  of  definition  are  of  no  consequence  as  re- 
gards zakat. 

(3)  The  collectors  ('amilun)  are  the  persons  appointed 
by  the  imam  for  the  collection  of  the  zakat  taxes.  The  term 
collector  applies  to  the  'ashirs  and  the    sa'is  as  well  as  to 
other  collecting  agents.     According  to  the  Shafiites,2  the 
word  'amilun,  besides  applying  to  the  sa'is  who  collect  the 
taxes  of  cattle,  applies  also  to  the  scribes  (katib},  the  distrib- 
utors (qasim  or  qassam),  the  hashirs  who  bring  together 
the  property  owners  or  the  beneficiaries,  the  'arifs  who  in- 
form about  the  beneficiaries,  the  zakat  keepers  (hafiz),  and 

1  P.  180. 

'  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  303;  Wajis,  p.  292;  An§iri,  p.  395;  Mugni,  vol. 
iii,  p.  102. 


444  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  accountants  (hasib).  There  is  dispute  as  to  whether 
the  kayyals  who  measure  off  the  zakat  dues  should  come 
under  the  class  of  collectors  ('amilun)  and  be  paid  out  of  the 
zakat  taxes.  Judges  (qadi)  and  governors  (wali)  and  the 
imam,  however,  are  not  included  in  the  class  and  are  not  paid 
from  the  zakat  for  any  services  they  may  have  rendered  in 
the  collection  or  distribution  of  the  zakat ,  because  they  are 
appointed  to  look  after  the  interests  of  Moslems  at  large, 
and  are  paid  from  the  share  of  masalih  if  they  have  not 
offered  their  services  freely.  According  to  the  Malikites,1 
the  persons  who  collect  (fabi)  and  those  who  distribute 
(mufarriq  or  qasim),  as  well  as  the  scribes  and  hashirs,  are 
paid  from  the  zakat.  However,  the  shepherds  (rai), 
waterers  (saqi),  judges,  muftis  and  the  like  are  only  paid 
from  the  zakat  when,  for  some  reason,  they  were  not  paid 
from  the  fa'y  (bayt-al-mal)  revenue,  which  is  their  usual 
source  of  payment.  According  to  al-'Adawi,  it  is  probable 
that  the  shepherds  and  waterers  are  not  paid  from  the  zakat 
because  the  zakat  as  a  rule  is  disbursed  to  its  beneficiaries 
as  soon  as  it  is  collected. 

There  are  two  views  concerning  the  reward  of  the  col- 
lectors. The  more  generally  accepted  view  is  that  the  col- 
lector is  paid  from  the  zakat  which  he  has  collected  an 
amount  which  is  on  the  average  sufficient  for  himself  and 
his  helpers  for  the  time  of  their  outgoing  and  incoming, 
provided  that  the  reward  so  given  him  does  not  exceed  the 
half  of  the  zakat  collected,  because  a  half-and-half  division 
is  the  very  essence  of  justice; 2  according  to  the  Muhit,  how- 
ever, the  reward  may  be  as  high  as  three-fourths  of  the 
tithe  collected.3  The  other  view  is  that  the  collector  is 

1  Kharashi,  p.  120. 

*Majma',  p.  180;  ' Alamkiriyyah,  p.  264;  Hiddyah,  p.  204;  Durar,  p. 
p.  123. 
»/am*v,  p.  335. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


445 


given  the  price  of  his  labor,  whatever  that  price  may  be, 
and  this  view  is  shared  by  al-Quduri.1 

According  to  al-ShafVi,2  the  collectors  are  paid  at  the  cur- 
rent rate  of  wages  out  of  the  eighth  set  apart  as  the  col- 
lectors' share.  If  this  share  is  not  sufficient,  their  wages 
are  made  up  from  the  other  shares  if  there  is  a  surplus 
available,  otherwise  from  the  share  of  the  Prophet,  or  ac- 
cording to  al-Mawardi,  from  the  share  of  masalih,  set  apart 
from  the  fa'y  and  gammah  revenues. 

Finally,  according  to  the  Malikites,3  the  wages  of  the  col- 
lectors are  paid  out  of  the  sakat  proceeds  before  anything 
else,  even  if  they  should  absorb  the  entire  sakat  proceeds. 

The  collector  may  be  rich,  according  to  all  of  the  three 
schools,  because,  as  the  Hanifites  argue,  his  reward  is  not 
meant  to  be  alms,  but  the  price  of  his  services,  and  since 
the  collector  is  going  to  give  his  time  and  effort  for  the 
work  of  collection  he  is  entitled  to  compensation.  The  col- 
lector may  not,  however,  be  a  Hashimite,  according  to  all 
of  the  three  schools;  this  is  because  the  reward  given  to  the 
collector  is  itself,  in  a  way,  in  the  nature  of  sakat,  and  the 
Hashimites  are  not  entitled  to  receive  sakat',  nevertheless, 
al-Tahawi  holds  the  opposite  view.  If,  however,  reward 
comes  from  other  than  the  proceeds  of  sakat,  according  to 
the  Jami'  the  collector  may  then  be  a  Hashimite. 

If  a  person  pays  his  sakat  directly  to  the  imam,  the  col- 
lector has  no  share  in  it.  Similarly  if  the  sakat  is  lost  or 
destroyed  in  the  hands  of  the  collector,  the  latter  forfeits 
his  right  to  a  share.4  The  collector  may  take  his  share  in 
advance  before  it  is  yet  due,  although  it  is  preferable  that 
he  should  not  do  so. 

1  Jam?,  ibid. 

8  t/mm,  p.  64;  cf.  Mawardi,  p.  211 ;  Wajiz,  p.  295. 

3  Kharashi,  p.  120. 


*  'Alatnkiriyyah,  p.  264. 


446  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

(4)  The  "  mukatabs  "  are  the  mukatabs  of  others  than 
the  zakat  payer,  even  if  these  other  persons  are  rich;  pro- 
vided they  are  not  Hashimites.     This  is  according  to  the 
Hanifites,  who  hold  that  the  expression  fi  'l-riqab  occurring 
in  the  Koran  verse  cited  means  fi  fakk  al-riqab,  namely, 
that  the  slaves  are  aided  in  completing  the  price  of  manu- 
mission (badal  al-kitabah)  in  order  that  they  may  become 
free;  and  not,  as  Malik  claims,  H  'itq  al-riqab ,  namely,  that 
slaves  are  bought  and  set  free.     The  Hanifites  take  exception 
to  the  view  of  Malik  on  two  grounds  i1  (a)  The  obligation  of 
zakat  consists  in  transferring  ownership   (tamlik)   in  the 
thing  given  as  zakat  from  the  giver  to  the  receiver,  but  this 
does  not  happen  when  a  slave  is  bought  and  set  free  with 
the  intention  of  settling  the  zakat.     (b)  The  setting  free 
of  a  slave  establishes  for  the  liberator  the  relation  to  the 
slave  freed,  of  a  patron  to  a  client  (wala),  but  it  is  a  fun- 
damental principle  of  zakat  that  its  giving  must  not  redound 
in  any  benefit  for  the  giver.     Neither  of  these  objections, 
however,  holds  true  when  the  mukatab,  who  has  the  right 
to  trade  and  to  receive  and  give  money,  is  given,  from  the 
zakat  funds,  a  certain  sum  in  order  that  he  may  himself 
apply  it  towards  the  price  of  manumission.     According  to 
the  Mudawwanah?  Malik  holds  the  view  that  when  slaves 
are  bought  and  set  free,  the  rights  of  patron  accrue  to  the 
entire  Moslem  community. 

(5)  The  "debtors"   (garimun)   are  those  who  do  not 
own  a  nisab  over  and  above  their  debts  and  first  necessities ; 
thus,  it  is  agreed  by  all  that  a  person  possessing  a  single 
month's  food  worth  a  full  nisab,  over  and  above  his  debts, 
is  still  entitled  to  a  share.     Some  say  that  the  word  garimun 

1  Kasani,  p.  45;  Mabsut,  part  iii,  p.  9;   cf.  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  304; 
Kharashi,  p.  121. 

2  P.  59. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES     447 

occurring  in  the  verse  means  the  creditor  who  can  not  col- 
lect his  claims  from  his  debtors.1  According  to  the  Majnia', 
in  giving  assistance  from  the  zakat  the  debtors  are  to  be  pre- 
ferred to  the  poor. 

According  to  the  Malikites,2  debtors  are  paid  from  zak&t 
only  for  debts  for  which  a  debtor  may  be  put  in  prison, 
namely,  debts  to  fellow-men  (adami),  provided,  however, 
the  debtors  prove  their  good  faith  by  applying  towards  the 
settlement  of  their  debts  such  cash  as  they  may  have,  and 
by  applying  the  saving  they  can  effect  through  living  in 
more  modest  quarters ;  and,  furthermore,  provided  the  debts 
were  not  incurred  for  unlawful  ends  such  as  drinking  wine 
or  gambling. 

Finally,  according  to  the  Shafiites,8  the  word  garim 
(debtor)  here  means  not  only  persons  who,  incurring  debts 
for  lawful  personal  reasons,  are  aided  only  when  they 
cannot  settle  the  debts  by  their  own  means,  but  also  persons 
who  incurred  debts  in  the  public  interest,  by  becoming 
surety  (hamalah)  or  by  composing  feuds  and  differences 
(islah  dJwt  al-bayn).  These  latter  are  paid  from  the  zakal 
even  if  they  are  rich.  According  to  the  J&mi',  al-Zahidi 
considers  the  word  "  debtors  "  in  this  connection  to  mean 
those  who  incurred  debts  for  composing  feuds. 

(6)  "The  way  of  God"  (sabll  allah).  According  to 
Abu  Yusuf  and  a  report  from  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan, 
the  expression  "  the  way  of  God  "  means  persons  who  by 
reason  of  poverty  have  been  unable  to  join  the  army  of  the 
Moslems  for  the  purpose  of  holy  war.  This  is  the  view 
generally  accepted.  Such  persons  deserve  a  share  even 
when  they  can  engage  in  business,  because  if  they  were  re- 

1  Jdmf,  p.  336. 

1  Kharashi,  p.  122. 

8  Umm,  p.  61 ;  Wajls,  p.  293 ;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  304. 


448  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

fused  a  share  they  would  stay  away  from  the  war.  Accord- 
ing to  another  report  from  Muhammad,  the  expression 
means  pilgrims  who,  by  reason  of  poverty,  have  been  in- 
capacitated for  the  completion  of  their  pilgrimage.  The 
ground  for  the  view  held  in  the  second  report  is  that  a 
person  who  was  given  a  camel  from  this  share,  was  ordered 
by  the  Prophet  to  transport  the  pilgrims  on  his  camel.  The 
ground  of  the  first  view  is  that  although  the  expression  "  the 
way  of  God  "  may  apply  to  every  act  of  devotion,  when 
there  is  no  indication  in  the  context,  or  otherwise,  in  favor 
of  a  specific  act  of  devotion,  it  applies  to  the  persons  who 
fight  the  holy  war.1  According  to  the  J&rni',  some  say  that 
the  expression  means  the  poor  persons  who  committed  the 
Koran  to  memory;  still  others  say  that  it  means  the  poor 
students.  According  to  the  Path,  however,  whatever  the 
meaning  of  the  expression  may  be,  the  unanimous  opinion 
is  that  with  the  exception  of  collectors,  people  of  all  the 
classes  mentioned,  if  they  are  poor,  receive  a  share,  and 
the  pilgrims  as  well. 

According  to  the  Malikites,3  the  expression  here  means 
the  persons  who  engage  in  holy  war  (jihad),  even  if  they 
are  rich.  However,  according  to  the  prevalent  view,  also 
judges,  jurisconsults,  prayer-callers  (mu'adh-dhin),  and 
other  functionaries  whose  services  redound  to  the  benefit 
of  all  Moslems  are  paid  from  the  sakat,  provided  they  do 
not  draw  a  pension  (ratib)  from  the  public  treasury.  In 
one  Malikite  view  of  the  matter,  the  above  in  reality  come 
within  the  scope  of  the  expression  "  the  way  of  God  ",  for 
they  contribute  to  "  the  maintenance  of  Islam,  its  reputa- 
tion and  exaltation  (ta'zim)  and  to  the  easing  of  hearts  in 
that  respect ". 


1  Hiddyah,  p.  205 ;  Jdmi',  p.  337. 
'Kharashi,  p.  122. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  449 

However,  according  to  al-Shafi'i  and  his  followers,1  the 
expression  means  the  persons  who  do  not  draw  a  pen- 
sion from  the  fa'y  revenue,  and  yet  volunteer  to  join  the 
holy  war,  especially  such  of  them  as  come  from  the  district 
where  the  zakat  was  collected.2  Such  persons  are  given  a 
share  even  if  they  are  rich. 

(7)  The  wayfarers  (ibn  al-sabll)  are  the  strangers  cut 
off  from  their  property,  and,  by  extension,  all  persons  who 
have  been  cut  off   from  their  possessions,   even  if  they 
should  be  in  their  own  cities,  such  as  the  resident  (muqlm) 
who  has  property  away  from  his  home,  and  the  creditor, 
whose  debtor  admits  his  debt  but  cannot  settle  it  because 
he  is  in  financial  straits.    These  people  do  not  receive  more 
than  they  need,  and  it  is  preferable  that  they  should  borrow 
the  money  they  need,  if  they  can  do  so.     Like  the  poor 
person  who  becomes  rich,  the  wayfarer,  too,  is  not  obliged 
to  bestow  as  alms  the  money  that  is  left  in  his  possession 
from  the  zakat  when  he  recovers  his  property.3 

According  to  the  Shafiites,4  wayfarers  are  given  enough 
to  complete  their  journey,  even  if  they  have  not  as  yet 
started  on  it,  provided,  however,  that  the  journey  is  made 
for  a  lawful  end.  According  to  the  Malikites,5  wayfarers 
who  have  property  at  home  are  aided  only  in  case  they  fail 
to  obtain  a  loan. 

(8)  The  people  called  mu'allafah  qulubuhum,  literally, 
people  whose  hearts  have  been  conciliated.     These  people 
were  of  three  classes.     One  class  included  those  to  whom  the 

1  Umtn,  pp.  62,  73;  Minhaj,  vol.  ii,  p.  304;  Wajiz,  p.  294. 

1  According  to  the  Shafiites,  as  we  shall  later  see  more  in  detail,  the 
fact  of  being  a  stipendiary  of  the  diwdn  bars  from  participation  in  the 
sakdt,  no  matter  what  class  of  beneficiary  one  belongs  in. 

8  Path,  p.  205. 

4  Umm,  pp.  62,  73;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  305;  Wajls,  p.  294. 

6  Kharashi,  p.  123. 


450  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Prophet  used  to  give  from  the  proceeds  of  zakat  in  order 
to  draw  them  into  Islam.  Another  class  consisted  of  those 
who,  although  already  converted  to  Islam,  were  weak  in  their 
faith,  and  to  whom  the  Prophet  gave  a  share  from  the  zakat 
in  order  to  strengthen  them  in  the  Faith.  A  third  class 
were  those  to  whom  the  Prophet  gave  a  share  in  order  to 
deter  them  from  doing  harm.  These  people  were  leaders 
of  the  Quraysh  tribe,  and  other  Arab  chiefs.  When  the  Pro- 
phet died,  these  people  came  to  Abu  Bakr  and  asked  him  to 
renew  the  document  concerning  their  shares  in  the  zakat, 
and  he  granted  their  request.  Then  they  came  to  Omar  and 
informed  him  of  it,  whereupon  Omar  took  the  document 
from  their  hands  and  tore  it  up,  saying  that  the  Prophet  gave 
them  a  share  in  order  to  draw  them  into  Islam,  but  that 
meanwhile  God  had  made  His  religion  to  prosper  and  the 
only  alternative  that  remained  for  them  was  Islam  or  the 
sword.  Upon  this  they  returned  to  the  calif  Abu  Bakr  and 
told  him  of  what  Omar  had  done,  saying:  "  Is  it  you  who 
is  the  calif,  or  he?  "  Abu  Bakr  replied :  "  He,  if  God  will  ", 
and  so  Abu  Bakr  did  not  blame  Omar  for  what  he  had 
done;  when  the  other  Companions  learned  of  the  hap- 
penings, they  all  approved  of  them,  and  in  this  way  an  ijmcf 
was  reached  on  the  matter.  In  view  of  this  ijmtf,  and  be- 
cause Islam  now  is  strong  and  no  longer  needs  resort  to 
such  means  for  protection,  the  Hanifites  hold  that  this  share 
has  lapsed  since  the  Prophet's  death. 

According  to  al-Shafi'i  and  his  followers,1  it  is  not  al- 
lowable to  disburse  the  zakat  to  an  unbeliever  in  order  to 
draw  him  into  Islam.  It  is,  however,  permissible  to  disburse 
it  to  powerful  Moslems  if  it  is  expected  that  this  will  result 
in  others  of  their  tribe  becoming  Moslems.  The  zakat  may 

1  Umnt,  pp.  64,  73 ;  Wajiz,  p.  293 ;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  303 ;  cf.  Kasani, 
p.  45- 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  45  j 

ilso  be  disbursed  in  order  to  confirm  Moslems  in  their  faith, 
or  to  enlist  the  military  assistance  of  a  Moslem  people 
against  those  infidels  or  Moslems  who  refuse  (mani')  to 
pay  zakat,  who,  being  near  that  people,  can  be  best 
brought  to  submission  by  them.  Al-Mawardi l  says  that 
although  it  is  not  allowed  to  give  the  infidels  from  the  zakat 
in  order  to  draw  them  into  Islam,  it  is  lawful  to  give  them 
funds  for  that  purpose  from  the  fa'y,  from  the  share  of 
wasalih.  Malik  says  that  these  people  were  given  a  share 
only  when  Islam  was  still  weak,  and  that  in  his  own  time 
Islam  was  strong  and  did  not  stand  in  need  of  financial 
backing,  as  it  did  in  the  days  of  the  Prophet  when  the  Mos- 
lems were  few  and  their  enemies  many  and  strong.  Malik 
arrived  at  this  view  by  using  his  method  of  istislah*  Ac- 
cording to  later  Malikites,8  the  divine  prescription  concern- 
ing this  share  is  still  in  force  and  consequently  zakat  may 
be  disbursed  to  unbelievers  provided  it  is  known  that  this 
will  lead  to  their  embracing  Islam. 

The  controversy  on  this  subject  has  largely  turned  on  the 
question  whether  it  was  possible  to  abrogate  a  point  of  law 
established  by  the  Koran  and  continued  in  force  until  the 
death  of  the  Prophet  by  means  of  an  ijma'  after  his  death. 
Those  who  believed  in  the  abrogation  of  the  Koran  and  the 
sunnah  by  an  ijma'  after  the  Prophet's  death,  saw  no  diffi- 
culty in  the  matter.  But  those  who  believed  the  contrary, 
had  to  tax  their  resources  to  find  a  justification  for  it. 
Thus  some  say  that  it  is  not  a  case  of  abrogation  by  ijma'. 
but  one  of  lapse  of  a  value  on  account  of  the  termination 
of  its  cause.  One  Hanifite  doctor  expresses  the  view  that 
in  the  time  of  the  Prophet  the  share  was  given  in  order  to 

1  P.  212. 

*  Ibn  Rushd,  B.,  p.  251 ;  cf.  Mudawwanah,  p.  57. 

s  Kharashi,  p.  121. 


452  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

strengthen  Islam;  but  that  now  Islam  is  strong  and  the 
same  object  is  served  by  not  giving  any  share.  This  view 
is  approved  by  the  'limy ah.* 

According  to  the  Shafiites,2  if  a  person  claims  to  be  a 
beneficiary  of  zakat  on  the  ground  that  he  is  poor  or  in- 
digent, he  is  believed  and  in  case  of  suspicion  is  sworn 
to  the  truth  of  his  statements.  According  to  some  doctors, 
he  is  always  sworn.  If,  however,  it  is  known  that  he  had 
property  although  he  claims  that  it  was  destroyed,  he  has 
to  prove  it.  The  same  applies  if  he  claims  that  he  has  a 
family  to  take  care  of.  Again,  if  a  person  claims  a  share 
in  the  zakat  on  the  ground  that  he  is  a  wayfarer  or  a  sol- 
dier he  is  believed  without  oath;  he  is  also  believed  if  he 
claims  a  share  on  the  ground  of  being  weak  in  faith;  but 
if  he  claims  that  he  is  a  mukatab  or  a  debtor,  he  is  required 
to  produce  evidence  to  that  effect,  since  this  can  be  done  in 
these  two  cases.  If  the  fact  is  generally  known  (mustafid), 
or  if  the  creditor  confirms  the  claim  of  the  debtor,  it  is  as 
if  proved  by  evidence. 

According  to  the  Malikites,3  persons  claiming  to  be  poor 
or  indigent  are  believed  without  oath,  unless  there  is  reason 
for  suspecting  the  contrary,  in  which  case  they  are  required 
to  produce  evidence.  If  a  person  claims  an  additional  share 
on  the  ground  of  having  a  family,  he  is  believed  unless  he 
is  a  resident  of  the  place  where  the  zakat  is  being  disbursed, 
for  in  such  case  the  matter  is  inquired  into.  If  a  person 
is  known  to  have  been  well-to-do  he  is  required  to  show 
that  he  has  lost  his  wealth.  A  person,  however,  is  believed, 
if  he  claims  bad  business.  Debtors,  must  prove  their  inabil- 
ity to  pay,  with  respect  to  debts  incurred  for  other  than 

1  P.  201 ;  cf.  Path,  and  Kifdyah,  ibid. 
*  Wajlz,  p.  294 ;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  305. 
"Kharashi,  'Adawi,  p.  116. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


453 


food  only,  because  it  is  generally  hard  to  prove  the  amount 
of  food  consumed.  Al-'Adawi  wonders  if,  when  evidence 
must  be  produced,  one  witness  would  be  sufficient,  or 
whether,  as  in  the  case  of  civil  procedure,  there  should  al- 
ways be  at  least  two.  On  the  whole,  he  seems  to  favor  a 
more  lenient  attitude  than  would  be  warranted  in  strictly 
civil  matters. 

The  Hanifites  do  not  discuss  this  matter,  except  in  what 
they  say  concerning  the  disbursement  of  zakat  by  the 
owners  themselves;  in  which  case,  as  we  saw,  they  resort  to 
intuition.  As  regards  the  disbursement  of  zakat  by  the 
state  officials,  they  evidently  intend  that  the  general  prin- 
ciples respecting  the  verification  of  assertions  (da'wa)  shall 
be  applied. 

The  method  of  distribution  of  the  zakat  among  the  var- 
ious beneficiaries  has  been  a  matter  of  difference  of  opin- 
ion. The  Hanifites  l  claim  that  the  zakat  may  be  disbursed 
to  all  the  classes  together,  excepting  that  of  the  mu'allafah 
whose  claims  have  lapsed ;  or  to  any  one  of  them  exclusively, 
even  if  it  consists  in  one  single  person.  Al-Shafi'i,  on  the 
contrary,  expresses  the  view  that  the  zakat  may  not  be  dis- 
bursed to  one  or  few  classes  when  there  are  more  of  them 
present,  and  that  the  share  of  each  class  is  disbursed  prefer- 
ably among  all  its  present  members,  or  at  least  three  of 
them;  it  being  unlawful  to  disburse  to  fewer,  when  there  are 
three  beneficiaries  present;  otherwise  the  collector  or  the 
owner,  if  it  was  he  who  disbursed  the  zakat,  has  to  make 
good  to  the  third  beneficiary  his  share.2  According  to  the 
later  Shafiites,  if  the  zakat  proceeds  are  sufficient  for  all 
the  beneficiaries  of  a  class,  and  their  number  is  easily  de- 
terminable  (munhasir),  each  is  given  a  share,  otherwise 

1  Majma',  p.  181 ;  Jam?,  p.  337 ;  Hiddyah,  p.  205. 
*  Utnnt,  pp.  69,  76-7 ;  Mabsuf,  part  iii,  p.  10. 


454  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

only  three  are  given  a  share.  This  rule  does  not  apply  to 
the  collectors  who  may  be  fewer  than  three.1  Finally,  ac- 
cording to  Malik  and  his  followers,2  as  in  the  case  of  the 
Hanifites,  the  zakat  need  not  be  disbursed  to  all  the  classes 
or  all  the  individual  beneficiaries  present,  but  is  disbursed 
to  the  neediest  ones,  even  if  they  should  be  in  other  dis- 
tricts. 

Al-Shafi'i's  ground  is  that  the  Arabic  preposition  "  for  " 
(li)  occurring  in  the  verse  establishes  for  the  beneficiaries  a 
right  on  the  property  due  as  zdk&t,  and,  since  the  names  of 
the  various  classes  are  construed  in  the  plural,  there  may 
not  be  fewer  than  three  persons  in  each  class ;  three  being  the 
minimum  number  for  which  the  plural  is  used.  It  is  true 
that  the  words  "  poor  ",  "  indigent ",  etc.,  are  defined  with 
the  article  and  the  article  indicates  the  entire  genus,  but 
since  such  a  meaning  cannot  have  been  intended  here,  they 
are  construed  as  mere  plurals  and  the  articles  are  ignored. 
Al-Shafi'i,  in  support  of  his  construction,  invokes  also  the 
analogy  of  a  will,  for  it  is  admitted  on  both  sides  that  if  a 
person  wills  a  sum  of  money  to  a  number  of  classes  they 
are  all  entitled  to  a  share.3 

On  the  Hanifite  side,  al-Sarakhsi  invokes  the  precedent 
of  Omar,  and  with  respect  to  the  analogy  of  a  will,  remarks 
that  it  pertains  to  a  relation  of  man  to  man,  where  import- 
ance attaches  to  the  expression  (lafz)  and  not  the  meaning 
(ma'na)  because  human  orders  (awdmir  al-'ibad),  unlike 
divine  commandments,  may  lack  a  commendable  wisdom. 
The  Hidayah  says  that  the  preposition  "  for  "  (li)  merely 
indicates  who  the  beneficiaries  are,  but  it  does  not  establish 

1  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  308 ;  An§ari,  p.  402 ;  Wajiz,  p.  295 ;  Mawardi,  p. 
210;  al-Fatdwa  al-Kubra,  vol.  ii,  pp.  37-8. 

'  Mudaruwanah,  p.  55;  Ibn  Rushd,  B.,  p.  250;  Kharashi,  p.  124;  Dardlr, 
p.  126. 

1  Mabstit,  part  iii,  p.  10. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES 


455 


a  valid  title  (istihqaq)  to  the  sakat  in  their  favor,  since  the 
sakat  is  in  reality  only  a  right  of  God,  and  the  classes  men- 
tioned are  beneficiaries  merely  by  reason  of  their  poverty. 
Furthermore,  the  Path  x  observes  that  the  preposition  here 
only  means  that  the  different  classes  are  entitled  to  the  pro- 
ceeds of  sakat  as  a  whole,  not  that  necessarily  every  individ- 
ual sakat  must  be  distributed  among  all  the  individual  bene- 
ficiaries, an  operation  which  is,  besides,  impossible-  More- 
over, it  is  a  rule  of  Arabic  grammar,  that  when  two  plurals 
are  set  against  one  another,  as  in  the  phrase,  "  the  people 
mounted  the  animals  ",  distribution  is  meant,  namely,  that 
each  person  mounted  one  animal;  similarly  in  the  case  of 
sakat,  each  sakat  is  given  to  one  or  a  few  beneficiaries,  but 
not  to  all  the  beneficiaries.  The  Path  adds  that  this  con- 
struction holds  true  even  if  the  preposition  "for"  (li)  means 
what  al-Shafi'i  claims  it  to  mean,  that  is,  a  title  on  the  sakat 
in  favor  of  the  beneficiaries.  Sadr-al-shari'ah  remarks 
that  the  article  before  the  words  "  poor  ",  etc.,  here  may 
not  be  construed  to  mean  certain  definite  (al-'ahd)  poor, 
since  there  is  no  evidence  in  the  context  to  bear  this  out, 
neither  may  it  mean  the  entire  genus  of  poor,  since  this 
would  require  that  all  the  sakat  of  the  world  should  be 
given  to  all  the  poor  of  the  world.  Therefore,  as  is  other- 
wise stated  in  the  Bahr?  the  defined  plural  here  of  necessity 
and  by  way  of  metaphor  means  the  genus  at  large,  and  may 
apply  to  a  single  individual  of  the  genus,  just  as  an  oath 
not  to  buy  the  slaves  applies  to  a  single  slave,  and  renders 
him  a  perjurer  if  he  buys  a  single  slave.  The  author  of  the 
Fara'id,  however,  takes  exception  to  this  and  says  that  the 
article  before  the  plural  need  not  necessarily  mean  a  literal 
universality  (istigraq  haqlqj)  since  it  may  also  mean  a  cus- 
tomary ((nrfi)  universality,  as  for  example,  in  the  phrase, 

1  P.  206.  'P.  260. 


456  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

"  the  king  called  together  the  artists  " ;  where  simply  the 
artists  of  the  city  or  the  outlying  districts,  but  not  of  the 
entire  world,  are  meant.1 

The  Malikite  view  on  this  matter  is  to  the  same  effect  as 
the  Hanifite.2 

The  Shafiite  method  of  distribution  of  the  proceeds  of 
the  zakat  taxes,  as  summarized  by  al-Mawardi,4  is  briefly 
as  follows :  When  the  proceeds  have  been  divided  among 
the  eight  classes,  and  each  has  received  its  sufficiency,  they 
cease  to  be  beneficiaries  of  zakat,  and  may  no  longer  claim 
a  share.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  they  have  not  received  their 
sufficiencies,  the  balance  is  made  up  from  future  proceeds. 
If  the  shares  of  all  the  classes  are  more  than  sufficient  for 
their  needs,  the  surplus  is  disbursed  to  the  beneficiaries  of 
the  nearest  city.  If  the  share  of  some  classes  is  insufficient 
and  of  others  is  more  than  sufficient,  the  surplus  of  the 
latter  is  disbursed  to  make  up  the  shortage  of  the  former 
classes.  If  all  the  eight  classes  are  not  present,  then  the 
entire  zakat  is  distributed  among  those  present,  even  if  it 
be  one  single  class;  and  the  shares  of  the  absent  are  not 
carried  to  them,  except  in  the  case  of  the  share  of  "  the 
way  of  God  "  which  belongs  to  the  fighters  who  normally 
reside  away  from  their  homes  in  the  frontier  cities. 

According  to  the  Hanifites,  the  giving  of  zakat  must 
result  in  the  transfer  of  ownership  (tamllk)  in  the  thing 
given  as  zakat  from  the  giver  to  the  receiver.  This  is  con- 
sidered to  be  the  formal  cause  (rukn)  of  zakat,  in  other 
words,  the  zakat  is  not  supposed  to  have  been  given  if  this 
requirement  is  not  met.  The  reason  for  this  requirement 
is  that  the  preposition  "for"  (li)  which  occurs  in  the  Koran 

1  Majma',  p.  181. 
'Kharashi,  p.  116. 
1  P.  213. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  457 

verse  respecting  the  beneficiaries,  indicates  that  the  sakat, 
when  it  is  given,  becomes  the  property  of  the  person  to 
whom  it  was  given.  Consequently,  the  zakat  may  not  be 
appropriated  for  impersonal  purposes,  such  as  the  building 
of  mosques,  bridges,  repairing  of  roads,  draining  of  rivers, 
etc.1  Likewise,  the  zakat  is  not  disbursed  for  fitting  out  the 
dead  for  burial  or  for  paying  their  debts.  Neither  is  it  al- 
lowable to  give  the  zakat  to  the  insane  or  the  undiscerning 
minor  (gayr  murahiq),  unless  it  be  given  to  his  guardian, 
such  as  the  father;  but  it  may  be  given  to  the  minor  who 
has  reached  the  age  of  discernment.  For  the  same  reason, 
a  person  may  not  dispose  of  his  zakat  in  settlement  of  the 
price  of  a  slave  he  has  bought,  in  order  to  set  him  free. 
According  to  Abu  Yusuf,  he  may  feed  (ibahah)  the  people 
of  his  household,  intending  this  for  the  settlement  of  his 
zakat  debt,  but  according  to  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan  he 
may  not  do  so;  however,  the  accepted  view  is  that  of  Abu 
Yusuf. 

Malik  agrees  with  the  Hanifites  that  the  zakat  may  not 
be  disbursed  for  the  fitting  out  of  the  dead  for  burial  or  for 
the  building  of  mosques,  on  the  ground  that  zakat  is  not 
intended  for  the  dead  but  for  the  living,  such  as  the  poor.2 
What  is  true  of  mosques  is  also  true  of  the  construction  of 
bridges,  the  payment  of  the  salaries  of  judges  and  of  iniams, 
etc.,  that  is,  purposes  of  public  utility  (masalih),  because 
these  are  not  specified  in  the  Koran  verse  cited.  However, 
the  salaries  of  the  functionaries  mentioned  may  be  paid  from 
the  sakat  in  case  they  have  not  been  paid  from  the  public 
treasury.  We  already  saw  that  one  Malikite  view  brought 
such  persons  within  the  scope  of  the  expression  "  the  way 

1  There  is,  however,  a  way  of  getting  around  this  difficulty,  as  ex- 
plained in  the  section  on  cunning,  under  Collection. 
1  Mu daurwanah,  p.  59;  cf.  Kharashi,  pp.  120,  123. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

of  God  ".  According  to  the  Shafiites,  the  zakat  may  not 
be  disbursed  to  others  than  those  specified  in  the  verse. 

Similarly  for  want  of  complete  transfer  of  ownership 
(tamlik*),  it  is  not  allowed  to  give  the  zakat  in  a  way  that 
may  result  in  some  benefit  for  the  giver.  It  is  not  therefore 
lawful  to  give  the  zakat  to  one's  ancestors  and  descend- 
ants in  direct  line,  no  matter  how  far  up  or  down,  whether 
legitimate  or  not,  or  to  one's  wife,  even  if  she  is  divorced 
and  in  her  waiting  term  (mu'taddah) ;  and  further,  in  Abu 
Hani  fan's  opinion,  the  wife  may  not  give  it  to  her  hus- 
band. However,  Abu  Yusuf  and  Muhammad  allow  it  in 
the  last  contingency.  Neither  may  one  give  his  zakat  to 
his  slaves  (mukatab,  mudabbar,  or  umm  walad),  even  if 
they  should  have  been  partly  set  free.  According  to  Abu 
Yusuf  and  Muhammad,  however,  one  may  give  it  to  his 
slave  if  partly  set  free,  because,  in  their  opinion,  the  setting 
free  of  a  slave  does  not  admit  of  division,  and  a  slave  partly 
set  free  is  considered  entirely  free. 

It  is  not  lawful  to  give  the  zakat  to  the  dhimmis,  be- 
cause the  hadith :  "  Take  it  from  their  rich  and  give  it  to 
their  poor  ",  refers  only  to  the  poor  of  the  Moslems.1  Simi- 
larly it  is  not  given  to  the  renegade,  nor  is  it  proper  either 
that  it  should  be  given  to  those  of  the  innovators  (mubtadi') 
who  have  incurred  unbelief.  Zufar  expressed  the  opinion 
that  the  beneficiary  need  not  be  a  Moslem.  It  is,  however, 
permissible  to  give  to  the  dhimmis  other  than  zakat,  such  as 
vows,  kaffarah,  etc-,  although,  in  one  report,  Abu  Yusuf, 
would  not  allow  this.  The  harbis,  however,  may  not  receive 
from  any  one  of  the  various  kinds  of  sadaqahs. 

According  to  the  Shafiites  and  the  Malikites,2  zakat  funds 

1  This  is  a  case  of  supplementing  the  Koran  on  the  basis  of  a  report 
of  the  ntashhiir  type. 

*  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  305;  Wajiz,  p.  294;  Kharashi,  p.  117. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  459 

may  not  be  given  to  unbelievers.  The  Malikites,  however, 
make  an  exception  as  regards  the  class  of  mu'allafah  and 
the  spies. 

Likewise  it  is  not  allowed  to  disburse  the  zakat  to  the 
rich,  because  it  can  clearly  be  seen  from  the  respective  verse 
that,  excepting  the  collectors  and  the  mu'allafah,  the  cause 
for  the  above-named  classes  being  beneficiaries  is  their  pov- 
erty, and  because  there  are  hadiths  from  the  Prophet  to  this 
effect.1 

According  to  the  Bada'i' ,  in  some  fatwa  collections  the 
opinion  has  been  expressed  that  students  of  law  such  as 
the  judges  and  the  muftis,  may  receive  the  zakat  even  if 
they  are  rich,  provided  that  they  exert  themselves  in  ac- 
quiring and  transmitting  knowledge,  since  by  so  doing  they 
become  unable  to  engage  in  business.  Ibn  'Abidin  says  that 
he  saw  a  similar  view  expressed  in  the  Jami'  al-Fatawa, 
where  it  is  said  that,  according  to  the  Mabsut,  it  is  not  al- 
lowed to  disburse  the  zakat  to  a  person  who  owns  a  nisab 
excepting  to  the  students,  the  fighters  (gazi),  and  the  per- 
sons cut  off  (munqati')  from  their  resources,  because  the 
Prophet  said :  "  It  is  allowed  to  disburse  the  zakat  to  the 
student  of  law  (film),  even  if  he  possesses  sufficient  sub- 
sistence for  forty  years."  a 

According  to  the  Shafiites,  the  fighters  (gazi) ,  the  mu'al- 
lafah, the  collectors,  and  the  debtors  who  have  incurred 
debts  for  public  purposes  are  not  barred  from  participation 
in  the  zakat  for  being  rich.  However,  no  beneficiary  of  any 
class  is  given  zakat  if  he  is  also  a  stipendiary  of  the  diwan.* 
According  to  the  Malikites,  finally,  the  mu'allafah,  the  col- 
lectors, and  the  fighters  are  not  barred  from  zakat  for  being 
rich. 

1  Path,  p.  209. 

*  Minhah,  p.  260;  cf.  'Adawi,  p.  120. 

8  Wajiz,  p.  292. 


45o  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Likewise  it  is  not  allowed  to  give  zakat  to  the  slave 
('abd)  of  a  rich  person,  even  if  he  is  of  the  mudabbar  or 
umm  walad  type,  because  the  property  of  the  slave  belongs 
to  the  master.  According  to  Abu  Hanifah  it  is  also  lawful 
to  give  the  zakat  to  the  slave,  if  he  is  indebted  for  all  his 
possessions  and  his  own  value.  Abu  Hanifah's  two  dis- 
ciples hold  the  contrary  view.  The  zakat,  however,  may 
be  given  to  the  mukatab  and  the  slave  who  was  permitted 
to  trade  (ma'dhun). 

Neither  is  the  zakat  given  to  the  infants  of  a  rich  person. 
However,  according  to  a  Zahir-al-riwayah  report,  the  zakat 
may  be  given  to  his  adult  children  and  wife  if  they  are 
poor,  even  though  the  children's  subsistence  comes  from 
the  father,  because  it  is  not  customary  to  consider  the  child 
rich  merely  because  the  father  is  rich.  Likewise  it  is  lawful 
to  give  the  zakat  to  the  father  of  a  rich  person  or  the  chil- 
dren of  a  rich  woman.4 

According  to  both  the  Shafiites  and  the  Malikites,1  per- 
sons, like  the  wife  or  children,  whose  support  legally  is  upon 
others,  may  not  be  given  zakat. 

Likewise  it  is  not  allowed  to  give  the  zakat  to  certain 
members  of  the  Hashim  family,  namely,  those  who  helped 
the  Prophet  in  spreading  Islam,  Hashim  being  the  grand- 
father of  the  Prophet.  This  is  based  on  many  hadlths  of 
which  the  following  one  was  uttered  by  the  Prophet  when 
he  refused  to  accept  the  sadaqah  offered  him.  It  is  as  fol- 
lows :  "  Verily  the  sadaqah  does  not  become  the  family  of 
Mohammed,  because  it  is  the  slops  (literally,  washwater) 
of  the  people."  2  Another  hadlth  is  the  following:  a  "  Oh, 
people  of  Hashim,  God  has  not  deemed  fit  for  you  the  wash- 

1  Durr,  p.  145. 

1  Minhdj,  p.  303 ;  Wajiz,  p.  292 ;  Kharashi,  p.  125. 

8  Path,  p.  212.  *  Kasani,  p.  49. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES      461 

water  of  the  people,  but  has  given  you  as  compensation  for 
it  one-fifth  of  the  fifth  of  the  spoils."  However,  they  may 
be  given  the  fwtf;  namely,  what  is  given  over  and  above  the 
amount  prescribed  as  zakat — or  some  other  ivajib  obligation, 
such  as  the  sadaqah  al-fitr.  In  other  words,  if  one  should 
give  them  property  intending  it  for  the  zakat,  the  property 
given  is  considered  as  a  supererogatory  offering,  and  hence 
the  zakat  debt  is  not  discharged.  According  to  the  Majma  , 
Abu  Hanifah  allowed  the  disbursement  of  zakat  to  these 
people.  In  the  al-Athar,  however,  it  is  stated  that  Abu 
Hanifah  held  two  contradictory  views  on  the  matter,  but 
that  the  view  which  allows  the  disbursement  is  preferred, 
on  the  ground  that  the  prohibition  of  disbursement  was 
limited  to  the  Prophet's  time.  The  Hashimites,  in  one  ver- 
sion, may  pay  zakat  to  one  another.  The  clients  (mazvla) 
of  the  Hashimites  are  treated  like  themselves,  because  the 
Prophet  said:  "The  clients  of  a  prophet  are  like  them." 

In  paying  the  zakat  to  the  beneficiaries,  the  proper  thing 
is  to  pay  only  enough  to  relieve  them  from  the  necessity 
of  begging  on  that  day ;  according  to  the  Majma',  however, 
from  the  necessity  of  begging  absolutely  (mutlaqa),  because 
the  object  in  giving  the  zakat  is  to  remove  the  need  for  beg- 
ging. It  is  therefore  an  abominable  practice  to  give  a  poor 
person  two  hundred  dirhams  or  more,  unless  he  has  a  family, 
or  is  in  debt ;  in  the  latter  case  it  is  allowed  to  give  the  entire 
amount  of  the  debt  plus  an  amount  less  than  a  nisab ;  and 
in  the  former  case  more  than  one  nisab,  provided  the 
share  corresponding  to  each  member  of  the  family  falls 
short  of  a  nisab.  If  the  poor  is  given  a  full  nisab,  notwith- 
standing that  he  is  not  in  debt  or  has  not  a  family  to  sup- 
port, according  to  al-Sarakhsi,  the  zakat  debt  is  nevertheless 
discharged.  Zufar  says  that  it  is  not.  Finally,  according 

1  Cf.  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  305;  Wajiz,  p.  294;  Kharashi,  p.  120. 


462  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

to  Abu  Yusuf,  there  is  no  harm  in  giving  two  hundred,  but 
it  is  abominable  to  give  more  than  two  hundred  dirhams. 
Zufar's  argument  is  that  when  a  poor  person  is  given  two 
hundred  dirhams  he  comes  under  the  description  of  a  rich 
man  during  the  act  of  receiving  the  money  and  therefore 
the  zakat  is  not  discharged  in  that  it  has  been  paid  to  a  rich 
person.  Al-Sarakhsi  replies  that  the  state  of  wealthiness 
depends  on  ownership  but  the  ownership  of  the  money  given 
accrues  to  the  poor  person  only  after  he  has  received  it,  and 
consequently  he  is  poor  while  he  is  yet  receiving  the  money, 
and  therefore  the  zakat  debt  is  discharged.  However,  be- 
cause here  the  state  of  wealthiness  follows  upon  that  of 
poverty  so  very  closely,  it  is  an  abominable  practice  to  pay 
two  hundred  dirhams,  although  legally  the  zakctt  is  dis- 
charged, just  as  it  is  abominable  to  pray  on  a  clean  spot 
close  to  which  there  is  filth,  although  the  prayer  is  legally 
valid.  Abu  Yusuf's  ground  is  that  when  two  hundred 
dirhams  are  given  to  a  poor  person,  a  small  part  of  them 
is  already  applied  (mustahaqq)  to  his  needs;  as  the  part 
which  remains  available  is  less  than  two  hundred,  he,  there- 
fore, is  not  rich.1 

According  to  the  Minhaj?  the  poor  and  indigent  are 
never  given  more  than  a  year's  subsistence.  But,  according 
to  al-Shafi'i  and  the  majority  of  his  followers,  they  are 
given  enough  for  the  rest  of  their  probable  lives  and  the 
amount  given  is  applied  to  the  purchase  of  real  estate,  its 
income  to  be  used  by  the  poor. 

It  is  abominable  to  transfer  the  zakat  of  a  property 
after  the  lapse  of  a  year  to  another  town,  even  if  that  town 
is  the  home  of  the  zakat  payer,  since  in  the  settlement  of 
zakat  the  location  of  the  property,  and  not  the  residence  of 

1  Mabstit,  part  iii,  p.  13. 

J  Vol.  ii,  p.  306;  cf.  Kharashi,  p.  119. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  ZAKAT  TAXES  463 

the  zakat  payer,  is  taken  into  account.  However,  it  is  al- 
lowable to  transfer  it  if  the  poor  of  the  town  to  which  the 
sakat  was  transferred  are  godlier  or  more  useful  to  Islam 
in  that  they  are  abler  in  learning  and  teaching  the  sharfah, 
or  if  the  zakat  payer  has  transferred  the  zakat  to  his  rela- 
tions in  that  town,  or,  finally,  if  the  poor  of  the  second  town 
are  needier  than  those  of  the  original.  It  is  said  that  the 
best  way  to  settle  one's  zakat  is  to  pay  it  first  to  one's 
brothers  or  sisters,  then  to  their  children  and  children's 
children  forever,  then  to  one's  paternal  uncles,  then  to  their 
children  and  children's  children  forever,  then  to  maternal 
uncles,  then  to  other  relations  through  females  (dhawu  al- 
arham),  then  to  neighbors,  then  to  the  beneficiaries  of  one's 
own  district,  finally  to  those  of  one's  own  town.  Accord- 
ing to  al-Mawardi,1  if  the  property  owner  brings  his  rela- 
tions before  the  collector  so  that  he  may  disburse  his  zakat 
to  them,  the  collector  does  so,  if  his  zakat  has  not  already 
been  mixed  with  the  zakat  of  others.  If,  however,  it  has 
been  mixed  with  the  zakat  of  others,  then  the  relations 
are  not  entitled  to  it  more  than  others  but  the  collector 
nevertheless  gives  them  a  share  from  it,  because  to  a  part 
of  it  they  are  more  entitled  than  others.  Al-Mawardi 
says  that  the  transfer  of  zakat  to  another  town  is  not  al- 
lowed unless  there  are  no  beneficiaries  in  the  first  town.  If, 
however,  the  zakat  is  transferred  while  there  are  bene- 
ficiaries in  the  original  town,  then,  in  one  view,  the  debts 
of  the  zakat  payers  remain  undischarged,  but  in  the  other 
view,  which  is  advanced  by  Abu  Hanifah,  they  are  dis- 
charged.2 

Finally,  according  to  Malik  and  his  followers,*  the  zakat 

1  P.  214. 

2  Mawardi,  p.  213;  cf.  Untnt,  p.  67;  Wajlz,  p.  295;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p. 

1  '     /••£      C«J  /»•*/»      r\*\      ->-9c'_n 


—  9    rw    —  -\j  i    "/• 

300;  cf.  supra,  pp.  335-9. 
1  Mudawwanah,  p.  46;  Kharashi,  p.  126. 


464  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

is  distributed  among  the  beneficiaries  of  the  town  and  its 
outskirts  (qurb),1  i.  e.,  the  town  where  the  zakat  was  col- 
lected, unless  it  be  that  the  zakat  was  collected  from  gold 
and  silver  and  articles  of  trade.  In  such  case  the  zakat  is 
distributed  in  the  town  where  the  owner  is.  If  there  is  an 
available  surplus  it  may  be  transferred  to  another  town, 
preferably  a  near  one.  It  is  even  allowed  to  transfer  the 
greater  part  of  the  zakat  of  a  town  to  another  town  if  the 
people  of  the  latter  town  are  needier.  Malik  allows  a  per- 
son to  settle  the  zakat  of  property  located  in  Egypt  (Misr) 
to  the  poor  of  Medina.2 

1  The  word  qurb  (vicinity)  is  technically  defined  as  the  distance  from 
the  inhabited  part  of  a  town  within  which  one  may  not  shorten  (qasr) 
one's  prayer  on  the  ground  of  having  set  out  on  a  journey.  This  dis- 
tance is  known  as  masdfat  al-qasr.  The  inhabited  gardens  of  a  city 
are  included  within  this  distance  (Kharashi,  vol.  i,  p.  411;  'Adawi,  p. 
127). 

J  The  Hanifite  doctors  do  not  state  if  the  rules  of  this  chapter  apply 
in  their  entirety  to  all  disbursements  of  sakdt,  whether  made  by  the 
zakdt  payers  directly  to  the  beneficiaries  or  whether  made  by  the  state 
collector.  There  is  no  doubt  that  certain  of  those  rules  cannot  very 
well  apply  in  the  last  case,  for  instance,  the  rule  concerning  the  pro- 
hibition of  paying  the  sakdt  to  one's  father  or  son,  or  slave,  etc.  The 
wording  of  the  texts  often  suggests  whether  the  rule  is  meant  for  both 
cases  or  for  the  case  of  disbursement  by  the  sakdt  payer  himself. 
Thus  as  against  the  impersonal  "the  sakdt  is  not  disbursed  (la  tudfa"} 
for  building  mosques.  .  .  ."  there  is  also  used  the  personal  form : 
"  the  sakdt  payer  does  not  disburse  the  sakdt  to  his  ancestry."  Except- 
ing, however,  those  cases  where,  in  the  nature  of  things,  the  rule  must 
be  intended  for  the  case  of  disbursement  by  the  sakdt  payer  himself,  in 
general  the  rules  set  forth  in  this  chapter  apply  equally  well  to  both 
cases,  since  according  to  the  Mohammedan  law  the  public  collectors  act 
only  as  the  agents  (nd'ib)  of  the  zakdt  payers.  This  is  also  borne  out 
by  a  statement  in  the  ' Alamkiriyyah  (p.  268)  which  implies  that  the 
rules  in  question  apply  also  in  case  the  sakdt  is  disbursed  by  the  col- 
lector after  its  collection.  (Cf.  also  Kharashi,  p.  124,  1.  6.) 


CHAPTER  XI 
EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE 

SECTION   I 

The  Booty  Revenue  l 

THE  expenditure  of  the  booty  revenue2  is  based  on  this 
verse  of  the  Koran : 3  "  And  know  ye,  that  whatever  thing 
you  have  taken  as  booty,  a  fifth  part  of  it  belongeth  to  (/») 
God,  and  to  the  Prophet,  and  to  the  near  of  kin  (dhu  al- 
qurba),  and  to  the  orphans  and  to  the  indigent  (miskin), 
and  to  the  wayfarer." 

It  is  stated  in  the  Mabsilt,  that,  according  to  Ibn  'Abbas, 
during  the  life  of  the  Prophet  the  fifth  of  the  spoils  was 
divided  into  five  shares,  namely,  one  share  to  God  and  His 
Prophet,  one  to  the  relations  of  the  Prophet  (dhazvu  al- 
qiirba),  one  to  the  orphans,  one  to  the  indigent,  and  finally 

*As  the  four-fifths  of  the  booty  revenue  accruing  to  individual  mem- 
bers of  the  community, — such  as  the  soldiers  (in  the  case  of  spoils),  or 
the  person  who  extracted  the  mine,  or  found  the  treasure-trove, — has 
been  already  treated  in  the  respective  sections,  in  this  section  we  will 
consider  only  the  part,  namely,  the  one-fifth,  accruing  to  the  state. 
For  the  disposal  of  the  four-fifths,  see  supra,  pp.  409-413,  413-421. 
Maima',  p.  504;  Mabsut,  vol.  x,  p.  8;  Hiddyah,  vol.  v,  p.  243;  Wajis, 
pp.  288,  290;  Umm,  vol.  iv,  pp.  71,  77;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  pp.  293,  209; 
Mawardi,  p.  241;  Muzani,  vol.  iii,  p.  192;  cf.  Ibn  Rushd,  5.,  p.  315. 

2  Although,  following  the  usage  of  the  Hanifites,  reference  in  this 
section  will  be  to  the  expenditure  of  the  fifth  of  spoils  alone,  the  reader 
should  bear  in  mind  that  what  is  true  of  the  fifth  of  spoils  is  true  of 
the  fifth  of  booty  revenue  in  general. 

*  Chao.  8,  verse  42. 

465 


466  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

one  share  to  the  wayfarers.  Later,  after  the  Prophet's  death, 
the  calif  Abu  Bakr  divided  it  into  three  shares,  namely,  the 
parts  for  orphans,  the  indigent  and  the  wayfarers.  So  did 
the  califs  Omar,  'Uthman,  and  'Ali,  none  of  the  Companions 
objecting  to  this  practice.  Abu  'l-'Aliyah,  on  the  other 
hand,  said  that  besides  the  above-named  five  shares  there 
should  also  be  set  apart  a  share  for  God  to  be  spent  for  the 
Ka'bah,  if  the  division  of  the  spoils  happens  near  it,  or  for 
the  mosque  of  a  town  if  the  division  takes  place  near  it, 
because  these  places  are  connected  with  God.  Al-Sarakhsi 
objects  to  this  construction,  saying  that  the  expression  "  to 
God  "  occurring  in  the  verse  is  not  to  be  taken  in  its  literal 
sense,  since  it  is  merely  meant  to  be  an  act  of  devotion  to 
open  a  sentence  with  the  name  of  God. 

As  regards  the  share  of  the  Prophet,  according  to  al- 
Sarakhsi,  it  lapsed  after  the  Prophet's  death.  Al-Shafi'i * 
thinks  that  this  share  after  the  death  of  the  Prophet  should 
go  to  the  imam,  inasmuch  as  the  Prophet  took  this  share 
in  his  lifetime  in  order  to  use  it  as  gifts  for  delegations 
and  deputations.2  Indeed  the  Prophet  said :  "  It  is  not 
allowed  for  me  to  take  a  share  from  your  spoils  except  the 
fifth  which  is  again  returned  to  you."  The  imam  in  this 
respect  is  exactly  like  the  Prophet,  and  therefore  he  must 
take  this  share.  The  Hanifites  reply  that  the  righteous 
califs  did  not  appropriate  this  share  for  themselves  and 
moreover  this  share  belonged  to  the  Prophet  by  virtue  of 
his  being  a  Prophet,  which  is  not  true  of  the  calif.  Then, 
too,  when  the  Companions  came  together  to  give  the  calif 

1  According  to  the  Malikites  (Kharashi,  p.  427;  Ibn  Rushd,  B.,  p.  315; 
Mudawwanah,  vol.  iii,  p.  26),  the  fifth  of  the  spoils  is  disbursed  like 
the  fa'y  revenue,  as  will  be  explained  in  the  next  section. 

2  It  is  stated  in  the  Unttn  (vol.  iv,  p.  72,  1.  i)  that  Al-Shafi'i  would 
prefer  to  have  this  share  disbursed  by  the  imam  for  the  strengthening 
of  Islam,  e.  g.  for  fortifications,  arms,  etc. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE        467 

Abu  Bakr  his  stipend,  they  did  not  give  it  from  this  share. 
Finally  there  is  no  reason  why  the  calif  should  take  the 
place  of  the  Prophet  as  regards  the  fifth  of  the  fifth  (i.  e., 
the  Prophet's  share)  when  it  is  a  fact  that  he  does  not,  as 
regards  the  safis,  namely,  choice  spoils  like  swords,  horses, 
slaves,  etc.,  which  the.  Prophet  chose  out  of  the  spoils  for 
his  own  special  use. 

Finally  as  regards  the  so-called  share  of  the  Relations, 
namely,  the  descendants  of  the  families  of  Hashim  and  al- 
Muttalib,  according  to  al-Sarakhsi,  this  share  has  been 
abolished  after  the  Prophet's  death.  Al-Shafi'i,  on  the  con- 
trary, says  that  the  relations  of  the  Prophet  are  gathered 
together  from  the  corners  of  the  earth  and  their  share  is 
divided  among  them.  Al-Karkhi  says  that  this  share  lapsed 
after  the  Prophet's  death  only  as  regards  the  rich  Relations. 
Al-Tahawi,  on  the  other  hand,  maintains  that  the  share  lapsed 
as  regards  both  the  rich  and  the  poor  Relations.  Abu  Bakr 
al-Razi,  finally,  holds  that  the  Relations  were  not  entitled  to 
this  share  by  virtue  of  their  relationship,  but  that  the 
Prophet  gave  them  this  share  in  consideration  of  the  assist- 
ance (nusrah)  they  rendered  him,  this  last  view  being  ap- 
proved by  al-Sarakhsi. 

Al-Shafi'i's  ground  is  that  the  preposition  "  to  "  (/»")  oc- 
curring in  the  verse  cited  establishes  ownership,  and  as  the 
word  "relation"  does  not  imply  any  economic  incompetency, 
the  poor  and  rich  are  treated  alike.  It  is,  however,  different 
with  the  orphans,  for  the  word  orphan  implies  poverty,  and 
therefore  only  the  poor  of  the  orphans  are  entitled  to  a 
share.  Moreover  it  is  a  fact  that  the  Prophet  gave  the 
Relations  a  share,  and  inasmuch  as  there  can  be  no  abroga- 
tion (naskh)  after  the  Prophet's  death,  the  share  stands 
valid.  Finally,  the  Hanifite  contention  that  the  lapse  of  the 
share  is  based  on  an  ijma'  of  the  Companions  is  not  true, 
because  there  is  a  hadith  from  Abu  Ja'far  Muhammad  Ibn 


468  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

'All  who  said :  "  The  opinion  of  'Ali  concerning  the  fifth 
was  like  that  of  his  family  but  he  disliked  to  oppose  Abu 
Bakr  and  Omar  ",  and  evidently  there  can  be  no  ijma' 
while  the  Family  of  the  Prophet  dissent. 

Al=Sarakhsi  replies  that  'AH  agreed  with  the  rest  simply 
because  he  saw  that  the  truth  was  on  their  side,  for  it  is 
known  that  he  opposed  them  on  many  occasions,  and  that  he 
would  have  done  so  in  this  case  also  if  the  right  had  been 
on  the  other  side,  because  'Ali  was  a  mujtahid  and  a  mujta- 
hid  is  not  allowed  to  abandon  his  own  opinion  in  favor  of 
another's  opinion  merely  because  he  is  ashamed  of  him. 
There  is,  besides,  an  unconfirmed  (shadhdh)  hadith  accord- 
ing to  which  the  Prophet  said  that  the  share  of  the  Rela- 
tions was  to  be  given  during  his  lifetime  only.  Finally,  there 
is  a  hadith  according  to  which  the  Prophet,  referring  to  the 
Relations,  said :  "  We  have  always  been  like  this  " ;  pointing 
out  his  fingers  which  were  knit  together.  This  hadith  shows 
that  the  Prophet  granted  them  a  share  because  of  the  assist- 
ance which  they  gave  him,  not  because  of  their  relationship, 
for  if  that  had  been  the  case,  the  Prophet  would  have 
given  a  share  to  his  other  relations  as  well,  and  not  to  the 
descendants  of  Hashim  and  Al-Muttalib  alone;  it  is  well  to 
remember  that  'Abd  Manaf ,  the  originator  of  the  family,  be- 
sides these  two  sons  had  two  more,  Nawfal  and  'Abd  Shams. 
Indeed  the  Prophet  himself  explained  the  matter,  saying 
that  he  gave  a  share  on  the  ground  of  assistance  in  the  way 
of  intimate  association,  not  in  the  way  of  fighting;  no  share 
was  given  to  'Uthman,  a  descendant  of  'Abd  Shams,  and  yet 
'Uthman  fought  for  the  Prophet.1 

To  sum  up  the  discussion,  according  to  the  accepted 
Hanifite  view,  the  booty  revenue  is  divided  into  three 
shares,  one  to  the  orphans,  one  to  the  indigent  and  one  to 

1  Mabsiit,  part  x,  pp.  9-14;  Umm,  vol.  iv,  pp.  72-77. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE        469 

the  wayfarers;  the  shares  of  the  Prophet  and  the  Relations 
having  lapsed  after  the  Prophet's  death.  The  Relations, 
however,  are  entitled  to  a  share  in  so  far  as  they  belong  in 
one  of  the  above  classes,  and  in  that  case  they  are  given 
precedence  over  the  rest.1 

On  the  other  hand,  the  Shafiite  view  is  that  the  fifth  is 
divided  into  five  shares,  namely,  the  Prophet's,  the  Rela- 
tions', the  orphans',  the  indigents',  and  the  wayfarers',  and 
that  the  Prophet's  share  after  his  death  is  disbursed  in  the 
general  interest  (inasalih)  of  Moslems;  for  instance,  for 
buying  the  provisions  of  the  army,  for  the  building  of  forts, 
bridges,  for  the  salaries  of  the  judges  and  wiams,  etc.  This 
share  is  referred  to  by  the  Shafiites  as  the  share  of  was??- 
lih.  The  share  of  the  Relations  is  divided  among  their  poor 
and  rich,  minors  and  adults  equally;  but  the  males  receive 
twice  as  much  as  the  females,2  because  they  are  entitled  to 
this  share  by  virtue  of  relationship,  with  respect  to  which 
God  said :  l  "  To  the  male  the  equal  of  the  share  of  two 
females  ".  The  clients  of  the  Relations,  and  the  children 
of  their  daughters  are  not  given  a  share.  The  orphans  re- 
ceive a  share  only  in  case  they  are  poor,  and  their  share  is 
discontinued  on  their  coming  of  age.  By  "  indigent  "  here 
are  meant  the  indigent  from  the  beneficiaries  of  the  fa'y 
(ahl  al-fa'y)  who  are  different  from  the  indigent  who  receive 
aid  from  the  zakat,  since  the  beneficiaries  of  the  two  revenues 
are  different.  This  is  also  true  of  the  wayfarers.3  This  last 
requirement,  namely,  that  by  indigent  and  wayfarers  here  is 
meant  those  from  the  fay  beneficiaries  is  because,  according 
to  the  Shafiites,  the  fifth  part  of  the  spoils  is  disbursed  in 

1  Majtiia',  p.  504;  'Alamklriyyah,  vol.  ii,  p.  304. 

2  The  passage  in  the  Mabsiit  (part  x,  p.  9)  to  the  contrary  effect  must 
be  a  mistake. 

8  Koran,  chap.  4,  verse  12. 
4  Mawardi,  pp.  218-9. 


470  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  same  way  as  the  fifth  part  of  the  fa'y  revenue,  which 
latter  may  not  be  disbursed  to  the  zakat  beneficiaries.1  The 
Hanifites,  however,  as  will  be  seen  in  the  next  section,  hold 
that  a  fifth  part  of  the  fa'y  revenue  is  not  set  apart  as  in 
the  case  of  spoils. 

According  to  the  Shafiites,  the  fifth  is  disbursed  equally 
among  all  the  five  classes  mentioned,  but  the  Hanifites,  as  in 
zakatj  here,  too,  hold  that  the  entire  fifth  may  be  disbursed 
to  one  single  class,  e.  g.,  the  orphans,  since  the  beneficiaries 
are  not  entitled  to  a  share,  but  may  simply  be  given  one. 
Moreover,  according  to  the  Shafiites,2  the  four  last  shares 
are  distributed  among  all  the  beneficiaries  of  the  entire 
Moslem  world  and  not  merely  among  such  of  them  as  are 
found  in  the  district  where  the  proceeds  were  obtained. 

SECTION  II 

The  Fa'y  Revenue* 

According  to  the  Hanifites,  a  fifth  part  of  the  fa'y  reve- 
nue is  not  set  apart,  as  in  the  spoils,  but  the  whole  of  the 
fa'y  revenue  is  disbursed  for  purposes  of  general  utility  to 
the  Moslem  community  (fi  masalih  al-muslimm)  ;  such  as 
the  stipends  of  the  soldiers,  the  fortification  of  cities,  the 
maintenance  of  stations  on  the  highways  for  protection 
from  robbers,  the  dredging  of  great  rivers,  the  building  of 
dikes,  the  stipends  of  the  learned  ('ulama'),  judges,  muftis, 
public  inspectors,  teachers,  students,  collectors,  governors 
and  their  assistants,  and  in  general  persons  who  exert  them- 
selves in  doing  some  work  for  the  Moslems  in  consideration 

lCf.  Mawardi,  p.  217;  Muzani,  vol.  iii,  p.  179;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  299. 

1  Umm,  p.  71 ;  cf.  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  294. 

8  Majma',  p.  520;  Hiddyah,  vol.  v,  p.  306;  Mabsut,  part  iii,  p.  17; 
Kasani,  vol.  vii,  p.  116;  Mawardi,  p.  218;  Umm,  vol.  iv,  p.  78;  Muzani, 
vol.  iii,  p.  199;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  293;  Wajlz,  p.  288;  Ibn  Rushd,  B.,  p. 
325;  Mudawwanah,  part  iii,  p.  26;  Kharashi,  p.  427. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE        47! 

of  a  reward.1  Some  say  that  only  the  offspring  of  the 
soldiers  receive  stipends,  but  the  opinion  generally  accepted 
by  the  Hanifites  is  that  the  offspring  of  all  the  classes  re- 
ceive stipends,  because  the  sustenance  of  the  offspring  is 
upon  the  fathers,  and  if  the  offspring  were  not  given  their 
sustenance  the  fathers  would  have  to  go  into  business  and 
Moslem  interests  would  suffer  from  it.2 

According  to  the  Shafiites,  as  in  the  case  of  the  spoils, 
one-fifth  of  the  fay  revenue  is  set  apart  to  be  spent  like  the 
fifth  of  the  spoils,  and  the  remaining  four-fifths  are,  in  the 
more  prevalent  view  of  the  matter,  disbursed  to  the  army 
alone,  and  in  another  view,  to  the  army  as  well  as  for  other 
purposes  of  general  utility  to  all  Moslems.3 

According  to  al-Muzani,4  al-Shafi'i  holds  that  the  four- 
fifths  of  the  fa'y  is  applied  to  the  payment  of  the  soldiers' 
stipends,  and  if  there  is  a  surplus  it  is  used  for  the  repair 
of  forts,  and  the  purchase  of  ammunition  and  arms,  and  in 
general,  for  the  strengthening  of  the  Moslems;  any  further 
surplus  is  divided  among  the  soldiers  according  to  their 
stipends.  Moreover,  the  stipends  of  officials,  such  as  judges 
and  religious  leaders,  employed  in  the  service  of  the  fa'y 
beneficiaries  are  paid  out  of  the  fa'y.  In  other  words,  ac- 
cording to  the  prevalent  Shafiite  view,  only  the  share  of  the 
masatih,  namely,  one-fifth  of  one-fifth  of  the  entire  fa'y  is 
spent  for  purposes  of  general  utility.5 

Finally,  according  to  Malik,6  the  entire  fa'y  revenue  and 


1  According  to  the  Hiddyah,  the  persons  who  received  stipends 
in  its  author's  days  were  the  judges,  the  teachers  (mudarris),  and  the 
muftis. 

J  \fobsut,  part  iii,  p.  18;  Ma/ma',  p.  520;  'Alamkiriyyah,  p.  268. 

1  Mawardi,  p.  219;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  294;  Wajlz,  p.  289. 

4  Vol.  iii,  p.  206. 

5  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  pp.  294-6  ;  Wajiz,  p.  289. 

•  Ibn  Rushd,  #.,  p.  325;  Mudawwonah,  part  iii,  p.  26;  Kharashi,  p.  427. 


472  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  fifth  of  spoils  are  a  part  of  the  assets  of  the  public 
treasury  and  belong  to  all  the  Moslems,  that  is,  they  are 
appropriated  by  the  imam,  according  to  his  judgment,  for 
the  stipends  of  soldiers,  the  building  of  forts  and  mosques, 
the  salaries  of  judges,  the  settlement  of  debts,  the  marrying 
of  bachelors  (afzab),  the  blood  money  of  wounds,  and  other 
purposes  of  public  utility.  If  the  revenue  is  ample,  the  Re- 
lations (of  the  Prophet)  are  paid  first,  then  the  remainder 
of  the  revenue  of  each  city  is  disbursed  to  the  fa'y  bene- 
ficiaries of  that  city,  or,  to  use  the  wording  of  the  Mudaw- 
wanah,  "  to  those  who  conquered  the  city  by  assault  or  by 
treaty  ".  The  poor  among  these  latter  are  first  provided, 
the  amount  given  to  each  being  sufficient  for  a  year's  sub- 
sistence. If,  on  the  contrary,  the  revenue  is  not  sufficient  for 
all,  the  neediest  are  paid  first.  It  is  lawful  to  transfer  the 
greater  part  of  the  fa'y  revenue  of  one  city  to  another  if 
the  beneficiaries  of  the  latter  city  are  in  greater  need. 
When  there  is  a  surplus,  it  may  be  transferred  to  another 
district,  or  immobilized,  or  disposed  of  otherwise. 

Al-ShafiTs  reason  for  setting  apart  the  fifth  of  the  fa'y 
is  the  verse  of  the  Koran : *  "  What  God  has  returned 
(of a* a)  as  spoils  to  His  Apostle  from  the  people  of  the 
towns,  belongeth  to  (li)  God,  and  to  the  Apostle,  and 
to  the  Relations  (dhu  al-qurba),  and  to  the  orphans,  and  to 
the  indigent,  and  to  the  wayfarers  ".  Ibn  Rushd  says  that 
because  the  wording  of  this  verse  resembles  that  of  the 
verse  concerning  the  fifth  of  the  spoils,  al-Shafi'i  by  mis- 
take concluded  that  the  mode  of  division  there  mentioned 
applies  to  the  fifth  only,  and  that  consequently  a  fifth  part 
of  the  fa'y  also  must  be  set  apart.  The  division  referred 
to  in  this  verse,  however,  applies  to  the  whole  of  the  fa'y. 
The  same  Ibn  Rushd  2  remarks  that  some  followed  the  literal 

1  Chap.  59,  verse  7.  s  Ibn  Rushd,  B.,  pp.  315-6,  325. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE        473 

sense  of  the  verse  and  held  that  the  entire  fa'y  is  disbursed 
like  the  tilth  of  spoils;  but  that  the  other  side  took  the  speci- 
fications of  the  verse  to  be  merely  illustrative  (tanbih),  not 
limitative  (ta'dld). 

Al-Kasani '  says  that  although  there  are  two  reports 
from  Abu  Hanifah  on  the  matter,  the  more  reliable  of  the 
two  is  the  one  according  to  which  there  should  be  no  fifth 
set  apart  from  the  fa'y,  because  the  fifth  is  set  apart  only 
in  the  case  of  spoils  and  the  fa'y  is  not  spoil.  There  is  a 
hadith  from  Sufyan  Ibn  Sa'kl  to  the  effect  that  only  in  the 
case  of  spoils  a  fifth  is  set  apart  and  that  the  fa'y  is  for  all 
Moslems.2 

According  to  the  Shafiites  the  fa'y  revenue  is  disbursed 
to  the  beneficiaries  of  fa'y  (ahl  al-fay)  exclusively,  ex- 
actly as  the  sadaqah  revenue  is  disbursed  to  the  beneficiaries 
of  sadaqah  (ahl  al-sadaqah)  exclusively.  However,  ac- 
cording to  Abu  Hanifah,  either  may  be  disbursed  to  the 
beneficiaries  of  the  other.3  The  Malikites  *  on  this  point 
agree  with  the  Hanifites. 

The  beneficiaries,  or,  literally,  the  people,  of  sadaqah  were 
those  who  had  not  migrated,5  and  on  the  contrary,  the 

1  Vol.  vii,  p.  117. 

1  Yahya,  p.  5. 

During  the  lifetime  of  the  Prophet  the  whole  of  the  fa'y  belonged 
to  him,  and  he  defrayed  from  it  the  subsistence  of  his  family,  and  the 
rest  he  spent  in  the  interests  of  Moslems  in  general.  (Mawardi,  p. 
218;  Yahya,  p.  3;  Wajis,  p.  289.) 

8  Mawardi,  pp.  219-20. 

4  Kharashi,  p.  120. 

5  According  to  the  Mabsut   (part  x,  p.  6),  before  the  conquest  of 
Mecca  it  was  a  farg  obligation   upon   every   Moslem   to  migrate   to 
Medina  in  order  to  learn  Islam  and  join  the  Moslems  in  order  to  aid 
the   Prophet.     The  people  who   did  this   were   called   the  Emigrants 
(muhdjir).     "And  they  who  have  believed  but  have  not   fled    (/am 
iuhdjiru)  their  homes,  shall  have  no  rights  of  kindred  with  you  at  all" 
( Koran,  chap.  8,  verse  73.)     After  the  conquest  of  Mecca,  this  verse 


474  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

people  of  fay  were  the  emigrants  who  defended  the  Mos- 
lem territory  and  its  sacred  places,  and  who  fought  the 
enemy.  Formerly  the  name  of  muhajir  (emigrant)  used 
to  apply  only  to  those  who  had  left  their  homes  to  go  to 
Medina  in  the  quest  of  Islam,  but  after  the  conquest  of 
Mecca  this  distinction  disappeared,  and  the  name  came  to 
designate  the  people  of  fa'y  in  opposition  to  the  people  of 
sadaqah  who  were  called  a'rabi  (Bedouin).1 

There  is  a  hadith  to  the  effect  that  Moslem  Bedouins 
(a'rab  al-muslimm)  have  no  share  in  the  fay  and  the  spoils 
unless  they  fight  together  with  the  Moslems.  Therefore 
the  Bedouin  who  has  not  fought  with  the  Moslems  and  is 
not  poor,  or  is  engaged  in  trade  or  some  other  work,  has  no 
share  in  the  spoils  and  the  fa'y  until  he  falls  in  need;  in 
that  case  he  receives  a  share  with  the  needy  (ahl  al-hajah).1 

According  to  al-Shafi'i,2  the  Prophet  used  to  instruct  his 
armies  to  tell  the  persons  who  became  Moslems :  "  If  you 
migrate,  then  you  shall  have  what  the  Emigrants  have,  but 
if  you  remain  in  your  homes,  you  are  like  the  Bedouins  ". 

According  to  al-Mawardi,3  if  the  imam  desires  to  give 

was  abrogated  by  the  hadith:  "  There  is  no  migration  after  the  con- 
quest, but  only  holy  war  and  sincere  intention  (niyyah)!'  Again  the 
Prophet  said:  "The  emigrant  is  the  person  who  shuns  (hajara)  the 
evil  and  shuns  what  God  forbade."  According  to  Ibn  al-Athir  (under 
the  word  hajara)  there  were  two  kinds  of  migration.  The  first  migra- 
tion or  hijrah  for  which  God  promised  Paradise  was  the  migration  to 
Abyssinia  and  to  Medina.  After  the  conquest  of  Mecca,  the  second 
hijrah  (migration)  came  to  supplant  the  former.  This  second  hijrah 
consisted  in  the  Arabs  of  the  desert  (a'rdbi)  leaving  the  desert  and 
joining  the  Moslem  campaigns.  This  second  hijrah,  however,  did  not 
equal  in  meritoriousness  the  former.  If,  without  an  excuse  for  so 
doing,  a  person  returned  to  his  home  after  migrating,  he  was  consid- 
ered an  apostate.  The  word  muhajir  (emigrant)  came  to  be  used  as 
the  opposite  of  Bedouin  (a'rdbi)  (Ibn  al-Athir  under  'aruba}. 

1  Mawardi,  p.  220. 

2  Yahya,  p.  5 ;  cf.  Muzani,  vol.  iii,  p.  242. 

s  Umm,  vol.  iv,  p.  84.  4  P.  220. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE 


475 


presents  to  a  people  from  the  fay  revenue,  he  may  do  so 
if  it  will  result  to  the  benefit  of  the  Moslems  at  large.1  If, 
however,  the  present  of  the  imam,  being  in  his  personal  in- 
terests only,  does  not  redound  to  the  benefit  of  the  Moslems, 
then  it  must  be  paid  out  of  his  own  property.2 

It  is  allowed  to  the  imam  to  assign  from  the  fa'y  a  sti- 
pend ('ata)  to  his  male  children,  since  they  are  from  the 
beneficiaries  of  the  fa'y.  If  they  are  yet  minors  they  re- 
ceive the  stipend  given  to  the  offspring  of  the  pioneers 
(dhawu  al-sabiqah) ,  and  if  they  are  of  age,3  they  receive 

1  The  Prophet  gave  'Uyaynah,  on  the  day  of  the  battle  of  Hunayn, 
one   hundred    camels,   al-Aqra'   one   hundred,   and   to   al-'Abbas   fifty 
camels,  but  the  latter  was  displeased  at  the  paltriness  of  his  share,  and 
so  the  Prophet  ordered  that  they  give  him  more  until  he  was  silenced. 

2  It  is  related  that  a  Bedouin  came  to  the  calif  Omar  and  recited  a 
poem  asking  for  assistance.    Omar  was  touched  by  his  plea  and  wept 
until  his  tears  wetted  his  beard  and  he  ordered  his  coat  given  to  the 
Bedouin,  saying  that  he  had  nothing  else.    Al-Mawardi  adds  that  Omar 
made  his  present  out  of  his  own  property  and  not  that  of  the  Moslems, 
because  his  present  did  not  involve  any  benefit  for  the  Moslems  at 
large.     Such    Bedouins,   al-Mawardi   goes   on   to   say,   belong   in   the 
people  of  sadaqah,  but  Omar  did  not  make  the  present  out  of  the 
sadaqah  revenue,  either  because  in  his  poem  the  Bedouin  reproved  him, 
or  because  the  $adaqah  is  disbursed  to  the  neighbors  and  the  Bedouin 
was  not  one  of  them.    In  contrast  with  Omar,  the  calif  'Uthman  was 
reproved  by  the  people  for  not  taking  into  account  the  distinction  be- 
tween the  two  cases  and  charging  all  his  gifts  to  the  fa'y  revenue. 

*  It  is  related  of  'Abdallah.  son  of  Omar,  that  when  he  came  of  age 
he  presented  himself  before  his  father  and  said:  "Oh,  Father,  I  have 
just  come  of  age,  assign  me  then  (a  stipend)."  Omar  assigned  him 
2000  dirhams.  Then  came  to  him  a  son  of  the  Helpers  (an$dr,  t.  e. 
the  Medina  people  who  became  Moslems  and  otherwise  helped  the 
Prophet  when  he  came  to  their  city)  who  had  just  come  of  age,  and 
asked  for  a  stipend,  and  Omar  assigned  him  3000.  Thereupon  'Ab- 
dallah said :  "  You  assigned  me  2000,  and  you  assigned  him  3000,  and 
yet  his  father  has  not  fought  the  battles  you  have." — "  Yes,"  answered 
Omar,  "  but  I  saw  the  father  of  your  mother  fight  the  Prophet,  whereas 
I  saw  the  father  of  his  mother  fight  with  the  Prophet,  and  the  mother 
is  worth  more  than  1000." 


476  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  stipend  given  to  soldiers  (nmqatilah)  of  their  rank-1 
It  is  not,  however,  lawful  for  the  iniam  to  assign  his  female 
children  a  stipend  from  the  fa'y,  because  they  are  his  off- 
spring and  are  provided  for  in  the  stipend  of  their  father. 

As  regards  his  slaves,  as  well  as  the  slaves  of  others,  if 
they  are  not  soldiers,  their  subsistence  is  upon  their  masters.2 
If,  however,  they  are  soldiers,  opinion  varies,  as  will  be 
explained  in  the  next  section.  The  slaves  may  be  assigned 
a  stipend  after  they  have  been  set  free.  It  is  likewise  al- 
lowable to  assign  a  stipend  for  the  intendants  (naqlb)  of 
the  beneficiaries  of  ftfy,  but  not  to  the  officials  ('ummal), 
because  the  former  are  from  the  people  of  fa'y,  but  the 
officials  only  receive  a  wage  for  the  work  they  have  done.3 

According  to  the  Hanifites,2  if  a  beneficiary  of  the  fa'y 
dies  in  the  middle  of  the  year  he  foifeits  his  stipend 
(fata),  because  it  is  a  kind  of  gift  (silah)  on  the  part  of 
the  state  and  not  a  debt,  and  its  beneficiary  does  not  acquire 
a  title  to  it  until  after  he  has  received  it.  If,  however,  he 
dies  towards  the  end  of  the  year,  it  is  commendable  that 
his  stipend  should  be  given  to  his  relations.  Shams  al- 
A'immah,  on  the  contrary,  holds  that  nothing  is  given  to  his 
heirs  even  in  case  he  should  die  at  the  completion  of  the 
year,  since  the  stipend  is  a  gift,  and  therefore  is  not  com- 
plete before  its  receipt.  If  a  beneficiary  has  been  given  his 

1  The  rules  concerning  the  pensions  of  soldiers  are  explained  in  the 
next  section. 

2  But  cf.  Mudawwanah,  vol.  iii,  p.  28. 

*  The  naqibs,  and  the  'arifs,  who  were  just  below  the  naqibs  and  the 
lowest  officers  of  the  army,  were  appointed  from  among  the  people  of 
fa'y  and  served  as  intermediaries  between  the  state  and  the  soldiers, 
informing  the  dlwdn  administration  about  the  condition  of  the  sol- 
diers and  the  offspring  they  had  to  take  care  of.  (Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p. 
295;  Mawardi,  p.  352;  Ansari,  vol.  iii,  p.  89.)  According  to  the  Wajlz 
(p.  289),  there  was  appointed  an  'arlf  for  every  ten  soldiers. 

4  Path,  vol.  v,  p.  307. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE        477 

sufficiency  before  it  became  due,  and  if  later  he  is  dismissed, 
or  dies  before  the  end  of  the  year,  opinion  varies  as  to 
whether  the  stipend  should  be  returned.  Muhammad  Ibn 
al-Hasan  holds  that  it  is  preferable  that  it  should  be  re- 
turned. Abu  Hanlfah  and  Abu  Yusuf ,  on  the  other  hand, 
say  that  the  stipend,  being  a  kind  of  gift,  may  not  be  re- 
claimed after  the  death  of  the  person  who  received  the  gift. 

SECTION  III 

The  Military  Stipends  l 

The  diwan  2  of  the  army  concerns  the  registration  (ith- 
bat)  of  the  soldiers  and  their  stipend  ('ata').  A  person 
may  be  registered  in  the  diwan  of  the  army  upon  the  ful- 
filment of  three  conditions.  The  first  condition  consists 
in  the  possession  of  the  following  five  qualifications:  (i) 
The  person  must  be  adult,  for  the  child  belongs  in  the 
class  of  offspring  and  dependents  and  may  not  be  registeied 
in  the  diivan  of  the  army.  (2)  He  must  have  freedom  of 
status,  because  the  slave  is  included  in  his  master's  share. 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  351  et  seq.  The  rules  set  forth  in  this  section,  with 
respect  to  the  disbursement  to  the  soldiers  in  the  way  of  military  sti- 
pends of  four-fifths  of  the  fa'y  revenue,  are  according  to  the  Shafiites. 
The  Hanifites  and  the  Malikites  do  not  devote  to  this  matter  any 
special  attention,  probably  because  according  to  them  the  fa'y  revenue, 
or  at  least  a  part  of  it,  need  not  be  disbursed  exclusively  to  the 
soldiers,  as  the  Shafiites  require,  but  on  the  contrary  may  be  disbursed 
entirely  for  peaceful  purposes,  such  as  the  salaries  of  civil  function- 
aries. The  Shafiites,  as  we  already  saw,  allow  this  in  regard  to  the 
share  of  viasdlih,  that  is,  in  one-fifth  of  one-fifth  of  the  fa'y  revenue 
only.  Cf.  An§ari,  vol.  iii,  p.  89 ;  Mugni,  vol.  iii,  p.  90. 

1  Diwdn  means  a  register,  or  a  government  office  where  administra- 
tion is  carried  on.  Thus  dlwdn  al-jaysh  (diwdn  of  the  army)  means 
the  register  or  administrative  office  of  the  army,  and  dlwdn  al-$adaqdt 
(diwdn  of  the  sadaqahs)  means  the  registers  where  the  records  per- 
taining to  the  sadaqahs  are  entered,  or  the  office  where  the  registers 
are  kept  and  the  administrative  work  pertaining  to  the  sddaqahs  is 
carried  on.  (Mawardi,  p.  343.) 


478  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Abu  Hanifah,  following  the  precedent  of  the  calif  Abu 
Bakr,  allows  the  giving  of  soldiers'  stipends  to  slaves.  On 
the  contrary,  al-Shafi'i,  following  the  precedent  of  Omar, 
makes  freedom  a  requirement,  but  allows  for  the  slaves  in 
the  way  of  increased  stipends  for  their  masters.  (3)  He 
must  be  a  follower  of  Islam,  in  order  that  he  may  ward  off 
harm  from  the  Moslem  community  by  virtue  of  his  belief 
and  in  order  that  his  sincerity  and  judgment  may  be  de- 
pended upon.  Therefore,  a  dhimmi  may  not  be  registered 
along  with  Moslems,  and  the  name  of  a  Moslem  is  stricken 
from  the  register  if  he  becomes  a  renegade.  (4)  He  must 
be  free  from  personal  defects  (afat)  which  prevent  him  from 
participating  in  fighting.  Therefore  cripples,  the  blind,  and 
the  one-handed,  are  barred  from  registration.  The  dumb 
and  the  deaf,  however,  are  not  barred.  The  lame,  if  horse- 
men, are  not  barred;  otherwise  they  are.  (5)  He  must  be 
courageous  in  battle  and  conversant  with  the  art  of  war. 

When  the  applicant  is  possessed  of  all  of  these  five  quali- 
ties, his  registration  in  the  register  (diwan)  of  the  army 
depends  upon  the  fulfilment  of  two  more  conditions,  i.  e., 
the  offer  and  the  acceptance.  The  offer  (ija-b)  is  made  by 
the  applicant  if  he  is  not  engaged  in  any  employment;  on 
the  other  hand,  the  offer  is  accepted  by  the  authorities  (wall 
al-amr)  if  there  is  need  for  the  services  of  the  applicant,  or, 
to  quote  al-Ansari,1  "if  the  funds  are  ample."  If  the  ap- 
plicant is  well-known  and  of  high  standing,  it  is  not  proper 
that  he  should  be  described  and  characterized  in  the  regsiter, 
but  if  he  is  from  the  ordinary  people,  then  he  is  described 
and  signalized,  and  his  age,  stature,  color,  and  facial  fea- 
tures are  described  and  his  peculiarities  indicated,  in  order 
that  he  may  not  be  confused  with  others  bearing  the  same 

1  Vol.  iii,  p.  92.  This  seems  to  suggest  that  every  able-bodied  person 
who  had  no  other  occupation  was  enrolled  as  a  soldier  and  received  a 
stipend  from  the  dlwdn  of  the  army. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE        479 

name.  The  stipendiary  is  called  when  the  stipends  are  dis- 
tributed, and  is  attached  to  his  naqib  or  'a-rif  in  order  to 
receive  his  stipends  through  his  intermediary. 

After  the  title  to  registration  in  the  register  has  been 
settled,  the  next  question  to  solve  is  the  order  of  registra- 
tion. This  order  may  be  general  or  particular.  The  gen- 
eral order  is  the  order  in  which  the  tribes  (qdba'il)  and 
clans  (ajnds)  are  entered  in  the  register,  each  being  entered 
apart  from  the  other.  It  is  not  allowed  therefore  to  enter 
persons  belonging  to  different  groups  under  one  group, 
or  to  enter  persons  coming  under  a  particular  group  un- 
der different  groups.  This  is  in  order  that  the  call  of  the 
register  may  be  in  a  uniform  manner,  and  that  strife  and 
friction  may  cease.  The  order  of  registration  differs  ac- 
cording as  the  stipendiaries  are  Arabs  or  non-Arabs. 

If  they  are  Arabs,  their  tribes  and  clans  are  entered  in 
the  order  of  their  relation  to  the  Prophet,  as  was  done  by 
the  calif  Omar.  In  this  order  of  registration,  one  begins 
with  the  origin  of  the  lineage  (asl  al-nasab) ;  then  with  the 
successive  generations  in  the  male  line  (ma  yafra'u  'anhu). 
Thus  the  two  main  branches  of  the  Arabs,  are  the  'Adnan 
and  Qahtan  folk.  The  former  come  before  the  latter 
because  the  Prophet  was  from  among  them.  On  the  other 
hand,  among  the  'Adnan  folk  the  Mudar  folk  precede  the 
Rabi'ah  folk.  Again,  from  the  Mudar  folk,  the  Quraysh 
are  given  precedence  over  the  rest.  Again,  among  the  Qu- 
raysh the  Banu  Hashim  come  first.  The  Banu  Hashim 
then  constitute  the  pole  of  the  register;  after  them  come  in 
order  of  relation  to  the  Prophet  the  adjoining  families  until 
the  whole  of  the  'Adnan  folk  are  included.1 

1  But  cf.  Angari,  vol.  iii,  p.  go.  According  to  al-Mawardi,  the  Arabian 
society  is  grouped  on  the  basis  of  relationship  in  the  male  line  (nasab) 
and,  according  to  the  length  of  lineage  with  respect  to  its  first  founder, 
each  of  the  two  independent  main  branches  (shtfb)  of  'Adnan  and 


480  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

If,  however,  the  beneficiaries  are  not  Arabs,  and  are  not 

organized  on  the  tribal  (nasab)  basis,  then  they  are  united 
by  one  of  two  ties:  either  by  the  tie  of  race  (ajnas)  or  by 
that  of  home  (buldan).  The  Turks  and  Hindus  are  ex- 
amples of  the  former,  and  the  Daylams  (Kurds)  of  the 
second.  But  the  Turks  and  Hindus  are  further  distin- 
guished among  themselves  by  races,  and  the  Kurds  by  cities. 
These  races  and  cities  then  are  entered  in  the  register  in 
the  following  order  of  precedence.  First  are  entered  those 
who  became  Moslems  first.  Then,  as  in  the  case  of  the 
Arabs,  are  entered  the  nearest  relatives  of  the  ruler  (ivali 
al-amr) ,  then  those  who  obeyed  him  first. 

The  particular  order  is  the  order  in  which  the  individuals 
of  the  same  group  are  registered.  Here  the  order  of  prefer- 
ence is  according  to  priority  in  accepting  the  Islam.  If  this 
test  fails  the  preference  is  according  to  godliness  (din),  then 
age,  then  courage.  If  the  last  test  also  fails,  e.  g.,  if  all  are 
of  the  same  courage,  then  the  imam  may  draw  lots  as  be- 
tween them,  or  use  his  own  judgment. 

The  amount  of  the  stipend  should  be  sufficient  to  satisfy 
the  soldier's  needs,  in  order  that  he  may  refrain  from  engag- 
ing in  what  may  keep  him  from  protecting  the  Moslem  coun- 

Qahtan  is  divided,  as  it  were,  into  six  concentric  social  layers.  The 
sha'b  (branch)  then  includes  all  those  who  can  be  traced  to  the  same 
remotest  lineage.  Within  the  sha'b  are  distinguished  the  so-called 
qabilahs;  thus  the  'Adnan  folk  comprise  the  qabllahs  of  Mu^ar  and 
Rabl'ah.  Within  the  qabllah  are  distinguished  the  imdrahs,  such  as  the 
Quraysh  and  the  Kinanah ;  within  the  imdrah,  the  batns  like  the  Banu 
'Abd  Manaf ;  within  the  batn  are  the  fakh-dhs,  like  the  Banu  Hashim. 
Finally,  within  the  fakh-dh  are  the  fasilahs,  like  the  Banu  al-'Abbas, 
Banu  Abu  Talib.  Each  layer  contains  the  following  ones,  namely,  the 
sha'b  includes  the  qabllahs,  the  qabllah  the  imdrahs,  the  imdrah  the 
batns,  the  batn  the  fakh-dhs,  and  the  fakh-dh  the  fasilahs.  In  the 
course  of  time,  as  the  lineage  lengthens  the  various  layers  become 
raised  to  the  preceding  layer;  thus  the  qabllahs  become  sha'bs,  the 
imdrahs,  qabllahs,  etc.  (Cf.  Zaydan,  vol.  iii,  p.  34;  vol.  iv,  p.  n;  Ibn 
Khaldun,  pp.  108  et  seq.) 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE        481 

try.  This  sufficiency  is  measured  with  reference  to  three 
circumstances;  the  number  of  children  and  slaves  he  has  to 
provide  for ;  the  number  of  horses  and  retinue  he  stations ; 
thirdly,  the  place  where  he  lives  with  reference  to  the  high 
or  low  cost  of  living.  In  other  words,  the  soldier  is  as- 
signed an  amount  sufficient  to  provide  for  subsistence  and 
wearing  apparel  for  the  whole  year,  and  this  amount  be- 
comes his  stipend. 

The  condition  of  the  stipendiary  is  examined  every  year 
and  if  his  pressing  expenses  have  increased,  his  stipend  is 
increased,  and  vice  versa.  The  doctors  have  disagreed  as  to 
whether  it  is  permissible  to  increase  the  stipend  beyond  one's 
sufficiency.  Al-ShafVi  prevented  the  increase  of  the  stipend 
beyond  one's  sufficiency,  even  if  there  should  be  available 
funds,  because  the  funds  of  the  public  treasury  are  not  dis- 
bursed except  for  necessary  expenses.  Abu  Hani f ah  al- 
lowed such  increase  over  and  above  one's  sufficiency  when 
the  funds  are  abundant. 

The  time  of  payment  of  the  stipends  is  known,  and  the 
army  expects  to  be  paid  when  it  has  acquired  title  to  its 
pay.  This  time  is  fixed  according  to  the  time  in  which  the 
revenues  of  the  public  treasury  are  due.  If  the  revenue  is 
collected  once  a  year  the  stipends  are  paid  in  the  beginning 
of  the  year.  If  the  revenue  is  collected  twice  a  year  the 
payment  is  made  twice  a  year.  Finally,  if  it  is  collected 
once  a  month,  the  payment  is  made  at  the  beginning  of 
each  month.  This  is  because  as  soon  as  there  has  been  col- 
lected any  revenue  it  should  reach  its  destination  as  soon 
as  possible,  but  the  army  has  no  right  to  demand  payment, 
if  the  collection  has  been  delayed.  If  the  payment  of  the 
stipend  is  delayed  the  stipendiaries  may  legally  demand  their 
settlement  if  there  are  funds  in  the  treasury.  If,  on  the 
contrary,  the  treasury  is  involved  in  financial  difficulties 
owing  to  untoward  events  which  wiped  out  its  revenues  or 


482  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

delayed  their  collection,  they  then  become  creditors  of  the 
treasury  to  the  amount  of  their  stipends;  but  they  may  not 
legally  demand  (mutalabah)  their  stipends  from  the  Moslem 
ruler,  just  as  the  creditor  may  not  demand  from  his  debtor 
when  the  latter  is  in  straits. 

If  the  ruler  wants  to  dismiss  part  of  the  army  for  suffi- 
cient cause  he  may  do  so;  otherwise  this  is  not  lawful, 
because  the  army  of  the  Moslems  is  for  their  protec- 
tion. On  the  other  hand,  if  a  part  of  the  army  wants  to 
quit  the  army,  it  is  allowed  if  they  are  no  longer  needed; 
but  it  is  not  allowed  if  they  are  needed,  unless  they  have 
an  excuse.  If  the  soldiers  refuse  to  fight  when  they  are 
ordered  to  do  so,  notwithstanding  that  they  are  equal  in 
number  to  the  enemy,  they  forfeit  their  stipends ;  but  if  they 
are  weaker  than  the  enemy,  their  stipend  is  not  canceled. 
If  a  soldiers'  beast  is  destroyed  during  a  battle  the  loss  is 
made  good  to  him,  but  if  the  beast  dies  outside  of  the  battle 
he  is  not  compensated  for  it.  If  a  soldier's  weapons  are 
destroyed  in  battle,  he  is  only  repaid  for  them  if  no  allow- 
ance had  been  made  for  them  in  his  stipend.  Likewise, 
when  a  soldier  is  detached  for  a  campaign,  he  is  given  the 
traveling  expenses,  if  they  have  not  been  allowed  for  in  his 
stipend.  If  a  soldier  dies  or  is  killed  in  action  his  stipend 
is  turned  over  to  his  heirs, 

The  stipend  is  turned  over  to  the  heirs  if  the  stipendiary 
died  after  the  collection  of  the  fa'y  revenue,  even  if  it  should 
be  before  the  completion  of  the  year.  The  heirs,  however, 
do  not  receive  anything  if  the  stipendiary  dies  after  the 
completion  of  the  year  but  before  the  collection  of  the  fa'y 
revenue,  for  the  stipendiary  acquires  a  title  on  his  stipend 
only  by  the  revenue's  having  been  collected.1 

1  Wajlz,  p.  289;  Ansari,  vol.  iii,  p.  91;  Mugni,  vol.  iii,  p.  92;  for  de- 
tails on  the  stipendiaries  of  pious  foundations,  see  Mugni,  ibid. 


EXPENDITURE  OF  THE  SECULAR  REVENUE        483 

Concerning  the  continuation  of  the  subsistence  of  his 

offspring  out  of  his  stipend  from  the  dlwan  of  the  army,  the 
doctors  have  held  two  views.  One  view  is  that  upon  the 
death  of  the  rightful  titleholder  of  the  military  stipend,  the 
latter  is  canceled,  and  the  offspring  are  cared  for  from  the 
proceeds  of  the  zakat  taxes.  The  other  view  is  that  this 
subsistence  is  continued  to  them  from  the  stipends  of  the 
deceased  soldier  in  order  to  induce  people  to  enter  the  army 
and  to  inspire  them  with  courage.  According  to  al-Ansari,1 
the  subsistence  of  the  wives  and  children  of  the  stipendiary 
after  the  latter's  death  is  continued  until  his  wives  and 
daughters  are  married  and  until  his  sons  become  indepen- 
dent as  to  earning  their  living  by  becoming  registered  in 
the  diwan  as  soldiers,  or  by  other  means.  The  doctors  have 
likewise  disagreed  on  the  canceling  of  the  stipend  when 
the  stipendiary  becomes  a  cripple.  One  view  is  that  the 
stipend  is  canceled  because  it  was  given  in  consideration  of 
a  service  which  is  no  longer  performed.  The  other  view 
is  that  the  stipendiary  is  still  given  his  stipend  in  order  that 
this  may  serve  as  an  incentive  for  volunteering  for  the 
army  service. 

1  Vol.  iii,  p.  91 ;  cf.  Mugni,  vol.  iii,  p.  91. 


CHAPTER  XII 
TAX  GRANTS 

Al-Mawardi  discusses  tax  grants  under  the  general  topic 
of  grants  (iqtaf)  and  distinguishes  them  from  the  grant  of 
lands  in  that  the  latter  is  a  grant  of  ownership  in  the  land, 
whereas  he  holds  the  former  a  grant  of  the  usufruct  (iqttf 
al-istiglal)  .* 

The  grant  of  the  usufruct  (iqfaf  al-istiglal)  is  of  two 
kinds,  grant  of  the  tithe  and  grant  of  the  kharaj.2 

( i )  Grant  of  the  tithe.  This  is  not  lawful  because  the 
tithe  is  a  kind  of  zakat  in  favor  of  certain  persons  who  at 
the  time  of  appropriation  must  possess  certain  qualities, 
e.  g.,  poverty,  and  it  is  possible  that  the  grantee  may  not 
possess  the  qualities  required  from  the  beneficiaries  of  tithe 
when  he  becomes  entitled  to  it.  Moreover,  the  zakat  is  due 
upon  the  fulfilment  of  certain  conditions  and  sometimes  these 
conditions  may  be  wanting  and  then  the  zakat  is  not  due. 
If,  however,  the  conditions  are  present  and  the  zakat  is  due, 
and  furthermore  the  grantee  is  entitled  to  it  at  the  time  of 
payment  by  possessing  the  required  qualities,  such  as  pov- 
erty, it  is  virtually  a  case  of  an  assignment  (hawalah)  of 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  337-341.     This  chapter  is  entirely  according  to  the 
Shafiites. 

2  From  the  financial  standpoint,  a  grant  of  tithe  or  kharaj  meant  that 
the  state  instead  of  itself  collecting  the  tithe  or  khardj,  in  order  to 
defray  from  the  proceeds  the  stipends  of  the  state  employees  gave  the 
latter  a  grant  of  tithe  or  khardj,  that  is,  the  privilege  of  collecting  the 
tithe  or  khardj  directly  from  the  taxpayers  and  applying  the  proceeds 
to  the  settlement  of  their  stipends. 

484 


TAX  GRANTS  485 

the  tithe  against  the  person  who  is  to  pay  it  in  favor  of 
the  assignee.  Such  an  assignment  therefore  is  valid  and 
the  payment  of  the  tithe  to  the  assignee  is  allowed ;  never- 
theless, this  does  not  create  for  him  a  title  to  the  tithe  until 
he  has  actually  received  it,  for  the  zakat  ceases  to  be  the 
property  of  the  zakat  payer  only  after  he  has  paid  it. 
Therefore,  if  the  assignee  is  refused  the  tithe  he  cannot 
bring  an  action  against  the  tithe  payer  and  in  such  case  the 
tithe  collector  is  more  entitled  to  the  collection  of  the  tithe 
than  the  assignee. 

(2)  Grant  of  the  kharaj.    This  differs  according  as  the 
grantees  differ,  as  follows : 

(a)  The  grantee  is  a  beneficiary  of  the  sadaqah  reve- 
nue.    It  is  not  allowable  to  grant  kharaj  to  such,  because  the 
kharaj  is  a  part  of  the  /cry  revenue,  and  the  beneficiaries  of 
the  sadaqah  revenue  are  not  entitled  to  the  fa'y,  just  as  the 
converse  is  true.     Abu  Hanifah  allowed  this  because  he 
permitted  the  disbursement  of  the  fa'y  to  the  sadaqah  bene- 
ficiaries. 

(b)  The  grantee  is  one  of  the  beneficiaries  of  the  share 
of  masalih  who  are  not  assigned  stipends  from  the  public 
treasury.     Although  these  people  may  be  given  assistance 
from  the  kharaj  revenue,  they  may  not  nevertheless  be  as- 
signed a  regular  stipend,   for  they  are  the  least  entitled 
(nail)  to  the  fa'y  and  get  a  share  only  after  the  rightful 
claimants  of  the  fa'y  have  received  their  stipends ;  what  they 
get  therefore  comes  only  from  the  gifts  distributed  from 
the  share  of  masalih. 

,  When  these  people  are  given  a  share  from  the  kharaj,  it 
is  legally  a  case  of  assignment  (hawalah)  and  not  of  grant 
(iqta(),  and  hence  two  conditions  are  necessary  if  it  is  to 
be  allowed.  First,  the  amount  assigned  must  be  fixed  and 
the  justification  of  its  donation  already  present;  and  sec- 
ondly, the  kharaj  must  have  already  fallen  due,  otherwise 


486  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  assignment  is  not  valid.  These  two  conditions  differ- 
entiate the  assignment  from  the  grant. 

(c)  The  grantees  are  from  the  class  of  the  beneficiaries 
of  the  fa'y  who  are  stipendiaries  (murtaziqah)  of  the 
diivan,  in  other  words,  soldiers  (ahl  al-jaysh).  These  peo- 
ple are  the  fittest  (akhass)  of  all  to  be  grantees  of  the 
kharaj,  for  they  receive  stipends  to  which  they  are  entitled 
in  consideration  of  the  services  they  have  rendered  in  fight- 
ing the  enemies  of  Islam  and  in  defending  its  sacred  terri- 
tories. Since  a  grant  to  these  people  is  valid,  the  next  thing 
to  consider  is  the  nature  of  the  khardj  revenue  granted,  for 
it  may  be  of  two  kinds.  It  may  be  in  the  nature  of  a  poll- 
tax  (jizyah),  or  it  may  be  in  the  nature  of  a  rental  (ujrah). 
If  the  kharaj l  granted  is  the  jizyah,  inasmuch  as  the  jiz- 
yah is  not  levied  forever,  but  only  as  long  as  the  taxpayer 
is  persisting  in  his  unbelief,  it  is  not  lawful  to  grant  it  for 
a  term  longer  than  one  year,  because  the  grantee  is  not 
assured  of  its  collection  after  the  year.  When  a  grant  is 
made  for  one  year,  if  it  is  after  the  tax  has  fallen  due,  it 
is  valid,  but  if  it  is  made  during  the  year  before  the  tax 
has  yet  become  due,  then  there  are  two  ways  of  looking  at 
the  situation :  If  the  condition  of  lapse  of  a  year  in  respect 
to  the  jizyah  is  considered  to  have  been  meant  for  the  con- 
venience of  payment,  the  grant  is  valid ;  but  if  it  is  said  that 
the  lapse  of  a  year  is  necessary  in  order  for  the  tax  to  be- 
come due,  it  is  not  valid. 

If,  however,  the  kharaj  granted  is  the  rental  of  the 
ground,  which  is  due  permanently,  its  grant  for  a  term  of 
more  than  one  year  is  valid,  and  it  need  not  be  limited  to 
one  year.  In  fact,  the  grant  of  this  latter  kind  of  kharaj 
may  be  in  one  of  the  following  three  forms. 

1  The  word  khardj,  besides  the  land  tax,  its  more  common  meaning, 
may  also  mean  any  tribute.  In  this  latter  sense  in  which  it  is  here 
used  by  al-Mawardi,  khardj  applies  to  the  jizyah  as  well  as  to  the 
khardj  (land  tax)  proper. 


TAX  GRANTS  487 

(a)  It  may  be  granted  for  a  definite  number  of  years, 

e.  g.,  ten  years.  Such  a  grant  is  valid  if  the  stipend  (rizqt) 
of  the  grantee  is  known  to  the  grantor,  and,  furthermore, 
if  the  amount  of  the  kharaj  is  known  to  both  grantor  and 
grantee.  If,  however,  the  second  condition  is  not  present, 
opinion  differs  according  as  the  kharaj  is  proportional  or 
fixed.  The  jurists  who  have  allowed  the  levy  of  the  pro- 
portional (muqasaniah)  kharaj  have  justified  it  by  con- 
sidering it  to  be  a  case  of  granting  a  definite  amount  of 
kharaj.  The  jurists  who  have  opposed  the  levy  of  the  pro- 
portional kharaj  have  considered  it  to  be  a  case  of  granting 
an  unknown  quantity  of  kharaj.  If,  however,  the  kharaj 
is  of  the  fixed  (masahah)  kind,  then,  if  it  is  of  the  kind  that 
does  not  vary  with  the  kind  of  crop,  the  grant  is  valid,  since 
the  amount  of  the  kharaj  granted  is  known.  The  grant  is 
also  valid,  if  the  kharaj  is  of  the  kind  which  varies  with  the 
nature  of  the  crop,  but  the  stipend  of  the  grantee  is  equal 
to  the  amount  of  the  kharaj  which  would  be  yielded  by  the 
highest  of  the  various  possible  rates,  for  the  grantee  has 
virtually  consented  to  a  lesser  yield,  should  that  be  the 
case;  on  the  contrary,  the  grant  is  not  valid,  if  the  grantee's 
stipend  is  equal  to  the  yield  of  the  lowest  of  the  various 
possible  rates,  for  he  may  possibly  get  more  kharaj  than 
his  stipend  would  entitle  him  to. 

If  the  grantee  remains  alive  during  the  term  of  the  grant, 
it  continues.  If,  however,  he  should  die  before  its  expiry, 
the  grant  is  then  considered  canceled  for  the  rest  of  the  term, 
and  the  kharaj  right  reverts  to  the  treasury.  In  such  case, 
if  the  deceased  has  left  offspring  they,  receive  a  share  from 
the  share  of  offspring,  but  not  from  that  of  the  army;  and 
therefore  what  they  receive  is  of  the  nature  of  public  assist- 
ance (sabab).  not  of  grant.  A  third  contingency  is  that 
the  grantee  should  become  a  cripple  after  a  time.  Accord- 
ing to  those  who  hold  the  view  that  being  a  cripple  does  not 


488  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

deprive  one  of  his  stipend,  he  continues  to  enjoy  the  grant, 
but  according  to  the  opposite  group,  the  contrary  is  true. 

(b)  The  grant  is  to  be  valid  during  the  life  of  the 
grantee,  and  after  his  death  it  is  to  devolve  to  his  heirs.  Such 
a  grant  is  void,  because  it  amounts  to  the  alienation  of  the 
interests  of  the  treasury,  since  the  treasury's  right  to  col- 
lect taxes  in  this  way  becomes  an  inheritable  private  prop- 
erty.    Although  such  a  grant  is  legally  imperfect  (fasid), 
the  grantee  is  nevertheless  entitled  to  the  kharaj  he  has 
already  collected  and  the  taxpayers  are  absolved  from  their 
debts;   if   he  collects   more   than   his   stipend,   he   returns 
the  surplus  to  the  treasury  and,  on  the  other  hand,  if  he 
collects  less  than  his  stipend,  he  applies  to  the  treasury  for 
the  balance.     The  sultan  in  this  case  announces  the  void- 
ness  of  the  grant,  in  order  that  the  grantee  may  be  pre- 
vented from  collecting,  and  the  taxpayers  from  paying  to 
him,  the  kharaj',  should  they  do  so  they  would  have  to 
pay  the  kharaj  over  again. 

(c)  The  grant  is  made  for  the  life  of  the  grantee.   There 
are  two  views  as  to  this  case :  According  to  those  who  hold 
that  being  a  cripple  does  not  constitute  a  cause  for  the  dis- 
continuance of  the  stipend,  such  a  grant  is  valid,  but  ac- 
cording to  those  who  hold  the  opposite  view,  it  is  not  valid. 

When  a  grant  is  valid,  the  sultan  may  still  revoke  it  for 
the  coming  year,  and  in  that  case  the  stipendiary  applies 
for  his  stipend  to  the  dvwan  of  the  army.  The  sultan  may 
not  revoke  the  grant  for  the  current  year,  if  the  time  of  the 
stipend  has  come  before  the  kharaj  has  fallen  due,  because 
the  grantee  has  already  acquired  a  title  on  the  kharaj  of 
that  year,  considering  that  his  stipend  is  overdue;  but  if 
the  kharaj  has  fallen  due  before  his  stipend,  then  the  grant 
may  be  revoked,  because  the  anticipation  (ta'jil)  of  a  future 
debt,  i.  e.,  the  stipend,  although  lawful,  is  not  binding. 

As  regards  the  stipends  of  others  than  soldiers,  when 
these  are  given  a  grant  of  kharaj,  three  cases  are  possible: 


TAX  GRANTS  489 

(a)  They  are  persons  who,  like  the  public  functionaries 
('umm&l  al-masalih)  and  the  kharaj  collectors,  receive  sti- 
pends in  payment  for  temporary  services.    A  grant  in  con- 
sideration of  such  stipends  is  not  valid,  and  when  it  is  made 
it  legally  constitutes  an  assignment  and  assistance  (tasblb), 
which  is  valid  only  after  the  stipend  and  the  kharaj  have 
fallen  due. 

(b)  They  are  persons  who  receive  stipends  in  consider- 
ation of  permanent  services,  but  the  stipends  legally  con- 
stitute a  case  of  /a'd/a/r.1     They  are  the  persons  connected 
with  religious  and  pious  institutions   (al-nticinln   /?  a'mal 
al-birr),  such  as  the  mil' adh-dhins  (callers  to  prayer)  and 
the  imams,  who,  without  an  investiture  from  the  proper  au- 
thorities, might  have  offered  their  services  to  those  institu- 
tions voluntarily  and  without  payment  for  them  (yasihhu 
al-tataiwit-   biha),  but  who  actually  are  receiving  stipends. 
A  grant  of  kharaj  in  favor  of  such  persons  legally  is  not  a 
grant,  but  an  assignment. 

(c)  They  are  persons  who,  like  the  judges  and  the  dlwan 
registrars,    receive   stipends    for   permanent   services,   but 
whose  stipend  legally  is  a  wage  (ijarah)  and  who  can  law- 
fully exercise  jurisdiction  only  by  virtue  of   investiture 
(taqlid)  and  legal  authority  (wilayah).     In  consideration 
of  their  stipends  they  may  be  given  a  grant  of  kharaj  for 
one  year,  and,  according  to  one  view,  as  in  the  case  of  the 
army,  also  for  more  than  one  year;  but  according  to  an- 
other opinion  this  is  not  lawful,  because  they  may  be  dis- 
missed from  service  or  shifted  to  another  post. 

1  Ja'dlah,  according  to  the  Shafiites  (Tanbih,  p.  149;  Wajiz,  p.  240), 
is  the  promise  of  a  compensation  for  services  rendered.  The  title  to 
the  compensation  is  acquired  only  after  the  performance  of  the  work. 
Although  the  person  undertaking  the  work  is  free  to  cancel  the  agree- 
ment at  any  time,  the  person  who  promised  the  compensation  may  do 
so  only  before  the  performance  of  the  work. 


CHAPTER  XIII 
CONCERNING  PUBLIC  RECORDS 

SECTION  i 
The  Public  Registers  1 

THE  accounts  (a'mal)  of  taxes  (rusum}  and  dues  (hu- 
quq)  entered  (ithbat)  in  the  public  registers  are  subject  to 
the  following  rules:  The  jurisdiction  of  each  oily  is 
marked  out  so  that  there  is  no  overlapping,  and  moreover 
the  districts  (nahiyah)  of  each  city  are  entered  separately 
when  they  are  subject  to  exceptional  treatment;  this  is 
also  true  of  the  individual  estates  (day'ah)  of  a  district 
when  they  are  treated  in  an  exceptional  way,  but  if  all  the 
estates  are  subject  to  the  same  rules,  then  they  are  not 
treated  separately. 

The  way  in  which  the  city  has  been  conquered,  e.  g., 
whether  by  assault  or  peace,  is  also  recorded ;  and  further- 
more a  record  is  entered  of  the  status  which  was  given  to 
its  lands,  e.  g.,  whether  kharaj  or  tithe  lands,  and  whether 
or  not  the  different  districts  of  the  city  are  subject  to  the 
same  rules. 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  356-360. 

Al-Mawardi  distinguishes  between  ithbdt  and  raf.  Ithbdt  means  to 
enter  a  record  in  a  register ;  raf,  to  make  a  report  to  the  registrar  in 
order  to  have  it  recorded.  Ithbdt  al-rufu  would  then  mean  the  enter- 
ing of  such  reports.  Hal  means  a  statement  of  account.  The  French 
etat  renders  it  exactly.  Ikhrdj  means  to  prepare  such  a  statement  by 
reference  to  the  registers. 
490 


CONCERNING  PUBLIC  RECORDS  49! 

If  all  the  lands  within  the  district  are  tithe  lands,  it  is  not 
necessary  to  register  their  area,  since  the  tithe  is  fixed  ac- 
cording to  the  amount  of  the  produce.  When  there  is  a 
new  crop,  a  report  of  it  is  made  to  the  dlwan  so  that  a 
record  of  it  may  be  entered  in  the  register  of  the  tithes.  In 
the  report,  the  names  of  the  owners  of  the  lands  are  also 
mentioned,  because  the  tithe  is  an  obligation  charged  to  the 
owner,  and  not  to  the  land  property.  Moreover,  when  a 
crop  and  the  name  of  the  owner  are  reported  to  the  diwan, 
the  amount  of  the  crop  and  the  method  of  irrigation  used 
in  cultivating  it,  whether  running  water  or  artificial  irriga- 
tion, are  indicated  in  order  that  the  rate  of  the  tithe  to  be 
charged  may  be  determined. 

If,  however,  all  the  lands  of  the  city  are  kharaj  lands, 
the  areas  are  entered,  because  the  klwraj  is  fixed  ac- 
cording to  area.  If  the  kharaj  is  in  the  nature  of  a  rental, 
the  mention  of  the  name  of  the  landowner  is  not  necessary, 
because  his  conversion  to  Islam  does  not  make  any  dif- 
ference so  far  as  the  payment  of  the  kharaj  is  concerned. 
But  if  the  kharaj  is  in  the  nature  of  jizyah,  then  it  is  nec- 
essary to  enter  the  names  of  the  landowners,  and  their  re- 
ligous  affiliations,  since  the  payment  of  the  tax  in  this  case 
depends  on  the  religious  status  of  the  owner. 

If  part  of  the  lands  are  tithe  lands  and  part  kharaj  lands, 
the  former  are  entered  in  the  register  of  tithes,  and  the 
latter  in  the  register  of  the  kharaj,  and  each  part  is  treated 
in  accordance  with  the  respective  rules  of  its  class  as  above- 
mentioned. 

The  details  pertaining  to  the  kind  of  the  kharaj,  namely, 
whether  it  is  of  the  proportional  or  the  fixed  kind  of  kharaj, 
are  entered.  If  it  is  the  proportional  kharaj,  then  when  a 
statement  concerning  the  area  of  the  land  is  prepared 
(ukhrijat)  from  the  registers,  the  amount  of  the  rate,  like 
one-third  or  one-fourth  of  the  produce,  is  also  mentioned 


492  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

in  the  statement,  and  the  amount  of  the  produce  is  reported 
to  the  diwan  in  order  that  the  amount  of  the  tax  may  be 
figured  out  accordingly.  If  the  kharaj  is  paid  in  silver 
(i.  e.,  specie),  two  cases  are  possible.  The  kharaj  may 
vary  with  the  nature  of  the  crop,  or  it  may  not  vary.  If  it 
does  not  vary  with  the  crop,  then  the  area  of  the  land  is 
determined  (ukhrijat)  from  the  registers  in  order  that  the 
kharaj  may  be  collected  accordingly,  and  it  is  only  neces- 
sary in  this  case  to  report  to  the  dlwan-  the  amount 
collected.  But  if  the  kharaj  varies  with  the  kind  of  crop 
grown  on  the  land,  the  area  is  determined  from  the  registers, 
and  the  kinds  of  the  crops  are  reported  to  the  registrar  in 
order  that  the  kharaj  may  be  collected  accordingly. 

Furthermore,  the  dhiminis  of  each  city,  and  the  conditions 
under  which  they  have  been  admitted  into  the  status  of 
dhimmi  are  indicated.  If  the  amount  of  the  jizyah  is  to 
vary  according  to  the  financial  status  of  the  dhimmis  their 
names  as  well  as  their  number  are  also  recorded,  in  order 
that  their  financial  status  may  be  known;  otherwise  only 
their  number  is  mentioned.  Then  every  year  a  new  exami- 
nation is  made,  and  the  dhiminis  who  have  come  of  age  are 
recorded  in  the  register  and  those  who  have  died,  or  have 
become  Moslems,  are  stricken  out  from  it,  the  result  being 
that  only  the  dhimmis  who  are  liable  to  the  jizyah  are 
registered. 

If  there  are  mines  within  the  city  limits,  the  mines  and 
their  kinds  are  mentioned.  In  the  case  of  mines  the  tax  is 
fixed  according  to  what  has  been  extracted  from  them,  irre- 
spective of  the  area  of  the  land,  and  regardless  of  whether 
it  is  tithe  or  kharaj  land.  As  already  mentioned  in  the 
chapter  on  mines,  there  are  various  opinions  as  regards  the 
kinds  of  mines  which  must  pay  tax,  and  also  as  regards  the 
rate  of  the  tax.  If  one  of  these  points  has  been  left  unde- 
termined by  previous  rulers,  then  the  ruler  for  the  time 


CONCERNING  PUBLIC  RECORDS  493 

being  decides  the  kind  of  mine  that  is  to  pay  the  tax,  and 
the  rate  of  the  tax,  and  acts  according  to  his  opinion,  pro- 
vided he  is  a  mujtahid.  But  if  the  previous  imSms  have 
already  expressed  an  opinion  on  these  two  points  and  acted 
according  to  that  opinion,  then  the  ruler  for  the  time  being 
follows  their  opinion  only  as  regards  the  kinds  of  mines 
he  is  to  tax. 

If  frontier  cities  situated  on  the  border  of  the  enemy's 
land  (dar  al-harb)  have  treaties  with  the  Moslem  state 
whereby  their  goods  are  subject  to  a  tax  when  they  enter 
the  Moslem  territory,  these  treaties  are  recorded  in  the 
registers,  and 'the  amount  of  the  tax  rate,  whether  one- 
tenth,  or  one-fifth,  or  more  or  less,  is  indicated.  Further- 
more, if  the  rates  are  to  differ  with  the  nature  of  the  goods, 
that  fact  is  also  mentioned.  As  regards  the  taxes  levied  on 
goods  carried  within  Moslem  territory  from  one  place  to 
another,  the  levy  of  a  tax  on  such  goods  is  prohibited  by 
the  shartah  and  no  mujtahid  has  ever  allowed  such  a  policy. 
Besides,  it  is  only  in  accordance  with  a  policy  of  justice,  and 
the  dictates  of  humanity.  Such  taxes  are  rarely  levied, 
except  in  tyrannical  cities.  It  is  related  that  the  Prophet 
said:  "  The  worst  of  men  are  the  toll  collectors  ('ash-sha- 
nln)  who  destroy  ". 

When  the  governors  (wall)  change  the  laws  of  the 
cities  and  the  tax  rates,  the  change  is  lawful,  if  the  governors 
are  of  the  class  of  mujtahids  and  the  change  made  by  them 
is  one  that  is  approved  by  the  sharTaJi ;  and  the  tax  is 
collected  on  the  basis  of  it.  In  such  case,  when  a  statement 
of  the  account  is  prepared  from  the  registers,  it  is  allowable 
if  only  the  new  rate  is  taken  into  account,  although  it  is 
better  that  both  rates  should  be  mentioned,  because  it  is 
possible  that  the  reasons  which  justified  the  change  have 
meanwhile  ceased  to  exist;  in  such  case  the  tax  would 
have  to  be  paid  according  to  the  old  rate.  If,  however,  the 


494  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

change  is  not  approved  by  the  shari'ah,  and  the  governor 
who  instituted  the  change  is  not  a  mujtahid,  the  change 
is  null  and  void.  When  a  governor  wants  a  statement 
(hal)  of  a  tax  account,  the  statement  must  mention  also  the 
rate  previous  to  the  change,  unless  the  governor  is  already 
acquainted  with  it.  In  this  last  case  it  is  sufficient  to  indi- 
cate that  the  rate  used  is  the  new  rate. 

SECTION   II 

The  Duties  of  the  Public  Registrars  l 

The  registrars  of  the  diwan  are  charged  with  the  follow- 
ing six  duties:  the  recording  of  laws;  the  settlement  (istifa) 
of  the  accounts  of  taxes  and  dues ;  the  recording  of  reports 
(ithbat  al-rufu')  ;  the  audit  of  the  accounts  of  officials;  the 
preparation  of  statements  of  accounts  (ikhraj  al-ahwal) ; 
and  the  hearing  of  complaints.  The  parts  pertaining  to 
finance  are  as  follows  : 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  370-75-  To  understand  this  section  properly,  the  fol- 
lowing distinctions  must  be  borne  in  mind :  There  is,  first,  the  depart- 
ment of  the  diwdn,  which  is  charged  with  the  settlement  (istifa'}  and 
the  audit  (muhdsabah)  of  accounts.  This  department  is  referred  to 
by  al-Mawardi,  as  kdtib  al-dlwdn  or  sdhib  al-dlwdn,  the  latter  appar- 
ently applying  to  the  head  of  the  department.  While  an  audit  refers 
to  the  accuracy  of  an  account,  a  settlement,  on  the  other  hand,  refers, 
as  it  were,  to  the  life  career  of  the  funds  mentioned  in  an  account, — 
namely,  whether  or  not  they  have  been  properly  disposed  by  the  person 
who  had  laid  hands  on  them,  by  their  being  turned  over,  for  instance,  to 
the  treasurer,  who  is  referred  to  as  the  sdhib  bayt-al-mdl.  The  word 
'dmilun  (plural  of  'dmil)  denotes  the  collectors  who  collect  the  taxes. 
They  may  turn  them  over  directly  to  the  treasurer,  or  to  some  author- 
ized official  ('mmdl,  also  plural  of  'dmil),  who  passes  them  on  to  the 
treasurer.  There  is,  finally,  the  official  who  issues  authorizations 
(tawql')  for  the  payment  of  funds.  He  is  referred  to  as  muwaqqi'. 
On  the  other  hand,  the  person  in  whose  favor  the  authorization  was 
issued  is  called  muwaqqa'  lah  or  sdhib  al-tawqi'.  Ihtisdb  means  to  give 
credit  for  a  sum.  Khar]  ila  refers  to  a  revenue,  kharj  min,  to  an  ex- 
penditure. 


CONCERNING  PUBLIC  RECORDS  495 

The  registrar  of  the  diw&n  sees  to  it  that  the  laws  passed 
during  his  tenure  of  office  are  recorded  in  the  dliu&n  of  the 
respective  district  (nahiyah)  as  well  as  in  the  diivSn  of  the 
public  treasury,  where  a  duplicate  of  all  district  records  is 
kept.  As  regards  laws  passed  before  his  time,  he  refers  to 
their  existing  records,  if  those  records  have  been  written 
by  trustworthy  registrars,  and  if  the  records  have  been  de- 
livered to  him  under  the  seal  of  the  persons  entrusted  with 
their  safe  keeping. 

However,  such  reports  do  not  constitute  evidence  in  the 
usage  of  courts.  Abu  Hanifah  holds  that  the  registrar 
(katib)  of  the  dlivan  may  not  rely  upon  a  written  record 
unless  he  has  heard  its  contents  directly  from  the  person  who 
wrote  the  record  and  he  meanwhile  keeps  it  in  his  memory.1 
Abu  Hanifah  arrived  at  this  view  by  the  analogy  of  legal  tes- 
timony and  judgment.  However,  such  a  view  is  impossible 
and  absurd,  for  as  testimony  and  judgment  relate  to  private 
rights  where  the  persons  who  would  take  a  hand  in  (mu- 
bashir),  and  look  after  (qayyim)  them  are  many  and  it  is 
not  difficult  for  them  to  keep  the  facts  in  memory,  it  is  not 
lawful  in  their  case  to  rely  upon  writing  alone.  The  rules 
and  customs  of  the  diwan,  however,  are  matters  of  public 
interest  (huquq  (ammah)  which  it  is  hard  to  keep  in 
memory,  for  although  they  are  many  and  widespread,  the 
persons  who  would  actually  take  a  hand  in  them  are  few. 
Consequently,  in  their  case,  writing  may  be  relied  upon  alone. 

The  settlement  of  the  accounts  of  dues  and  taxes.  Two 
cases  are  possible.  The  settlement  may  refer  to  the  ac- 
counts of  the  collectors  ('amilun)  directly  responsible  for 
them,  or  it  may  refer  to  the  accounts  of  the  officials  (eum- 
mal}  who  have  received  the  taxes  from  the  collectors. 
With  respect  to  the  settlement  of  accounts  of  the  collectors 

1  Cf.  Kashf,  p.  771. 


496  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

('amilun),  if  the  officials  ((ummal)  admit  having  received 
from  them  the  tax,  their  word  is  accepted.  If  the  admis- 
sion is  in  writing,  the  practice  of  the  registrars  is  to  consider 
such  a  written  admission  as  evidence  of  the  receipt  of  the 
tax  if,  by  comparison  with  the  well-known  writing  of  the 
official,  the  writing  is  recognized  to  be  his ;  whether  or  not  he 
admits  it.  However,  the  opinion  of  the  jurists  on  this 
point  is  that  if  the  official  denies  that  the  writing  is  his,  the 
writing  alone  cannot  be  held  as  evidence  against  him.  If 
the  official  admits  the  writing  to  be  his,  but  denies  that  he 
has  actually  received  the  tax,  this  written  admission,  as  is 
otherwise  the  custom,  constitutes  evidence,  according  to  al- 
Shafi'i,  in  the  matter  of  public  dues  alone,  that  the  tax  has 
been  paid  by  the  persons  concerned  (nm'amiluri)  and  that 
the  official  received  the  same;  but  Abu  Hanifah  here  again 
differs  from  al-Shafi'i. 

As  regards  the  settlement  of  the  account  of  the  officials, 
if  it  is  a  case  of  revenue  for  the  public  treasury  (kharj  ila 
bayt-al-mal) ,  it  is  not  necessary  for  the  official  to  show  an 
authorization  from  the  proper  authority  (tawqf  wcdi  al- 
amr),  and  the  admission  of  the  treasurer  (sahib  bayt-al- 
mat)  that  he  received  the  money  is  sufficient  for  the  ac- 
quittal of  the  official.  If  the  admission  of  the  treasurer  is 
merely  in  writing  and  has  not  been  confirmed  by  his  oral 
admission,  according  to  al-Shan'i,  it  is  evidence  that  he  re- 
ceived the  money,  although  Abu  Hanifah  holds  the  opposite 
view. 

If,  on  the  contrary,  it  is  a  case  of  a  treasury  expenditure 
instead  of  revenue,  then  the  officials  may  not  make  the  ex- 
penditure except  upon  a  written  authorization  from  the 
proper  authorities,  such  an  authorization,  when  genuine, 
being  sufficient  ground  for  the  expenditure.  There  are, 
however,  two  possible  courses  (wajhan)  in  giving  the  offi- 
cial credit  (ihtisab)  for  the  amount  included  in  the  authori- 


CONCERNING  PUBLIC  RECORDS  497 

zation.  The  first  course,  which  is  the  one  recommended  by 
the  faqihs,  is  that  if  the  person  in  whose  favor  the  authori- 
zation of  payment  has  been  issued  (nmwaqqa'  lah)  admits 
having  received  payment  of  the  amount  contained  in  the 
authorization,  the  official  who  made  the  payment  is  given 
credit  for  the  amount ;  otherwise  he  is  not  given  credit  for 
it.  because  the  authorization,  although  it  entitles  the  official 
to  pay  the  money,  is  by  no  means  evidence  that  he  actually 
did  pay  it.  The  other  course,  which  is  the  one  followed  in 
the  practice  of  the  dnvan,  is  to  give  the  official  credit  for  the 
amount  in  question  so  far  as  the  public  treasury  is  con- 
cerned, and  if  the  person  in  whose  favor  the  authorization 
was  issued  (sahib  al-taivql1 )  denies  having  received  the 
amount,  he  institutes  a  suit  against  the  official.  The  offi- 
cial in  such  case  has  to  support  his  contention  by  presenting 
legal  evidence,  or,  if  he  has  no  evidence,  by  demanding  the 
oath,  failing  in  which  he  has  to  repeat  the  payment. 

If  the  public  registrar  (sahib  al-diw&n)  has  reasons  to 
doubt  the  fact  of  authorization,  whether  or  not  the  persons 
in  whose  favor  it  was  issued  admits  receipt  of  the  amount 
involved,  he  does  not  give  the  official  credit  for  it  until  he 
has  inquired  about  the  matter  from  the  person  who  issued  the 
authorization  (muwaqqf).  If  the  latter  admits  having  is- 
sued it,  then  the  procedure  is  as  above  noted.  If,  how- 
ever, he  denies  it,  the  official  is  not  given  credit  for  the 
amount  involved.  In  this  last  case,  the  official  recovers  his 
loss  by  recourse  to  the  persons  to  whom  he  made  the  pay- 
ment, if  such  a  recourse  is  still  possible;  otherwise  the  only 
remedy  left  to  him  is  to  demand  the  oath  from  the  person 
alleged  to  have  issued  the  authorization  (muwaqqi'). 

The  Record  of  Reports  in  the  Diwan.  There  are  three 
kinds  of  reports  (rufuf)  :  (i)  reports  of  areas  and  accounts 
(a'mal}  ;  (2)  reports  of  receipts  (qabd)  and  settlements 
(istifa);  (3)  reports  of  expenditure  (nafaqcth).  As  re- 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

gards  reports  of  area  and  account,  if  there  are  already  in 
the  diwan  previously  established  (muqaddar)  records 
(usul),  their  truth  is  determined  by  reference  to  those 
records,  and  if  the  reports  are  found  to  be  in  accordance 
with  them,  they  are  entered  (ithbat).  If,  however,  there 
are  no  such  records,  then  the  entry  is  made  in  accordance 
with  the  statements  of  the  person  who  made  the  report 
(rail1).  As  regards  reports  of  receipt  and  settlement,  they 
are  entered  in  the  registers,  on  the  mere  strength  of  the 
statement  of  the  person  who  is  making  the  report,  since  he 
is  reporting  against,  and  not  for,  his  own  interests.  Finally, 
as  regards  reports  of  expenditure,  the  person  making  the 
report  is  really  putting  forth  a  claim  (da'wa)  and  there- 
fore his  report  is  not  entered  unless  substantiated  by  con- 
vincing proof.  If  he  presents  as  evidence  the  authorization 
(tawqi')  of  a  superior  officer  the  procedure  is  as  explained 
above. 

The  Audit  of  the  Accounts  of  Officials.  The  procedure 
in  this  connection  differs  according  as  the  collector  deals  with 
tithe  or  kharaj.  If  he  is  a  collector  of  kharaj,  then  it  is 
his  duty  to  make  a  report  (raf)  of  his  account  to  the  regis- 
trar, who  is  bound  to  verify  the  accuracy  of  the  account. 
It  is  not,  however,  the  duty  of  the  collector  of  tithe  to 
make  a  report  of  his  account  to  the  registrar,  nor  is  it  the 
duty  of  the  registrar  to  audit  his  account,  because  the  tithe, 
in  al-ShafiTs  opinion,  is  a  kind  of  sadaqah  whose  disburse- 
ment so  little  is  a  prerogative  of  the  authorities  (wulat), 
that  should  the  tithe  payer  settle  his  tithe  dues  directly  to 
the  poor,  his  debt  is  discharged  (ajzaat)  as  between  him 
and  God.  According  to  Abu  Hanifah,  however,  the  col- 
lector of  tithe  is  under  obligation  to  make  a  report  of  his 
account,  and  the  registrar  to  audit  the  same. 

When  the  account  of  a  collector  has  been  audited  by  the 
registrar  of  the  diwan,  if  no  difference  of  view  has  arisen 


CONCERNING  PUBLIC  RECORDS  499 

between  the  two,  the  registrar  is  believed  with  respect  to 
his  audit,1  but  should  the  proper  authority  (wali  al-amr) 
entertain  doubts  on  this  score,  he  may  require  the  registrar 
to  bring  his  evidence.  If,  thereupon,  the  proper  author- 
ity's suspicions  cease,  no  oath  is  administered  to  any  one. 
In  the  contrary  case,  the  authority  in  question  may  require 
the  oath  from  the  collector,  but  not  from  the  registrar, 
since  it  is  the  collector  who  is  subject  to  demand.  If,  how- 
ever, the  collector  and  the  registrar  have  differed  concern- 
ing the  account,  the  collector  is  believed  upon  his  oath 
if  the  disagreement  bears  on  an  item  of  revenue,  since  in 
this  case  the  assertion  is  made  by  the  registrar  and  the  bur- 
den of  proof  rests  on  him.  If,  on  the  contrary,  the  dispute 
has  to  do  with  an  item  of  expenditure,  then  the  collector 
must  prove  his  assertion.  If,  finally,  the  dispute  concerns  a 
matter  of  area,  then  the  area  is  remeasured,  if  that  is  pos- 
sible. 

1  The  text  here  reads,  "  with  respect  to  the  balance  of  the  account " 
(fi  baqdya  al-hisdb).  The  word  "balance,"  however,  was  omitted  as  a 
meaningless,  and  probably  later,  addition. 


CHAPTER  XIV 
PUBLIC  DOMAIN  * 

THE  concession  (iqttf)  of  a  piece  of  land  by  the  sultan 
is  allowed  only  as  regards  lands  which  he  may  administer 
and  dispose  of  (tasarruf),  and  concerning  which  his  orders 
are  valid.  Consequently,  his  concession  is  not  valid  when 
exercised  with  regard  to  lands  which  are  the  property  of 
known  and  definite  persons.  Concessions  are  of  two  kinds : 
concessions  of  ownership  (iqta  tamlik),  and  concessions  of 
usufruct  (iqtae  istiglal).  Al-Shafi'i,2  speaking  of  this  dis- 
tinction, says  that  in  the  case  of  iqtaf  irfaq,  as  he  calls  iqta 
istiglal ,  the  grantee  has  only  the  right  of  use  (intifaf)  as 
distinct  from  ownership  (raqabah),  and  the  right  to  pre- 
vent others  from  using  it  so  long  as  he  or  his  agent  is  using 
it;  but  that  he  forfeits  his  right  by  abandoning  the  thing 
granted,  and  that  he  may  not  sell  it  to  others.  The  conces- 
sions referred  to  in  this  chapter  with  respect  to  waste  and 
cultivated  lands  are  concessions  of  ownership. 

Concession  of  Waste  Lands  (mawat)*  According  to 
al-Shafi'i,  the  term  "  waste  "  applies  to  every  piece  of  land 
which  is  not  proper  for  cultivation  ('amir)  and  is  not  the 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  33O-37,  341-43- 

8  Umm,  vol.  iii,  p.  266. 

*  Mawardi,  pp.  330-2,  308-13;  Umm,  vol.  iii,  p.  265;  Mugni,  vol.  ii,  p. 
3345  IVajiz,  p.  241;  Ansari,  vol.  ii,  p.  444;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  171; 
Hiddyah,  voK  ix,  p.  2;  Bahr,  vol.  viii,  p.  238;  Zayla'i,  vol.  vi,  p.  35; 
Majma',  vol.  ii,  p.  436;  Yusuf,  p.  36;  Mabsiit,  part  xxiii,  p.  166;  /ami', 
vol.  ii,  p.  276;  'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  v,  p.  574;  Durr,  p.  708;  Dardir,  voL 
ii,  p.  181 ;  Yahya,  p.  6r. 
5<x> 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN  501 

hanm  (complement  or  dependancy)  of  land  proper  for  cul- 
tivation. According  to  Abu  Yusuf,  a  piece  of  land  which 
cannot  be  utilized  is  not  considered  "  waste  "  unless  it  is  far 
enough  from  a  town  so  that  a  person  standing  on  this  land 
at  a  point  nearest  to  the  town  and  shouting  at  the  top  of  his 
voice  cannot  be  heard  from  the  town.  Muhammad  Ibn  al- 
Hasan,  on  the  other  hand,  holds  that  a  piece  of  land  is 
waste  if  it  can  not  be  utilized,  whether  it  is  near  or  far 
from  a  town.  According  to  al-Kasani  *  lands  located  with- 
in towns  are  never  considered  "  waste." 

A  piece  of  land,  in  order  to  be  waste  land,  must  further- 
more be  the  property  of  no  one,  for  if  a  piece  of  land  is 
known  to  have  a  present  owner,  whether  a  Moslem  or  a 
dhimmi.  it  is  not  considered  waste,  even  if  it  has  been  liter- 
ally waste  for  ages.  On  the  contrary,  a  piece  of  land  is 
considered  waste  if  at  present  its  owner  is  not  known, 
whether  the  land  has  lain  waste  without  an  owner  from 
time  immemorial,  or  whether  it  was  at  one  time  under  cul- 
tivation before  it  later  went  to  waste,  before  or  after  Islam. 
This  is  the  view  of  Abu  Hanlfah.  However,  according  to 
his  disciple,  Muhammad,  if  the  land  is  known  to  have  had 
an  owner  at  some  time  since  the  advent  of  Islam,  whether 
or  not  the  present  owner  is  known,  the  land  is  not  treated 
as  waste,  but  belongs  to  the  Moslem  community  at  large. 
According  to  al-Shafi'i,  such  lands,  whether  or  not  their 
present  owners  are  known,  are  not  waste,  that  is,  they  do 
not  become  private  property  by  being  developed  for  cultiva- 
tion (ihyd'),  etc.  According  to  al-Mawardi,  the  reason 
why  lands  which  have  lain  waste  from  pre-Islamic 
times,  such  as  the  lands  of  'Ad  and  Thamud,1  are  treated  as 

1  Vol.  vi,  p.  194. 

5  Ancient  Arabian  tribes.  The  adjective  'ddi,  derived  from  'Ad,  is 
used  by  the  doctors  in  the  sense  of  what  has  been  from  time  immemo- 
rial (qadim'). 


502  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

waste  lands  is  the  hadith :  "  The  lands  which  come  from  'Ad 
('adi  al-ard)  belong  to  God  and  to  His  Prophet;  then  they 
are  given  to  you  (i.  e.,  the  Moslems)  from  me."  According 
to  the  Malikites,1  waste  lands  are  lands  which  have  not 
become  private  property  (ikhtisds)  through  purchase  or 
through  some  other  method  of  acquisition,  or  by  being  de- 
veloped (ihya')  for  cultivation,  etc. ;  or  by  being  the  harim 
of  developed  lands,  such  as  the  pasture  lands  which  are  the 
harims  of  a  village,  or  such  as  the  harims  of  springs,  trees 
and  houses;  or  by  being  given  in  concession  (iqtd()  by  the 
imam;  or  finally  by  being  reserved  (hima)  by  the  imam  as 
pasture  land,  etc.,  for  common  use. 

Abu  Yusuf,2  true  to  his  definition  of  a  "  waste  "  land, 
does  not  allow  to  the  imam  the  concession  of  waste  lands 
which  are  near  a  town  within  the  distance  mentioned,  be- 
cause, he  argues,  such  lands  are  apt  to  be  used  by  the  towns- 
people as  meadows,  etc.  Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  how- 
ever, allows  the  concession  of  such  lands,  if  they  are  not 
used  by  the  town  folk  in  some  way,  e.  g.,  for  getting  wood 
or  pasturing;  on  the  contrary,  he  does  not  allow  the  en- 
closure of  lands  for  private  use,  if  they  are  used  by  the 
town  people,  no  matter  how  far  from  the  town  the  lands 
are  situated.  According  to  the  Malikites,3  the  imam  may 
give  away  in  concession  even  such  waste  lands  as  are  used  by 
village  people  as  pasture  land  and  wood  land  (muhtatab). 

When  a  piece  of  land  coming  under  the  description  of 
waste  as  above  explained  is  developed  (ihya')  by  a  person, 
it  becomes  his  property.  According  to  the  Hanifites,  such 
person  may  be  a  Moslem  or  a  dhimmi,  but  according  to  the 
Shafiites,  and,  as  regards  waste  lands  situated  in  the  vicinity 

1  Kharashi,  vol.  v,  p.  66;  Dardlr,  vol.  ii,  pp.  181-2. 
1  Majtna',  vol.  ii,  p.  437. 
1  Dardir,  vol.  ii,  p.  181. 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN 


503 


of  towns,  also  the  accepted  Malikite  views,  only  a  Moslem 
may  acquire  the  ownership  of  waste  lands  by  development. 
The  Malikites,  however,  allow  the  dhimmis  equal  rights  as 
regards  waste  lands  distant  from  towns.1 

According  to  Abu  Hanifah,  a  person  acquires  property  in 
a  piece  of  land  he  developed  only  in  case  he  had  beforehand 
obtained  the  permission  (iqta'  or  idhn)  of  the  imam  to  de- 
velop it.  According  to  his  two  disciples  and  to  al-Shafi'i, 
the  permission  of  the  imam  is  not  necessary.  Finally,  ac- 
cording to  the  Malikites,2  permission  is  necessary  only  as 
regards  waste  lands  situated  in  the  vicinity  of  towns.  The 
ground  for  Abu  Hanifah's  view  is  the  hadith :  "  A  person 
owns  only  what  pleases  his  imam  ".  Besides,  lands  are  a 
kind  of  booty  obtained  from  unbelievers  and  like  all  booty, 
no  part  of  it  may  be  owned  without  permission  from  the 
imam.  The  ground  for  the  opposite  view  is  another  hadith 
to  the  effect  that  a  person  owns  the  land  he  has  developed 
because  lands,  like  game,  are  free  property  (mub&h)* 

There  is  dispute  as  to  the  technical  meaning  of  the  word 
ihya  (development).  According  to  the  'Indyah,  as  quoted 
in  the  Bahr,  ihya'  consists  in  ploughing  and  irrigating  the 
land ;  either  one  by  itself  being  insufficient  According  to 
the  Kofi,  either  one  of  them  is  sufficient.  According  to 
Abu  Yusuf,  ihya'  is  building,  or  sowing,  or  ploughing,  or 
irrigating.  According  to  one  report  from  Muhammad  Ibn 
al-Hasan,  ploughing  is  not  ihya',  unless  followed  by  sowing. 
According  to  the  Mabsut*  ihya  consists  in  rendering  the  land 
fit  for  cultivation  by  ploughing,  or  building  water  channels, 
or  digging  a  canal  leading  to  it.  According  to  the  Majallah* 

1  Majma',  vol.  ii,  p.  436;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  171 ;  Dardir,  vol.  ii,  p.  183. 

1  Kharashi,  vol.  v,  p.  70. 

s  Hiddyah,  vol.  ix,  pp.  3-4.  4P.  168. 

5  Article  1051 ;  also  arts.  1275,  1276. 


504 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


ihya'  consists  in  rendering  land  fit  for  cultivation.  Accord- 
ing to  al-Mawardi,  the  exact  meaning  of  ihya  is  fixed  by 
reference  to  the  purpose  for  which  the  land  is  developed  in 
accordance  with  custom,  since  the  Prophet  has  left  it  un- 
determined. Thus  if  the  land  is  intended  for  residence,  it  is 
considered  "  developed  "  (ihya)  if  a  covered  building  is 
erected  on  it,  since  that  is  the  minimum  necessary  for  use  as 
residence.  If,  on  the  other  hand,  the  land  is  developed  for 
cultivation,  then  three  things  are  required :  ( I )  The  land 
must  be  marked  off  on  all  sides  by  heaping  up  earth.  (2) 
The  land  must  be  irrigated,  if  it  is  dry,  and  drained  if 
marshy.  (3)  The  land  must  be  tilled  (harth)  ;  but  it  is  not 
necessary  that  it  should  be  sown  or  planted,  any  more  than 
that  the  house  should  be  actually  inhabited.  Al-Shafi'i,  as  a 
counterpart  to  his  distinction  between  concession  of  owner- 
ship and  concession  of  usufruct,  distinguishes  between  the 
ihyaf  which  results  in  the  ownership  of  the  thing  developed, 
and  the  development  which  is  not  customarily  called  ihya' 
and  produces  a  tithe  of  usufruct  only.  Thus  if  a  nomad 
tribe  puts  up  tents  or  wooden  huts  it  is  not  a  case  of  ibytf, 
and  the  tribe  does  not  acquire  the  ownership  of  the  ground 
but  is  only  entitled  to  its  use  until  it  leaves  the  place.  Finally. 
according  to  the  Malikites,  ihya'  consists  in  providing  a 
means  of  irrigation,  or  draining,  or  putting  up  a  building, 
or  plantng,  or  tilling,  or  clearing  the  land  from  trees,  or 
leveling  the  ground.  It  does  not  consist  in  enclosing  the 
land  with  a  wall,  or  using  it  for  grazing. 

When  the  imam  makes  a  concession  (iqta'),  of  waste 
land  to  a  person,  such  person  acquires  a  title  to  the  develop- 
ment of  that  land  as  over  against  others,  and  in  this,  al- 
Shafi'i  agrees  with  Abu  Hanifah.  The  concessionaire, 
however,  does  not  acquire  the  ownership  of  the  land  before 
developing  it.  If  he  fails  to  do  so,  he  does  not  own  it,  but 
he  nevertheless  has  a  title  of  possession  (yad)  to  that  land, 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN  505 

as  over  against  others.  If  his  failure  is  due  to  an  evident 
cause,  the  land  is  left  in  his  possession  until  the  disappear- 
ance of  the  cause.  If  he  had  no  excuse  for  his  failure,  ac- 
cording to  Abu  Hanifah  he  is  not  molested  during  three 
years  from  the  date  of  concession,  but,  should  he  fail  to 
develop  the  land  within  that  time,  the  concession  becomes 
null  and  void,  and  the  land  reverts  to  the  status  of  waste. 
This  term  of  three  years  is  based  on  a  precedent  of  Omar. 
According  to  al-Shafi'i,  Omar's  precedent  is  not  binding 
as  it  was  meant  for  a  special  case,  and  the  length  of  the 
term  is  determined  by  the  possibility  of  development.  Con- 
sequently, if  the  concessionaire  fails  to  develop  the  land  dur- 
ing a  long  enough  term,  he  is  required  either  to  develop 
the  land,  or  to  forfeit  his  title  to  it  in  order  that  the  land 
may  be  granted  to  others. 

If,  during  these  three  years,  the  land  is  developed  by  some 
one  other  than  the  concessionaire,  according  to  Abu  Hani- 
fah, the  land  still  belongs  to  the  concessionaire.  The  case 
is  otherwise,  however,  if  it  was  developed  after  the  three 
years.  According  to  al-Shafi'i,  the  land  in  either  case  be- 
longs to  the  person  who  developed  it. 

According  to  the  Malikites,1  the  concession  (iqta')  by  the 
imam  of  waste  land  in  and  of  itself  results  in  its  becoming 
the  property  of  the  concessionaire,  even  if  he  fails  to  de- 
velop the  land  or  neglects  it  after  development.  If,  how- 
ever, a  piece  of  land  was  acquired  by  development  (ihyft'), 
it  may  not  be  allowed  to  lie  waste  for  a  long  time,  for 
should  such  land  be  meanwhile  developed  by  a  third  party 
it  becomes  the  property  of  the  latter.  According  to  a  re- 
port from  Ibn  Rushd,  if  in  the  above  case  the  third  party 
developed  the  land  shortly  after  its  neglect  by  the  first  de- 
veloper, the  latter  continues  to  own  the  land,  but  the  third 

1  Dardlr,  vol.  ii,  p.  182;  Kharashi,  vol.  v,  pp.  66,  69;  'Adawi,  vol.  v, 
P.  67. 


506  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

party  must  be  compensated  for  the  standing  (qaimah) 
value  of  his  development,  if  he  was  not  aware  of  the  fact 
of  previous  development ;  otherwise  he  is  compensated  only 
for  the  value  of  his  development  as  removed  from  its  posi- 
tion (maqlu'a). 

According  to  al-Shafi'i,  when  a  person  develops  a  piece 
of  land  he  acquires  a  title  of  ownership  not  only  to  the  land 
so  developed,  but  also  to  such  adjoining  land  as  is  indispen- 
sable for  the  full  use  of  the  land  developed.  For  instance, 
he  is  entitled  to  a  way,  to  a  courtyard  (/ma'),  to  channels 
for  drainage  and  water,  etc.  These  rights  are  designated 
under  the  collective  term  of  harim,  which  is  defined  by  the 
Rawd  ol-Talib  *  as  the  immediate  environment  necessary  for 
the  full  use  of  a  property.  According  to  the  Hidayah,  the 
harim  of  a  land  developed  for  planting  trees  is  five  cubits 
on  every  side. 

If  a  person,  instead  of  developing  a  piece  of  land,  con- 
tents himself  with  the  initial  stages  of  development  known 
as  tahjir  (literally,  enclosure),  marking  off  the  land  by 
placing  stones  all  around  it,  in  order  to  indicate  his  inten- 
tion of  development,2  according  to  the  Minh&j,  he  becomes 
entitled  (ahaqq)  to  this  land  as  against  others,  but  he  may 
not  sell  it,  and  should  another  develop  it  the  latter  owns  it. 
If  the  encloser  unduly  delays  the  development  of  the 
land,  he  is  required  by  the  sultan  to  develop  it  within  a 
short  time  or  forego  his  rights.  According  to  the  Hanifites, 
the  encloser  acquires  a  priority  with  respect  to  the  land  for 
three  years,  but  only  as  a  matter  of  religion  (diyanah),  so 
much  so  that  if  another  person  should  develop  it  mean- 
while he  acquires  the  land.  After  the  lapse  of  the  three 

1  Ansari,  vol.  ii,  p.  445. 

1  According  to  the  Hanifites,  tahjir  consists  in  marking  off  the  land 
by  placing  stones  or  sticking  branches  all  around,  or  by  burning  the 
dry  herbs  grown  on  the  land,  etc. 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN  507 

years,  the  land  is  given  to  others  in  order  that  it  may  become 
a  source  of  tax  revenue.  This  term  of  three  years  is  based 
on  the  precedent  of  Omar  who  desired  to  check  the  prac- 
tice of  enclosing  land  and  not  developing  it  later.1 

According  to  the  ' Alamkiriyyah  and  the  Majallah,  if  the 
imdm  permits  the  development  of  a  piece  of  land  on  condi- 
tion that  the  person  developing  it  shall  be  entitled  to  pos- 
session alone,  the  land  does  not  become  his  property.3 
Cultivated  Lands.  These  are  of  two  kinds : 
(a)  Those  whose  owners  are  definite  and  known  persons. 
The  imam  has  no  jurisdiction  over  these  lands,3  whether 
owned  by  Moslems  or  by  dhimmis,  if  they  are  situated  in 
the  Moslem  state,  except  in  so  far  as  they  are  subject  to 
taxes.  If,  however,  these  lands  are  situated  in  the  country 
of  the  enemy  over  which  the  Moslems  have  not  as  yet  ex- 
ercised rights  of  possession  (yad)  and  the  imam  wishes  to 
make  a  concession  of  them  which  will  be  valid  when  such 
lands  shall  have  been  conquered,  it  is  lawful.  There  are 
instances  of  such  concessions  made  by  the  Prophet  him- 
self. Thus  Tamim  asked  the  Prophet  to  give  him  in  con- 
cession the  springs  of  the  city  of  Damascus,  before  the  city 
was  yet  conquered,  and  the  Prophet  granted  his  request. 
Again,  the  Prophet  made  concession  of  land  in  the  Byzan- 
tine empire  to  al-Khushni  upon  his  request.  The  same 
rule  applies  if  a  person  is  presented  with  wealth  or 

1  Yahya,  p.  66.  The  Hanifite  texts  are  very  confusing  on  the  matter 
of  enclosures.  Most  of  them  suggest,  and  some  explicitly  state,  that  an 
enclosure,  to  entitle  to  priority  for  three  years,  must  have  been  based  on 
a  permit  (iqta).  The  Mabsut,  however,  on  which  later  works  are  largely 
based,  clearly  suggests  the  opposite,  and  the  Jdmi'  expressly  states  that 
permission  is  immaterial.  The  Majallah,  finally,  is  conceived  clearly  in 
this  same  spirit.  This  is  also  in  accordance  with  history,  as  appears 
from  Yahya. 

1  Cf.  Kharashi,  vol.  v,  p.  69. 

*  Cf.  t/wm,  vol.  iii,  p.  273. 


ro8  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

U 

women  or  children  belonging  to  enemies.  All  these  gifts 
and  concessions  are  valid  when  the  conquest  is  made.  If 
the  conquest  is  made  in  the  way  of  peaceful  agreement,  the 
things  made  presents  of  are  excluded  from  the  effect  of  the 
terms  of  peace.  If,  however,  the  conquest  is  made  by  force 
of  arms  then  the  army  is  not  compensated  for  these  presents 
if  they  knew  about  them;  otherwise  the  imam  must  satisfy 
them  in  some  way.  Abu  Hanifah  says  that  the  imam  need 
not  do  so,  when  there  is  public  benefit  in  excluding  certain 
things  from  the  spoils. 

(b)  Cultivated  lands  whose  owners  are  not  known.  These 
are  of  three  classes:  (i)  Lands  which  are  set  apart  by  the 
imam  for  the  public  treasury  (bayt-al-mal)  either  because 
they  came  to  belong  to  the  state  as  its  one-fifth  share  in  the 
spoils  of  war,  or  because  the  imam  reserved  certain  lands 
for  the  public  treasury,  the  army  being  compensated  for  it 
otherwise.  For  example,  Omar  reserved  for  the  public 
treasury  from  the  lands  of  Sawad  the  lands  owned  by  the 
Persian  king  (kisra)  and  by  the  members  of  his  dynasty,  and 
the  lands  whose  owners  had  fled  or  perished.  The  rentals 
of  these  lands  amounted  to  nine  million  dirhaws,  and 
were  spent  for  the  Moslem  cause  in  general.  Omar  did 
not  give  any  of  these  lands  in  concession.  Later  'Uthman, 
his  successor,  leased  them  (iqta  i  jar  ah)  because  he  thought 
that  it  would  be  better  from  the  standpoint  of  yield  to 
place  them  in  private  hands  by  iqta'  rather  than  to  have  them 
lie  idle,  it  being  a  condition  of  the  lease  that  the  lessees  would 
pay  the  rights  of  the  public  (haqq  al-fa'y).  This  was  there- 
fore a  case  of  concession  of  usufruct,  not  of  ownership  of 
the  land,  and  in  this  way  the  rentals  increased,  until  they 
reached,  as  is  alleged,  fifty  million  dirhams.  'Uthman  made 
his  presents  and  gifts  out  of  these  sums.  Things  continued 
in  this  way  until  the  year  eighty-two,  when  during  the  re- 
bellion of  Ibn  al-Ash'ath,  the  registers  were  burnt  and  each 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN  509 

people  took  possession  of  the  lands  situated  in  their  neigh- 
borhood. 

It  is  not  lawful  to  alienate  the  ownership  of  the  public 
in  these  lands,  because  such  lands  by  being  reserved  by  the 
imam  for  the  public  treasury  have  become  the  property  of 
all  the  Moslems  and  hence  mortmain  (waqf)  forever. 

The  Malikite  view  of  the  matter  is  similar.1  However, 
according  to  the  Hanifites,  who  do  not  require  the  constitu- 
tion of  these  lands  into  waqf  property,  it  is  allowable  for  the 
imam  to  give  them  away  in  concession.2 

With  regard  to  these  lands,  the  imam  has  the  right,  with 
a  view  to  insuring  the  best  interests  of  the  Moslems,  to  do 
one  of  the  following  two  things :  To  have  them  cultivated 
on  account  of  the  public  treasury  (yastagilluhu  li  bayt-al- 
mal),  as  did  Omar;  or  to  leave  them  to  persons  who  possess 
the  ability  to  improve  them,  subject  to  payment  of  kharaj 
fixed  according  to  the  amount  of  the  produce  as  did  'Uth- 
man,  and  in  this  case  the  kharaj  collected  from  these  lands 
is  in  reality  their  rental*  and  is  disbursed  for  works  of 

1  Kharashi,  vol.  v,  p.  69. 

*  Yusuf,  pp.  32-3. 

*  This  practically  amounted  to  a  complete  alienation  of  the  ownership 
of  the  public  treasury  in  these  lands,  the  right  of  the  state  consisting 
simply  in  the  khardj  collected   from  these  lands.     According  to  the 
Mugni  (vol.  iv,  pp.  216-17;  Mawardi,  pp.  302-3),  a  Shafiite  work,  in 
the  case  of  the  lands  of  Sawad,  for  reasons  of  public  interest,  analogy 
was  departed  from  in  that  they  were  leased  by  the  calif  Omar  under  a 
perpetual   lease    (ijdrah  mu'abbadah),   the  khardj  collected    from   the 
landholders  being  the  rental.    The  author  adds  that  although  the  land- 
holders, being  tenants,  may  not  sell  their  landholdings,  they  may  never- 
theless lease  them  for  short  periods ;  furthermore,  that  the  lands  may 
not  be  taken  away  from  their  holders;  finally,  that  the  lease  is  not 
dissolved  upon  the  death  of  the  holders  but  devolves  in  favor  of  their 
heirs.     Al-Shafi'i   (Unun,  vol.  iii,  p.  240;  compare  supra,  p.  377  fn.) 
at  an  earlier  date  had  considered  the  nature  of  the  landholder's  title  to 
these  lands  as  a  case  of  qabdlah.    It  is,  therefore,  very  probable  that 
the   claim   of   al-Mawardi   that   these   lands   continued   to    remain   the 


510  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

general  utility,  unless  the  lands  were  taken  over  by  the  state 
by  virtue  of  its  one-fifth  share  in  the  spoils,  in  which  case 
the  rental  is  disposed  of  to  the  beneficiaries  of  that  share. 

If  the  kharaj  imposed  in  this  case  is  a  half-and-half 
proportion  of  the  fruits  or  the  crops,  it  is  lawful  in  the 
case  of  dates,  following  the  example  of  the  Prophet  who 
had  entered  into  an  agreement  (musaqat)  with  the  people  of 
Khaybar  on  the  condition  that  they  would  pay  to  the 
Prophet  half  of  the  produce  of  their  date  trees.  As  re- 
gards crops  (zar'),  there  is  dispute  among  the  doctors, 
those  who  do  not  allow  the  mukhabarah  system  objecting 
to  it.  Some  say  that  the  proportional  kharaj  may  be 
levied  on  the  crops  even  if  the  mukhabarah  system  in  their 
respect  is  not  lawful,  because  there  is  a  public  benefit  in 
levying  the  proportional  kharaj  and  therefore  in  their  case 
the  law  concerning  private  relations  may  be  departed  from. 

(ii)  The  lands  subject  to  the  payment  of  kharaj.  The 
ownership  of  these  lands  may  not  be  ceded,  because 

property  of  the  state  and  that  the  cultivators  were  merely  tenants,  if  at 
all  true,  was  so  only  in  theory.  (Cf.  Caetani,  vol.  v,  pp.  392-433; 
Berchem,  p.  5,  fn. ;  Worms,  Journal  asiatique,  1842-4.)  Turkish  his- 
tory offers  two  striking  parallels  in  this  line, — the  so-called  domanial 
lands  (arddi  amiriyyah),  and  the  waqf  (pious  foundation)  estates 
known  as  ijdreteynli  awqdf.  Although  theoretically  the  ownership 
(raqabah)  of  these  two  classes  of  property  is  vested  in  the  state 
(Young,  vol.  vi,  p.  45)  or  in  the  waqf  (ibid.,  p.  115),  respectively,  and 
their  holders  are  considered  by  the  Turkish  jurists  as  mere  tenants 
(Husni,  pp.  92-3),  the  latter  nevertheless  practically  own  them.  The 
property  rights  of  the  state  and  the  waqf  were  still  further  weakened 
by  the  laws  of  1867  and  1875,  which  extended  the  right  of  inheritance 
to  their  holders  to  a  considerable  extent.  However,  the  fact  that  in 
theory  the  present  holders  are  only  tenants  constitutes  a  real  handicap 
for  the  holders  when  they  want  to  transfer  or  use  their  lands  as  secur- 
ity for  loan.  One  of  the  many  problems  to  the  solution  of  which  the 
Turkish  Government  has  turned  its  attention  since  the  recent  restora- 
tion of  the  Constitutional  Regime  has  been  the  complete  assimilation 
of  the  domanial  lands  and  the  waqf  properties  to  properties  owned  in 
fee  simple  (milk}, — at  least  in  their  practical  aspects. 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN 

either  they  are  mortmain  lands  and  then  the  kharaj  levied 
on  them  is  in  reality  a  rental,  and  being  mortmain  they 
may  not  be  alienated,  or  they  are  private  property  and  in 
that  case  the  kharaj  levied  on  them  is  a  sort  of  jizyah,  and 
again  they  may  not  be  alienated,  since  their  ownership  is 
vested  in  definite  private  persons.  The  Hanifite  and  Mali- 
kite  views  are  to  the  same  effect.1 

(iii)  Lands  whose  owners  have  died  without  leaving 
rightful  heirs  to  inherit.  Such  lands  devolve  to  the  public 
treasury,  as  inheritance  by  the  Moslems  at  large,  and  there- 
fore they  are  spent  in  the  interests  of  the  Moslems  at  large. 
Abu  Hanifah  says  that  such  property  is  disbursed  to  the 
poor  only  as  an  alms  from  the  deceased  to  them;  al-Shafi'i, 
however,  does  not  agree  with  this  view  because,  as  he  argues, 
by  entering  the  public  treasury  these  properties  have  lost 
their  private  character  and  have  become  the  property  of  all 
the  Moslems.2 

Mines.3  These  are  exposed  or  concealed.  Exposed 
mines  are  those  in  which  the  mineral  deposits  are  visible, 
like  coal,  salt,  tar,  naphtha,  etc.  These  are  like  water,  whose 
grant  is  not  allowed;  all  persons  being  equally  entitled  to 
their  use.  The  person  who  first  lays  hold  on  them  owns 
them.  The  concession  of  exposed  mines,  therefore,  has  no 

1  Cf.  Yusuf ,  pp.  32-33 ;  Kharashi,  vol.  v,  p.  66. 

8  Al-Mawardi  has  probably  in  mind  here  such  lands  as  were  owned 
in  fee  simple  (milk)  by  Moslems  and  upon  their  death  devolved  to  the 
state.  For  such  of  them  as  were  owned  by  dhintntis,  according  to  the 
prevalent  Shafiite  view,  become  fa'y  and  may  not  be  disbursed  for 
purposes  of  public  utility  excepting  the  share  of  tnasdlib  set  apart  from 
them.  Abu  Hanifah's  opinion,  as  quoted  by  al-Mawardi,  also  involves 
a  certain  contradiction ;  for,  as  we  already  saw,  in  the  chapter  on 
Public  Treasury,  according  to  the  current  Hanifite  view,  lands  devolv- 
ing to  the  state  from  dhimmis  become  fa'y,  while  those  devolving  from 
Moslems  are  disbursed  to  widows,  etc. 

*  Mawardi,  pp.  341-3;  Umm,  vol.  iii,  p.  265;  Angari,  vol.  ii,  p.  452; 
cf.  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  178;  Tanbih,  p.  155. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

legal  effect  and  the  grantee  and  others  are  equally  entitled 
to  them,  and  hence  the  concessionaire  may  not  prevent 
others  from  helping  themselves  to  the  mines,  and  he  may 
do  the  same  himself.  The  Hanifite  view  is  to  the  same 
effect.1 

Concealed  mines  are  those  whose  deposits  are  hidden 
under  ground,  and  may  be  reached  only  by  means  of  labor; 
such  as  mines  of  gold,  silver,  copper,  iron,  etc.,  whether  or 
not  the  ore  extracted  needs  smelting  and  purification.  Con- 
cerning the  concession  of  such  mines  there  are  two  views : 
One  view  is  that,  as  in  the  case  of  exposed  mines,  their  con- 
cession is  not  lawful,  all  men  being  alike  entitled  to  them. 
The  other  view  is  that  the  concession  is  valid  in  consequence 
of  what  has  been  related  of  the  Prophet,  namely,  that  the 
Prophet  made  a  grant  of  certain  mines  to  Bilal  Ibn  al- 
Harth.  According  to  this  second  view,  the  grantee  acquires 
a  right  of  priority  (ahaqq)  to  these  mines  and  may  prevent 
others  from  encroaching  on  his  right.  As  regards  the  legal 
status  of  the  concession,  some  hold  that  the  mines  become 
the  property  (raqabah)  of  the  grantee,  it  being  a  case  of 
iqta'  tamlik  (concession  of  ownership),  irrespective  of 
whether  the  grantee  exploits  the  mines  or  leaves  them  idle, 
provided  he  has  already  had  work  done  on  them.  There- 
fore, he  may  sell  them  and  upon  his  death  they  devolve  to 
his  heirs.  Others  contend  that  it  is  a  case  of  concession  of 
usufruct  alone  (iqtaf  irfaq),  and  that,  therefore,  the  grantee 
does  not  acquire  the  ownership  of  the  mines  but  only  the 
right  to  exploit  them  and  to  prevent  others  from  using  them 
during  the  time  that  he  is  working  the  mines,  but  as  soon 
as  he  abandons  the  mines  the  concession  ceases  to  be  ef- 
fective and  the  mines  become  common  property  (mubtih). 
Al-Shafi'i,2  in  subscribing  to  this  second  view,  observes 

1  Durr,  p.  709.  *  Umm,  vol.  iii,  p.  267,  1.  — 17. 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN 

that  apparently  the  ground  for  it  lies  in  the  fact  that  mines 
are  natural  wealth  lying  in  the  ground  and  that  no  art  at- 
taches to  them  when  a  part  of  them  is  extracted  and 
smelted  by  men,  that  consequently  one  should  be  entitled 
to  them  only  in  so  far  as  he  exploits  them.  Al-Shafi'i 
further  observes  that  the  sultan,  in  giving  a  mine  away, 
should  expressly  stipulate  that  the  concessionaire  shall 
pay  the  zakat  that  will  be  due  on  the  mines  he  is  to  operate, 
that  he  shall  be  entitled  to  the  mine  only  so  long  as  he 
operates  it,  and  finally,  that  he  may  not  sell  it  to  others. 

If  a  person  improves  a  tract  of  land,  whether  or  not 
such  tract  has  been  granted  to  him,  and  in  the  process  of 
improvement  mines  are  brought  to  light,  whether  they  are 
exposed  or  concealed,  they  become  the  property  of  the  im- 
prover forever,  exactly  as  springs  and  wells  would  belong 
to  the  person  who  discovered  or  dug  them  up.  According 
to  the  Malikites,1  the  imam  has  full  authority  over  the  dis- 
posal of  mines. 

Hima,  or  Reservations  for  Public  Use.2  Hi  ma  is  the  act 
of  preventing  the  enclosure  (ihya)  of  waste  lands  for  pri- 
vate ownership,  in  order  to  insure  their  perpetual  reservation 
for  common  use,  for  the  grass  that  grows  on  them  and  for 
grazing  cattle.  In  fact  the  Prophet  did  reserve  in  Medina 
a  stretch  of  land  one  by  six  miles  large  for  the  use  of  the 
horses  of  the  Helpers  (ansdr)  and  the  Emigrants  (muliajir). 
Al-Shafi'i,  following  the  precedents  of  the  Prophet  and 
Omar,  says  that  a  reservation  must  redound  to  the  benefit 
of  all  the  Moslems;  that  the  poor  people  living  near  the 
reservation  may  graze  their  cattle  on  it,  though  not  the  rich 
people;  that  the  imam  grazes  on  the  reservation  grounds 
only  those  of  his  animals  which  are  used  in  the  holy  war; 

1  Kharashi,  p.  in. 

1  Mawardi,  p.  322;  cf.  Umm,  vol.  iii,  pp.  270-2;  An§ari,  vol.  ii,  p.  449; 
Kharashi,  vol.  v,  p.  69 ;  Dardlr,  vol.  ii,  p.  182. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

finally,  that  the  grounds  were  and  should  be  used  for  the 
grazing  of  the  horses  and  camels  used  in  the  holy  war,  the 
cattle  collected  as  jigyah,  the  remainder  of  the  sadaqah  cattle, 
and  a  few  stray  cattle.1  As  regards  reservations  made  by 
the  successors  of  the  Prophet,  if  they  have  extended  them  to 
all  the  waste  lands  or  the  greater  part  of  them,  it  is  not  law- 
ful ;  or  if  they  have  made  the  reservation  in  favor  of  some  of 
the  Moslems,  or  the  rich  among  them,  it  is  also  unlawful ;  but 
of  they  have  made  reservation  in  favor  of  all  the  Moslems,  or 
the  poor  and  the  indigent,  in  one  opinion,  the  reservation  is 
not  valid,  inasmuch  as  the  right  to  make  reservations  be- 
longed to  the  Prophet  alone,  who  in  making  the  reservation 
above-mentioned,  said :  "  There  is  no  reservation  except  for 
God  and  His  Prophet".  According  to  the  other  opinion,  the 
reservations  made  by  the  successors  of  the  Prophet  are 
valid,  as  were  those  made  by  the  Prophet  himself,  inas- 
much as  the  Prophet  made  these  reservations  for  the  benefit 
of  Moslems,  not  for  his  own  private  interests,  and,  there- 
fore, those  who  came  in  the  Prophet's  place  as  regards 
Moslem  interests,  are  equally  entitled  to  make  reserva- 
tions. Consequently,  the  meaning  of  the  Prophetic  say- 
ing :  "  There  is  no  reservation  except  for  God  and  His 
Prophet ",  is  that  there  may  be  no  reservation  except  for 
the  benefit  of  the  poor  and  the  indigent,  and  in  the  interests 
of  the  Moslems  in  general,  as  contrasted  with  what  used 
to  be  the  case  in  the  pre-Islamic  times  when  the  strong  re- 
served the  land  for  their  own  particular  use.2 

1  According  to  a  report  from  Malik   (Zarqani,  vol.  iv,  p.  247),  the 
number  of   such   cattle  pastured   on   reservation   grounds   during  the 
califate  of  Omar  was  forty  thousand. 

2  It  is  related  that  Kulayb  Ibn  Wall  used  to  take  a  dog  to  an  elevated 
place  and  let  him  loose,  and  then  reserve  for  his  own  use  all  the  land 
for  a  distance  as  far  as  the  yelping  of  the  dog  could  be  heard  in  every 
direction,  the  outlying  land  being  used  by  others  in  common.   'This  is 
alleged  to  have  resulted  finally  in  his  murder.     Cf.  Umm,  vol.  iii,  p. 
270. 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN 

If  the  reservation  has  been  made  for  the  benefit  of  all, 
then  all  persons,  rich  or  poor,  Moslems,  or  dhimmis,  have 
equal  rights  to  pasture  their  horses  and  cattle  in  the  reser- 
vation grounds.  If,  however,  the  reservation  has  been 
made  for  Moslems  alone,  then  only  Moslems,  both  rich  and 
poor  can  use  it.  On  the  other  hand,  if  the  reservation  has 
been  made  for  the  poor  and  the  indigent  alone,  the  rich  and 
the  dhimmis  are  barred  from  its  use.  It  is  not  lawful  to 
make  a  reservation  for  the  rich  alone,  leaving  out  the  poor, 
or  for  the  dhimmis  alone,  leaving  out  the  Moslems.  Again, 
if  a  reservation  has  been  made  for  the  animals  of  sadaqah 
alone  or  for  the  horses  of  the  soldiers  alone,  other  cattle 
may  not  be  pastured  on  the  reservation  grounds. 

The  restrictions  established  as  to  the  persons  who  might 
use  the  reservation  grounds  continue  in  force,  but  if  a  re- 
servation in  favor  of  a  special  class  should  be  sufficient  for 
the  whole  population,  then  the  whole  population  is  allowed 
to  use  the  reservation  grounds,  but  a  reservation  made  for 
all  the  people  may  not  be  restricted  to  the  rich  alone  on  the 
ground  that  the  reservation  grounds  are  not  sufficient  for 
all.  As  to  whether  in  this  last  case  the  reservation  may  be 
restricted  to  the  poor  alone,  there  have  been  two  different 
opinions. 

When  a  piece  of  land  has  been  already  converted  into  a 
reservation  and  later  a  person,  disregarding  such  reser- 
vation, encloses  it  for  his  own  private  use,  in  case  the  reser- 
vation is  one  that  has  been  made  by  the  Prophet  himself, 
the  act  of  enclosure  is  unlawful  and  the  interloper  is  ousted 
from  the  land.  Especially  is  this  true  when  the  reasons  for 
which  the  reservation  was  made  still  exist,  since  the  act  of 
the  Prophet  may  not  be  set  aside.  If,  however,  the  reser- 
vation had  been  made  by  one  of  the  imams  after  the 
Prophet,  then  one  view  of  the  matter  is  that  later  enclosure 
is  unlawful  just  as  in  the  case  of  the  reservations  made  by 


516  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

the  Prophet  himself,  but  the  other  view  of  the  matter  is 
that  the  reservation  is  overruled  by  the  act  of  enclosure 
and  the  land  becomes  the  private  property  of  the  person 
who  enclosed  it,  since  the  Prophet  said  explicitly :  "  He  who 
develops  waste  lands  becomes  their  owner ".  Moslem 
rulers  are  not  allowed  to  take  money  for  the  use  of  pasture 
lands,  whether  waste  or  reservation  lands,  because  the 
Prophet  said :  "  The  Moslems  are  partners  in  three  things : 
water,  fire,  and  grass  ".  Al-Shafi'i x  says  that  if  a  person 
who  is  not  entitled  to  graze  his  cattle  on  the  reservation 
grounds  does  so,  the  most  that  can  be  done  is  to  prevent 
him  from  grazing  his  cattle,  and  that  he  is  not  punished  or 
fined  for  it. 

According  to  Abu  Yusuf,2  forests  belonging  to  no  per- 
son may  be  used  by  every  body  for  picking  up  fire-wood, 
and  this  is  true  if  it  is  not  known  that  the  forest  is  private 
property.  This  applies  also  to  meadows  (marj)  and  wild 
fruits  and  honey;  that  is,  every  one  is  entitled  to  help  him- 
self to  them.  In  the  case  of  meadows,  people  are  entitled 
to  their  use  even  if  the  meadows  should  be  private  prop- 
erty.3 According  to  the  Malikites,4  one  may  not  use  grass 
growing  on  private  meadows,  but  one  may  use  grass  (kola) 
growing  on  lands  left  uncultivated,  provided  it  does  not 
cause  the  land  owners  any  damage. 

Woodlands  (mithtatab)  and  pasture  lands  in  which  the 
people  of  a  village  are  known  to  pick  fire-wood  and  pasture 
their  cattle  are  the  exclusive  property  (milk)  of  those  people, 
and  therefore  they  may  exercise  in  their  regard  all  the  rights 

1  Umm,  vol.  iii,  p.  272. 

2  Yusuf,  pp.  58-9. 

*  Apparently  this  is  on  account  of  the  hadith  to  the  effect  that  in 
water,  fire  and  grass  all  Moslems  are  partners. 

4  Kharashi,  vol.  v,  p.  77. 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN 

of  property  and  prevent  others  from  their  use.  They  should 
not,  however,  use  this  right  if  the  woodlands  and  pasture 
lands  in  question  are  more  than  sufficient  for  their  needs  and 
consequently  no  prejudice  would  result  in  allowing  their 
use  to  others.1  The  Malikites  apparently  agree  with  the 
Hanifites  in  granting  the  village  people  the  exclusive  use 
of  their  woodlands  and  pasture  lands,  for  they  consider 
them  as  the  harim  of  the  village.  They  nevertheless  grant 
the  imam  the  right  to  make  concessions  of  such  lands 
(iqta')  to  individuals,  should  the  public  interest  require  it 
(bi  'l-nazar).2 

The  doctors  discuss  fishing  and  hunting  from  a  purely 
religious  standpoint,  e.  g.,  whether  or  not  the  devotional 
formula  (tasmiyah)  :  "  In  the  name  of  God  the  merciful 
and  the  Clement "  should  be  pronounced  before  the  act  of 
fishing  or  hunting,  or  when  the  meat  of  the  game  is  "clean" 
for  eating  purposes,  etc.  The  relation  of  the  subject  to  the 
state  is  not  discussed  at  all.  It  would  appear  from  the  general 
trend  of  the  discussion  that  the  matter  escaped  entirely  the 
control  of  the  state,  except  in  so  far  as  the  failure  of  the 
Moslems  to  fulfill  their  religious  duties,  namely,  the  fard, 
ivajib,  sunnah,  etc.,  came  under  the  cognizance  of  the  muh- 
tasib  or  public  inspector,  who  was  appointed  in  order  to  see 
that  those  duties  were  performed  and  the  delinquents  pun- 
ished.3 These  purely  religious  views  will  not  therefore  be 
discussed  here  beyond  stating  that  in  general  fishing  and 
hunting  were  allowed  (ja'is),  as  between  the  fisher  or 
hunter,  and  God.4 

1  Articles  91,  97,  100  and  105  of  the  Ottoman  Land  Code  (QdnHn- 
ndtneh  Arddi)  have  been  framed  in  practically  the  same  spirit. 

a  Dardir,  vol.  ii,  pp.  181,  183. 

8  See  Mawardi,  pp.  404-32,  also  375-4°3- 

4  It  was  already  explained  in  Part  I  (chapter  on  Classification  of  the 
Shan'ah  Values)  that  the  doctors  distinguished  between  the  predomi- 


5i8  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Water.1  Following  the  hadith  according  to  which  the 
Moslems  are  partners  in  water,  fire  and  grass,  water  is  con- 
sidered as  res  nullius  (mitbah)  and  belongs  to  the  person  who 
"  occupies  "  (ihraz}-  it,  but  it  is  not  considered  "  occupied  " 
until  it  has  ceased  to  run,  that  is,  until  it  is  placed  in  a  vessel 
or  a  water-tight  well  or  basin.  Consequently,  water  found 
in  conduits,  and  rivers,  or  in  wells  and  basins  which  are  not 
water  tight  is  considered  as  res  nullius  (mubah)  even  if  the 
conduits,  river-beds,  wells  or  basins  should  be  private  prop- 
erty.8 A  fortiori  this  is  true  of  water  found  in  lakes  and 
seas.  Such  water  therefore  as  has  not  been  "  occupied  "  is 
the  common  property  of  all,  and  every  one  is  entitled  to  its 
use  for  drinking  purposes  (shafah),  whether  for  himself 
or  his  animals,  provided,  however,  the  animals  do  not  ex- 

nantly  religious  and  the  predominantly  worldly  or  legal  values.  The 
distinction  often  expressed  in  the  Hanifite  books  by  the  use  of  the  two 
words  diydnah  and  qatfd'  is  along  the  same  line.  Thus  it  may  be  one's 
religious  duty  to  do  a  certain  thing  (diydnah}  although  one  might  not 
be  forced  judicially  (qadd')  to  do  it.  For  details  on  hunting  and  fish- 
in,  see  Majma',  vol.  ii,  p.  450;  Hiddyah,  vol.  ix,  p.  42;  Majallah,  art. 
1292  et  seq;  Minhdj,  vol.  iii,  p.  293;  Dardir,  p.  173;  Kharashi,  vol.  v, 
p.  77;  Ibn  Rushd,  B.,  p.  368.  For  details  concerning  diydnah  and  the 
state  enforcement  of  the  sharl'ah  values,  see  Tech.  Diet.,  p.  503;  Ma- 
wardi,  pp.  118,  128,  134-40,  141-2,  160,  375,  376-8,  378-81,  404-8. 

1  Mabsiit,  part  xxiii,  p.  161 ;  Majma',  vol.  ii,  p.  440 ;  Yusuf,  p.  53 ; 
Hiddyah,  vol.  ix,  p.  12;  Durar,  p.  186;  Durr,  vol.  ii,  p.  710;  Babr,  vol. 
viii,  p.  242;  'Alamkiriyyah,  vol.  v,  p.  580;  Kasani,  vol.  vi,  p.  188;  /ami', 
vol.  ii,  p.  281;  Majallah,  arts.  1262  et  seq.;  Mawardi,  pp.  313-22; 
Ansari,  vol.  ii,  p.  453;  Wajiz,  p.  243;  Minhdj,  vol.  ii,  p.  179;  Kharashi, 
vol.  v,  p.  73. 

1  Ihrdz  legally  means  the  act  of  occupying  a  thing  which  is  common 
property  and  does  not  belong  to  any  one  person  in  particular  (mubdh*)  ; 
it  may  be  actual  or  hypothetical.  The  latter  consists  in  preparing  the 
means  of  actual  occupation,  as  in  the  case  of  collecting  rain  in  a  vessel 
placed  outdoors  for  that  end.  (Majallah,  art.  1248.) 

*  Yusuf,  p.  55,  1.  17;  Mabsiit,  part  xxiii,  pp.  164-5;  Kasani,  vol.  vi,  p. 
188,  1.  — 2;  I  ami',  vol.  ii,  p.  281;  Path  al-Mu'in,  vol.  iii,  p.  416;  cf. 
Majallah,  art.  1251;  Mawardi,  p.  319. 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN 

haust  the  entire  supply  of  water.  Moreover,  it  is  not  per- 
missible to  sell  such  water,  or  rent  its  use,  since  it  is  res  nul- 
lius.  The  owner  of  the  adjoining  land,  however,  may  pre- 
vent people  from  using  it,  if  they  can  obtain  drinking  water 
elsewhere.  In  the  contrary  case,  the  owner  of  the  land 
is  asked  either  to  grant  a  right  of  passage,  or  to  fetch  some 
water  himself.  If  he  fails  to  do  so,  he  may  be  forced  by 
use  of  arms.  The  right  of  drinking  extends  even  to  the 
case  of  water  already  "  occupied  ",  provided  that  the  per- 
son who  "  occupied  "  it,  has  more  water  than  he  himself 
needs.  In  this  last  case,  however,  the  person  asking  for 
water,  in  taking  it  by  force,  may  not  use  arms,  and,  further- 
more, is  obliged  to  pay  the  price  of  the  water  he  used.1 

According  to  the  Malikites,2  the  water  of  privately  owned 
wells,  basins,  springs,  and  rivers  is  considered  like  privately 
owned  water,  such  as  water  contained  in  a  vessel.  The 
owner  of  such  water  may  prevent  others  from  its  use  and 
may  even  sell  it,  although  he  is  recommended  to  allow  its 
free  use.  He  is,  however,  obliged  to  allow  its  use,  if  there 
is  danger  of  death  from  thirst. 

This  unconditional  right  to  use,  as  regards  water  that  has 
not  been  occupied  by  any  one,  such  as  water  found  in 
basins,  wells,  rivers,  etc.,  is  limited  only  to  use  for  drink- 
ing or  cooking  purposes,  because  use  for  irrigation  or  other 
similar  purposes  is  conditioned  upon  the  nature  of  the  water 
as  follows: 

(i)  Water  of  seas  or  the  great  natural  rivers,  such  as 
the  Euphrates,  the  Tigris,  etc.  Such  water  may  be  used 
by  every  one,  for  irrigation,  turning  mills,  and  otherwise. 
And  every  one  may  divert  a  river  from  them.  According 
to  the  Mabsut,3  the  use  of  the  river  is  not  allowed  if  the 
diversion  of  part  of  its  water  lessens  its  water  to  a  degree 

1  Mabsut,  part  xxiii,  p.  166.  *  Kharashi,  vol.  v.  p.  73- 

*  Part  xxiii,  p.  178. 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

prejudicial  to  acquired  interests,  or  if  the  use  of  its  water 
for  power  involves  the  danger  of  overflow,  should  the  dam 
later  break. 

(2)  Water  of  small  natural  rivers.     If  the  people  of  a 
village  desire  to  divert  part  of  the  water  of  such  a  river  to 
their  lands,  they  may  do  so  only  if  this  does  not  prejudice 
the  interests  of  the  earlier  settlers   (ahl).     According  to 
al-Mawardi  these  latter  may  irrigate  their  lands  whenever 
they  need  to  do  so,  unless  the  level  of  the  river  is  not  high 
enough  for  irrigation,  and  needs  to  be  dammed.     In  such 
case,  the  landowner  situated  highest  up  the  river  dams  the 
river  and  draws  off  the  water  needed  first,  then  the  one 
next  to  him,  and  so  on  down  the  line.     As  regards  the 
amount  which  each  owner  may  draw  off  before  allowing 
the  water  to  go  to  the  next  owner,  the  Prophet  is  said  to 
have  allowed  a  level  as  high  as  the  ankles,  but  al-Mawardi 
remarks  that  the  Prophet's  precedent  was  meant  for  the 
particular  case  in  question,  and  that  the  amount  varies  with 
the  nature  of  the  land,  the  kind  of  crop,  the  time  of  sowing, 
the  season,  and  the  consideration  whether  the  river  is  per- 
manent or  intermittent.     The  Hanifites,  on  the  basis  of  a 
hadith  related  by  Ibn  Mas'ud,  hold  that,  on  the  contrary, 
the  right  to  dam  the  river  first  belongs  to  those  situated 
lowest,  and  as,  regards  the  hadith  in  question,  they  dispose 
of  it  on  the  ground  that  it  applies  to  cases  where  the  water 
is  abundant-1     According  to  the  Malikites,2  the  settlers  situ- 
ated higher  up  the  stream  irrigate  their  lands  first  until  the 
water  rises  as  high  as  the  ankles.     If,  however,  settlers 
situated  lower  had  developed  their  lands  earlier,  and  there 
is  danger  of  their  crops  being  destroyed  should  they  come 
after  those  situated  higher  up  the  stream,  they  come  before 
the  latter. 

(3)  Water  flowing  in  artificial  beds,  such  as  the  water 

1  Mabsu},  part  xxiii,  p.  163.  a  Kharashi,  vol.  v,  p.  76. 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN  52i 

of  a  river  or  canal  dug  by  the  people  of  a  village,  or  the 
water  of  wells  and  pools.  Such  water  is  the  exclusive  right 
of  the  owners  of  the  bed  and  others  may  not  use  it  for  irri- 
gation, even  if  the  water  should  be  amply  sufficient  for  all. 
The  expenses  of  dredging  or  repairing  the  natural  rivers 
falls  upon  the  public  treasury,  if  there  are  funds  in  it; 
otherwise,  it  is  assessed  on  the  people.  According  to  the 
Hanifites,  in  the  case  of  the  rivers  which  are  owned,  the 
expense  is  upon  the  owners,  and  if  the  river  is  not  of  the 
"  private  "  (khtiss)  kind,  the  owners  are  forced  to  contribute 
to  the  expense.  The  doctors  disagree  as  to  the  meaning  of 
"  private  ",  some  saying  that  the  term  may  be  applied  to  a 
river  owned  by  forty  persons,  others,  by  one  hundred,  and 
still  others,  by  one  thousand.  The  view  recommended  by  the 
'Alamkiriyyah  l  is  that  this  matter  should  be  left  to  the  de- 
cision of  the  mujtahids.  As  regards  the  mode  of  assess- 
ment, according  to  Abu  Hanifah  each  landowner  contributes 
equally  to  the  expense  only  for  the  part  fronting  on  his 
land  and  above  it,  not  for  the  part  below  it,  but  according 
to  his  two  disciples,  the  entire  expense  is  assessed  on  all  the 
partners  in  proportion  to  their  shares.  The  argument  of 
the  latter  is  that  each  partner  benefits  from  the  entire 
river,  since  even  those  situated  up  JJie  stream  need  the 
lower  part  of  the  stream  for  the  drainage  of  the  surplus 
water  after  the  irrigation  of  their  land.  Abu  Hamfah's 
argument,  on  the  other  hand,  is  that  the  expense  of  dredg- 
ing is  assessed  in  consideration  of  the  right  of  irrigation, 
and  this  right  is  not  furthered  by  the  dredging  of  lower 
parts  of  the  river.  As  regards  the  drainage  of  the  surplus, 
one  need  not  concern  himself  about  it.  Moreover,  one 
might  turn  off  the  stream  at  a  point  further  up  the  stream, 
should  that  be  necessary.2 

1  Vol.  v,  p.  579- 

1  Mabsiit,  part  xxiii,  pp.  173-4. 

For  details  on  the  subject  of  waters,  consult  the  sources  indicated, 
also  Durar  al-Hukkdm  (esp.  vol.  iii,  pp.  5*6,  5*7,  537)  and  Bruno. 


522  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

Markets,  Schools,  Mosques,  Inns,  Streets,  and  Other 
Public  Domain.1  The  Hanifite  texts  do  not  consider  this 
subject  unless  it  be  incidentally,  e.  g.,  in  connection  with 
the  treating  of  encroachments  on  public  roads.2  The  Sha- 
fiite  texts,  on  the  other  hand,  devote  to  it  special  sections 
under  such  titles  as  Common  Benefits  (manafi'  mushtara- 
kah),  or  Irfaq  and  Irtifaq,  meaning  by  the  latter  two  words 
the  granting  and  the  enjoyment  of  the  use  of  a  thing  re- 
spectively, as  contrasted  with  the  ownership  in  that  thing.3 

The  general  principle  applying  to  the  public  places  in 
question  is  that  the  person  who  came  first  is  entitled  to 
their  use  on  condition  that  he  respects  the  rights  of  the 
others,  and  that  his  title  lapses  as  soon  as  he  gives  up  his 
use  of  them.  In  the  case  of  the  use  of  roads  no  fees  may 
be  charged  by  the  imam  or  his  governors.  Here  are  a  few 
details. 

Any  person  may  sit  by  the  road  for  rest  or  for  trade 
without  a  permit  from  the  imam,  and  he  may  protect  him- 
self against  the  sun  by  a  mat  or  the  like,  provided  that  in 
doing  so  he  does  not  obstruct  the  traffic.  Some  say  that  the 
dhimmis  do  not  enjoy  this  privilege,  but  others  hold  the  con- 
trary view-  The  imam  may  grant  to  a  person  the  use  of  a 
part  of  the  road  for  trade  purposes,  but  he  may  not  charge 
a  fee  for  it,  neither  may  he  grant  the  ownership  (iqta'  tam- 
llk)  of  that  part.  According  to  al-Mawardi,  in  the  absence 

1  Mawardi,  pp.  325-9;  Ansari,  vol.  ii,  pp.  449-52;  Minhdf,  vol.  ii,  p. 
176;  Wajiz,  p.  242. 

1  Cf.  Majmae,  vol.  ii,  p.  512;  Majallah,  arts.  1254  et  seq. 

*  The  information  here  given  is  derived  almost  entirely  from  the  indi- 
cated Shafiite  sources,  since  the  Hanifite  views  on  this  subject  are 
isolated  and  incidental.  Suffice  it  to  say  that  according  to  the  latter, 
the  general  principle  in  regard  to  the  use  of  common  property  (mubdh) 
is  that  every  one  is  entitled  to  it  on  condition  of  not  prejudicing  the 
general  public  interest.  The  Malikite  sources  are  equally  silent.  (Cf. 
Kharashi,  vol.  v,  p.  71.) 


PUBLIC  DOMAIN 

of  a  grant  on  the  part  of  the  imam,  if  a  person  goes  away 
from  the  place  he  occupied,  he  may  not  the  next  day  claim 
priority  on  the  basis  of  previous  occupation,  but  the  first 
comer  is  entitled  to  it.  Malik  holds  that  when  a  person  is 
well  known  as  the  occupant  of  a  particular  place,  he  is  al- 
lowed a  title  to  that  place  in  order  to  avoid  dispute.  Al- 
Mawardi  observes  that  although  there  is  an  advantage  in 
this,  it  would  nevertheless  amount  to  transferring  streets 
from  the  category  of  free  things  (mubah)  to  that  of  private 
property  (milk).  The  view  expressed  in  the  Minliaj  con- 
cerning traders  is  like  that  held  by  Malik,  for  according  to 
it,  the  occupant  of  a  place  does  not  forfeit  his  title  to  it  by 
mere  departure,  unless  he  gave  up  his  trade,  or  his  absence 
extends  for  a  period  long  enough  to  result  in  a  loss  of  his 
custom.  However,  a  person  who  occupied  part  of  the  road 
for  rest  forfeits  his  right  by  merely  walking  away  from  it. 

The  person  who  sits  habitually  in  a  place  in  a  mosque 
for  rendering  legal  opinions  (fatwa) ,  or  teaching,  or  follow- 
ing the  lectures  of  a  teacher  is  like  the  person  who  occupies 
a  part  of  the  road  or  market  for  trade.  If,  however,  he  is 
occupying  the  place  for  prayer,  he  forfeits  his  place  by  de- 
parting from  it.  Nevertheless,  if  he  went  away  for  a  neces- 
sity and  intends  to  come  back,  he  does  not  forfeit  his  title 
for  the  prayer-meeting  in  question  even  if  he  did  not  leave 
his  coat  to  indicate  his  intention.  According  to  al-Mawardi, 
in  the  case  of  the  great  mosques  and  worshiping  places, 
the  muftis,  etc.,  may  not  occupy  a  place  in  them  without  the 
permission  of  the  imam,  if  the  custom  is  to  that  effect. 
According  to  Malik,  if  a  mufti,  etc.,  is  known  to  sit  in  a 
certain  place,  he  is  entitled  to  it.  Al-Mawardi  holds  that 
he  forfeits  his  right  by  going  away  from  it.  Al-Ansari 
and  al-Gazzali,  on  the  other  hand,  agree  with  Malik. 

According  to  al-Mawardi,  people  may  use  the  courtyards 
of  mosques  and  worshiping  places,  if  this  does  not  interfere 


524  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

with  the  religious  functions;  otherwise  they  are  kept  from 
them,  and  the  imam  may  not  allow  them  to  use  such  places. 
There  is  divergence  of  view  as  to  whether  people  need  the 
permission  of  the  imam  for  using  such  places.  According 
to  Malik,  as  quoted  by  al-Kharashi,  praying  places  (mas- 
jid)  situated  in  the  desert,  may  in  the  absence  of  other 
places  be  used  for  taking  shelter  in  them  and  eating  dry 
food  such  as  dates.  It  is  not,  however,  lawful  to  engage 
in  irreverent  practices  while  in  such  praying  places,  except 
when  life  is  in  imminent  danger. 

Nomad  people  who  travel  from  place  to  place  in  the  coun- 
try, grazing  their  cattle,  are  entitled  to  the  place  where  they 
camp  until  they  leave.  Such  people  may  be  allowed  by 
the  imam  to  settle  in  a  place  if  this  is  not  prejudicial  to  the 
interests  of  travelers. 

As  regards  the  inns,  watering  places,  schools,  and  other 
public  buildings  or  pious  foundations  of  similar  nature,  their 
use  belongs  to  the  first  comer,  and  may  not  extend  beyond 
the  customary  length  of  time,  unless  the  founder  of  the  en- 
dowment stipulated  to  the  contrary  (shart  waqif).  When 
there  is  no  stipulation,  only  the  faqihs  may  take  up  their 
residence  in  the  schools,  although  the  general  public  may 
visit  them  and  enjoy  their  shelter  for  a  short  time.  Ex- 
cept in  the  case  of  travelers'  inns,  where  the  travelers  may 
not  stay  longer  than  three  days  and  nights  unless  it  be  be- 
cause of  rain  or  bad  weather,  or  fear  of  danger,  the  occu- 
pants of  public  buildings  are  not  molested  while  they  are 
pursuing  the  object  for  which  the  building  is  intended. 
Thus  the  students  lodged  in  an  educational  institution 
(madrasah)  are  let  alone  until  the  end  of  their  studies,  or 
until  they  give  them  up.  Such  people  do  not  forfeit  their 
title  by  going  away  to  attend  to  some  necessary  business. 


CHAPTER  XV 
SUMMARY  AND  CONCLUSION 

ACCORDING  to  Mohammedan  theory,  as  already  ex- 
plained, the  revenue  of  a  Mohammedan  state  falls  into  the 
two  classes  of  religious  and  secular  revenue.  The  religious 
revenue  is  derived  from  the  Moslems  and  is  chiefly  made 
up  of  the  so-called  sakat  taxes.  The  secular  revenue,  on 
the  other  hand,  is  collected  from  non-Moslems  especially 
and  consists  principally  in  the  jizyah,  the  kharaj,  and  the 
fifth  levied  on  spoils  of  war,  mines,  and  treasure-trove. 

According  to  the  Hanifites,  the  sakat  taxes  comprise  the 
sakat  of  animals  (sawaim),  the  zakat  of  gold  and  silver, 
and  the  articles  of  trade,  and  finally,  the  sakat  of  produce 
or  tithe.  Theoretically  the  sakat  applies  to  property  only 
when  it  is  productive.  This  theoretical  limitation,  how- 
ever, is  far  less  sweeping  than  might  at  first  appear.  In  fact, 
animals  which  are  pastured  are  considered  productive  for 
that  very  fact.  Gold  and  silver  are  regarded  as  always  pro- 
ductive in  virtue  of  their  very  essence.  Likewise  agricul- 
tural produce  is  always  assumed  to  be  productive,  since  it 
is  under  all  circumstances  subject  to  sakat.  In  all  of  these 
three  cases,  practically  according  to  all  of  the  three  schools 
with  which  we  have  been  mainly  concerned,  the  zakat  is 
considered  to  apply  to  the  physical  identity  ('ayn)  of  the 
object  as  distinct  from  its  commercial  value.  On  the  con- 
trary, articles  ('urud)  which  are  not  subject  to  sakat  on  the 
basis  of  physical  identity  under  one  of  the  three  heads  men- 
tioned, pay  sakat  on  the  basis  of  their  commercial  value, 
and  it  is  only  with  reference  to  them  that  the  theoretical 

525 


526  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

limitation  of  productivity  above  referred  to  may  be  said  to 
have  had  significance.  Such  articles  are  considered  produc- 
tive only  in  so  far  as  they  answer  the  technical  description 
of  articles  of  trade,  that  is,  only  in  so  far  as  they  are  ac- 
quired in  the  process  of  trade  with  the  express  or  implied 
intention  of  trade.  When  due  account  of  all  theoretical 
limitations  is  taken,  the  three  kinds  of  zakat  mentioned  vir- 
tually reduce  themselves  to  zakat  of  flocks  and  herds,  zakat 
of  commercial  capital,  and  zakat  of  agricultural  produce  or 
tithe,  respectively.  When  it  is  further  considered  that 
flocks  and  herds  and  agricultural  produce,  on  the  one  hand, 
and  commercial  capital,  on  the  other,  practically  exhausted 
all  the  kinds  of  property  then  existing,  it  becomes  apparent 
that  zakat  in  its  various  forms  virtually  constituted  a  gen- 
eral property  tax.  Allowance,  of  course,  must  be  made  for 
the  above-mentioned  qualification  of  productivity  which  re- 
sulted in  the  exemption  of  such  potential  trade  articles  as 
were  intended  for  consumption,  or  at  least  failed  to  be 
articles  of  trade ;  as  well  as  for  the  limitation  of  nisdb  which 
caused  the  exemption  of  property  falling  short  of  the  re- 
quired minimum. 

With  respect  to  collection,  the  most  important  point  to 
emphasize  is  the  distinction  between  apparent  and  non- 
apparent  property.  While  the  zakat  of  apparent  property, 
namely,  animals  and  agricultural  produce,  is  collected  and 
disbursed  by  the  state,  the  zakat  of  non-apparent  property, 
namely,  gold  and  silver  and  articles  of  trade,  is  disbursed 
to  the  beneficiaries  of  zakat  directly  by  the  property  owners 
themselves.  The  zakat  of  non-apparent  property  came 
under  state  control  only  in  so  far  as  the  owners  passed  with 
it  the  public  collectors  stationed  on  the  public  roads 
('ashirs).  Without  attempting  to  anticipate  the  discussion 
of  the  relation  between  theory  and  practice  reserved  for 
Part  TIL,  let  it  be  said  here  that  this  theoretical  distinction 


SUMMARY  AXD  COXCLUSJON  507 

between  apparent  and  non-apparent  property  very  strongly 
suggests  that  the  Mohammedan  experience  with  zakat  as  a 
general  property  tax  very  closely  followed  that  of  other 
people,  namely,  that  the  greater  part  of  the  tax  was  ulti- 
mately borne  by  the  owners  of  tangible  as  distinct  from  in- 
tangible, or  in  the  present  case,  of  apparent  as  distinct  from 
non-apparent  property. 

The  zakat  beneficiaries  are  specified  in  the  Koran  and 
in  the  main  consist  of  those  members  of  the  Moslem  com- 
munity who  need  assistance,  such  as  the  poor,  wayfarers, 
and  debtors  among  them.  The  zakat  raised  in  a  locality  is 
disbursed  to  the  zakat  beneficiaries  of  that  locality.  The 
imam,  however,  may  under  certain  circumstances  disburse 
the  zakat  of  one  locality  to  the  beneficiaries  of  another,  for 
instance,  on  the  ground  that  the  latter  are  godlier.  The 
imam  may,  moreover,  disburse  the  entire  proceeds  to  one 
class  of  beneficiaries  to  the  exclusion  of  the  others,  or  even 
to  one  single  individual,  provided  that  he  does  not  disburse 
to  any  one  beneficiary  more  than  a  certain  maximum.  This 
maximum  is  a  very  arbitrary  standard  which  entirely 
ignores  the  special  needs  of  the  beneficiary. 

To  cite  only  a  few  of  the  important  Shafiite  and  Malikite 
differences  in  the  matter  of  zakcit  taxes,  the  Shafiite  defini- 
tion of  pasture  animals  (sawa'im),  which  according  to  the 
Hanifites  are  the  only  animals  subject  to  zakat,  is  broader, 
while  the  Malikites  go  even  further  and  collect  the  zakat 
on  every  animal,  pastured  and  non-pastured.  The  Shafiites 
take  zakat  largely  out  of  state  control  by  virtually  assimi- 
lating apparent  property  to  non-apparent  property.  The 
Malikites,  on  the  contrary,  require  even  the  zakat  of  non- 
apparent  property  to  be  paid  to  the  state  collector.  In  the 
matter  of  disbursement,  the  Shafiites  consider  the  bene- 
ficiaries specified  in  the  Koran  as  the  real  owners  (musta- 
hiqq}  of  the  zakat  that  has  been  collected,  and  consequently 


528  MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

they  reduce  to  the  minimum  the  power  of  the  imam  to  dis- 
burse the  zakut  according  to  his  own  discretion.  For  in- 
stance, they  do  not  allow  an  arbitrary  exclusion  of  indi- 
vidual beneficiaries  or  classes  of  beneficiaries,  nor  do 
they  allow  the  transfer  of  sakat  from  one  locality  to  an- 
other. The  Malikites,  unlike  the  Shafiites,  give  the  imam 
in  this  respect  considerable  power,  more  in  fact  than  the 
Hanifites.  The  amount  which  may  be  given  to  a  bene- 
ficiary, according  to  both  the  Shafiites  and  the  Malikites,  is 
far  less  arbitrary  than  is  the  case  with  the  Hanifites,  and 
makes  proper  allowance  for  the  peculiar  circumstances  of 
each  case. 

Of  the  secular  revenue,  the  fifth  levied  on  mines  and 
treasure-trove  hardly  deserves  discussion  beyond  the  state- 
ment that  mines  and,  in  so  far  as  it  was  not  buried  by  Mos- 
lems, also  treasure-trove,  are  considered  a  case  of  spoils  of 
war,  the  fiction  being  that  like  the  spoils  of  war  they  were 
originally  the  property  of  the  infidels  and  became  Moslem 
property  by  conquest.  They  are  therefore  treated  like 
spoils  of  war. 

The  jizyah  is  a  poll-tax  levied  on  the  male  non-Moslem 
subjects  of  the  Moslem  state  for  their  humiliation  and  as 
payment  for  the  security  of  life  and  property  which  they 
enjoy;  also,  as  the  monetary  equivalent  of  the  military 
service  which  they  owe  the  Moslem  state,  but  for  which 
their  unbelief  renders  them  unfit.  Its  rate  varies  according 
to  the  financial  capacity  of  the  tax  payer.  The  tax  is  levied 
on  such  persons  only  as  may  lawfully  be  killed  in  war, 
namely,  on  persons  other  than  women,  children,  and  monks 
retired  from  the  world,  and  it  is  abrogated  upon  their  con- 
version to  Islam. 

Finally,  the  kharaj  is  a  tax  on  land  in  proportion  to  its 
produce  or  fixed  according  to  its  area.  The  kharaj  is  levied 
on  the  so-called  kharaj  lands,  and  this  is  true  even  when 


SUMMARY  AND  CONCLUSION  529 

the  lands  are  owned  by  Moslems.  The  rates  of  kharaj  are 
based  on  the  precedent  of  the  calif  Omar,  and  where  no 
precedent  is  available,  on  the  tax-bearing  capacity  (t&qah) 
of  the  land.  Although  the  actual  kharaj  rates  may  never 
exceed  the  particular  rates  assessed  by  Omar,  they  may  be 
reduced  below  them,  should  the  tax-bearing  capacity  of  the 
land  require  it.  However,  the  upper  limit  of  this  capacity 
has  been  fixed  at  the  high  point  of  one-half  of  the  entire 
produce,  because,  as  the  Hanifite  doctors  are  wont  to  put  it, 
"  a  half-and-half  division  is  the  very  quintessence  of  jus- 
tice ".  As  a  lower  limit,  one-fifth  of  the  produce  has  been 
recommended.  The  fixed  khar&j  is  levied  on  land  irrespec- 
tive of  its  cultivation,  provided  that  it  can  be  cultivated. 
The  proportional  khar&j,  on  the  contrary,  is  levied  only 
when  a  crop  has  been  raised. 

In  the  expenditure  of  secular  revenue,  the  following  two 
cases  are  possible :  ( i )  The  revenue  is  secured  through  the 
instrumentality  of  definite  persons  who  thereby  acquire 
special  rights  to  it.  The  spoils  of  war,  mines,  and  treas- 
ure-trove are  of  this  type.  They  constitute  the  so-called 
booty  revenue  and  belong  to  the  persons  who  secured  them, 
namely,  the  army,  the  miner,  or  the  finder  respectively,  the 
state's  share  in  them  being  only  one-fifth.  This  fifth  is  dis- 
bursed according  to  a  Koranic  prescription.  (2)  It  is  not 
secured  through  the  instrumentality  of  any  particular  per- 
son, and  therefore  inures  to  the  benefit  of  Moslems  at  large. 
Such  revenue  constitutes  the  so-called  fa'y  revenue  and  is 
disbursed  by  the  imam  to  meet  the  general  expenses  of  the 
state,  such  as  stipends  of  functionaries  and  soldiers,  con- 
struction and  repair  of  roads,  etc.  The  kharaj  and  jizyah 
are  the  principal  items  of  the  fa'y  revenue. 

With  respect  to  fa'y  revenue,  the  Shafiites  require  one- 
fifth  of  it  to  be  disbursed  according  to  a  Koranic  prescrip- 
tion in  the  same  way  as  the  fifth  of  booty  revenue  levied 


530 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


as  a  tax  by  the  state.  The  remaining  four-fifths,  accord- 
ing to  al-Shafi'i,  is  disbursed  by  the  imam  for  the  stipends 
of  soldiers  and  for  other  military  purposes,  but  according 
to  later  Shafiites,  the  imam  may  disburse  it  also  for  civil 
purposes.  The  Malikites,  here,  too,  differ  from  the  Sha- 
fiites and  agree  with  the  Hanifites,  and  in  fact  outdo  the 
latter.  For  according  to  the  Malikites,  the  imam  has  full 
discretion  in  the  disbursement,  not  only  of  the  entire  fafy 
revenue,  but  also  of  the  fifth  of  booty  revenue. 

The  outstanding  feature  of  Mohammedan  financial 
theory  is,  if  one  may  put  it  so,  its  dual  nature  due  to  the  dis- 
tinction between  religious  and  secular  revenue  above  re- 
ferred to.  The  standards  used  with  respect  to  the  former 
revenue,  therefore,  differ  essentially  from  those  used  with 
respect  to  the  latter.  The  zakat  taxes,  for  instance,  are  pri- 
marily a  religious  obligation  as  between  every  Moslem  and 
God,  and  the  function  of  the  state  as  regards  them  re- 
solves itself  into  one  of  police — namely,  of  seeing  that  the 
obligation  is  performed.  The  secular  taxes,  on  the  con- 
trary, were  purely  civil  obligations — in  so  far  as  a  thing  in 
those  times  could  be  purely  civil  and  free  of  religious  im- 
plication— which  found  their  justification  in  the  power  of  the 
stronger  or  at  least  in  a  quid  pro  quo  relation.  The  dhimmis 
must  pay  the  jizyah,  because  they  have  been  conquered  and 
deserve  humiliation.  This  is  the  Koranic  conception.  It 
was  later  tempered  by  the  additional  justification  that  the 
dhimmis  enjoy  security  of  life  and  property,  and  should 
pay  for  it.  This  fundamental  distinction  between  religious 
and  secular  revenue  accounts  for  much  of  the  difference  in 
the  theories  concerning  them.  Since  zakat  is  primarily  a 
religious  obligation,  the  question  of  its  discharge  as  be- 
tween the  tax  payer  and  God  is  the  fundamental  question. 
The  mere  payment  of  the  zakat  to  the  state  could  not  there- 
fore be  sufficient  by  itself,  unless  it  was  also  accompanied 


SUMMARY  AND  CONCLUSION  53 1 

by  its  discharge  as  a  religious  obligation.  This  principle 
pushed  to  its  logical  conclusion  would  mean  that  the  state 
could  not  collect  the  zakat  by  force,  should  the  zakat  payer 
refuse  to  settle  it  of  his  own  free  consent,  for  it  is  a  well- 
known  principle  that  a  religious  obligation  can  validly  be 
discharged  only  when  performed  of  one's  own  free  will. 
We  have  already  seen  how  the  doctors  reconciled  this  theo- 
retical requirement  with  fiscal  necessity.  Again,  the  zakat 
debt  lapses  upon  the  death  of  the  property  owner ;  debts  of 
secular  taxes  do  not.  Indebtedness  exempts  from  zakat ; 
it  does  not  from  secular  taxes.  The  zakat  may  often  be 
disbursed  by  the  owner  directly  to  the  zakat  beneficiaries; 
the  secular  taxes  must  always  be  paid  to  the  state.  The 
zakat  payer  is  believed  when  he  claims  to  have  himself  dis- 
bursed his  tax  dues ;  the  payer  of  secular  taxes  is  not.  The 
collectors  of  zakat  are  not  subject  to  audit;  those  of  secular 
taxes  are-  There  is  an  untaxable  minimum  in  zakat,  but 
none  in  secular  taxes. 

Another  marked  characteristic  of  Mohammedan  theory 
is  its  dialectical  and  legalistic  nature.  The  examples  that 
might  be  cited  to  support  this  assertion  are  legion,  and  it 
is  a  case  where  the  only  difficulty  is  that  of  selection.  Here 
are  a  few  illustrations  of  dialectical  discussion:  Goats  pay 
zakat  like  sheep,  because  the  word  ganam  occurring  in  the 
Prophetic  sayings  (hadlth)  means  both;  on  the  other  hand, 
for  instance,  mules  do  not  pay  zakat  because  they  are  not 
mentioned  anywhere  in  the  sources.  The  zakat  of  camels, 
when  paid  in  kind,  is  settled  in  females  only,  because  the 
gender  used  in  references  to  them  in  the  sources  is  the 
feminine.  Again,  the  differences  of  view  as  to  the  age  of 
sheep  acceptable  in  payment  of  zakat  in  kind,  all  center  in 
meanings  of  words.  The  zakat  may  not  be  given  to  a  slave 
because  the  word  "  give  "  used  in  the  sources  means  to 
transfer  the  ownership  of  a  thing,  and  the  slave  is  legally 


532 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 


incapable  of  owning  property.  The  zakat  may  not  be  dis- 
bursed to  fewer  than  three,  because  the  plural  in  which 
number  the  word  is  construed  in  the  sources  cannot  apply 
to  fewer  than  three.  The  zakat  may  not  be  disbursed  to  a 
rich  person  and  yet  it  may  be  disbursed  to  tyrannical  rulers, 
for  the  latter,  although  they  appear  to  be  rich,  in  reality 
are  poor  in  consequence  of  the  fact  that  their  property 
would  not  be  sufficient  to  make  proper  restitution  for  all 
their  misdeeds.  The  zakat  beneficiaries  have  a  legal  title 
on  the  zakat  proceeds,  because  the  preposition  li  (to)  oc- 
curring in  the  Koranic  verse  expresses  such  a  title.  Again, 
and  perhaps  this  is  the  most  absurd  case  of  legalistic  con- 
sistency,— if  a  nisab  (taxable  minimum)  of  property  is  de- 
stroyed before  payment  of  the  zakat  due  on  it,  and  the  owner 
acquires  a  new  nisab,  zakat  is  due  on  it  upon  the  lapse  of 
a  year,  if  the  first  nisab  was  destroyed  (halak)  accidentally? 
On  the  contrary,  no  zakat  need  be  paid  on  the  acquired  nisab, 
if  the  first  nisab  was  destroyed  (istihlak)  by  the  owner 
wilfully,  for  instance,  for  purposes  of  consumption,  or  by 
sale, — notwithstanding  that  the  owner's  intention  may  have 
been  exactly  to  escape  the  zakat  on  the  new  nisab.  The 
reason  for  this  seeming  paradox  is  that  in  case  of  wilful 
destruction  the  zakat  on  the  nisab  destroyed  becomes  a  debt 
upon  the  owner  who  thereby  escapes  zakat  on  the  acquired 
nisab.  In  case  of  accidental  destruction,  however,  the  zakat 
on  the  nisab  destroyed  lapses  and  the  second  nisab,  being 
free  of  debt,  becomes  subject  to  the  zakat i.1 

Here  are  a  few  cases  of  legalistic  discussion:  The 
crossbreds  do  not  pay  zakat  if  the  mother  was  wild, 
because  the  sperm  of  the  father  has  been  in  a  legal  sense 
destroyed  by  that  of  the  mother,  and  so  the  offspring 
acquires  the  status  of  the  mother.  Cunning  to  escape  zakat 

1  Bahr,  p.  220. 


SUMMARY  AND  CONCLUSION 

before  it  has  fallen  due  is  lawful,  since  no  encroachment  upon 
acquired  rights  is  yet  involved.  A  zakat  debt  of  three 
bushels  of  good  wheat  may  not  be  paid  in  terms  of  four 
bushels  of  inferior  wheat  of  equal  value,  because  this  is  a 
case  of  usury  (riba).  The  insane  do  not  pay  zakat,  no 
matter  how  rich,  because  zakat  is  an  obligation  (taktif), 
and  does  not  apply  to  a  person  who  is  not  endowed  with 
understanding  ('aql).  Should  a  person  exchange  his 
camels,  on  which  zakat  is  to  fall  due  at  the  end  of  the  year, 
for  other  camels,  just  a  day  before  the  completion  of  the 
year,  he  is  not  subject  to  sakat,  because  camels  are 
subject  to  zakat  in  virtue  of  their  physical  identity,  but 
the  camels  received  in  exchange  are  not  the  very  same  ani- 
mals and  therefore  are  subject  to  zakat  only  after  a  year 
has  elapsed  after  their  acquisition.  An  animal  is  consid- 
ered one  of  pasture  only  in  case  it  has  been  pastured  for 
at  least  slightly  over  half  a  year,  since  otherwise  the  quality 
of  being  a  pasture  animal  would  not  have  been  predominant, 
and  in  law  importance  attaches  to  the  predominant  only. 
Non-Moslems  do  not  pay  a  toll  on  pigs  by  themselves,  be- 
cause pigs  are  non-fungible  (qlmi)  goods,  and  to  collect  a 
toll  on  them  on  the  basis  of  value  would  be  tantamount  to 
collecting  a  part  of  the  pigs  themselves,  but  pigs  are  pro- 
hibited to  Moslems.  Pigs,  however,  are  subject  to  toll  if 
found  in  connection  with  an  article  that  by  itself  is  fit  to 
pay  toll,  such  as  wine,  because  in  such  case  the  pigs  would 
merely  be  an  appurtenance  (taba()  of  the  wine,  and  it  is  a 
legal  principle  that  what  is  not  allowed  by  itself  may  be 
allowed  incidentally  (bi  }l-taba(). 

Notwithstanding  that  dialecticism  and  legalism  are  the 
dominant  notes  of  the  entire  discussion,  here  and  there 
considerations  of  a  practical  nature  are  referred  to,  at  least 
to  reinforce  the  argument  based  on  dialectical  and  legal  rea- 
soning. As  one  might  expect,  this  happens  most  often  with 


MOHAMMEDAN  THEORIES  OF  FINANCE 

respect  to  matters,  such  as  kharaj  (land-tax),  on  which  the 
sources  are,  relatively  speaking,  silent.  Thus  the  kharaj  is 
levied  on  a  piece  of  land  regardless  of  whether  it  is  owned 
by  a  Christian  or  a  Moslem.  The  kharaj  rates  are  accord- 
ing to  the  tax-bearing  capacity  of  the  land.  Indebtedness 
does  not  exempt  from  kharaj  or  jizyah  as  it  does  from 
zakat.  The  jizyah  rates  vary  with  the  financial  means  of 
the  tax  payer.  The  zakat  of  animals  (sawaim)  is  given 
precedence  over  that  of  trade,  because  as  al-Shafi'i  pleads, 
the  property  owners  "  often  do  not  pay  "  their  zakat  of 
trade,  whereas  the  zakat  of  animals  is  collected  by  the  state 
itself  and  may  not  be  so  easily  escaped.  Again,  with  re- 
spect  to  the  zakcit  of  gold  and  silver,  a  Hanifite  doctor  in- 
vokes administrative  expediency  to  avoid  incommensurate 
numbers. 

It  is  hardly  surprising  that  Mohammedan  financial  dis- 
cussion is  dialectical  and  legalistic.  As  already  explained, 
Mohammedan  financial  theory  is  an  integral  part  of  fiqh 
or  Mohammedan  law.  Mohammedan  law  in  turn  is  de- 
rived from  the  revealed  sources  of  the  Koran  and  the  Pro- 
phetic utterances  and  conduct  (sunnah),  and  its  avowed 
object  (gayah) ,  as  the  doctors  put  it,  is  "  beatitude  in  the 
two  worlds."  There  is  a  body  of  revealed  truth  from  which 
one  must  not  stray,  and  to  which  one  must  adapt  himself 
as  best  he  can.  Evidently  the  only  element  of  flexibility  in 
a  situation  of  this  sort  lies  in  reading  new  meanings  into 
the  old  letter,  unless  it  be  that  the  letter  itself  is  ignored, 
and  this  has  often  been  done  and  is  being  done.  In  fact, 
the  layman  at  large  prefers  the  latter  course  and  leaves  the 
task  of  casuistry  to  the  doctors  who  are  responsible  for  the 
theory  and  should  also  be  responsible  for  its  salvation. 

It  may  not  be  amiss  to  conclude  with  a  few  generaliza- 
tions as  to  the  characteristics  of  the  three  schools  that  have 
most  claimed  our  attention.  The  Hanifites,  at  least  so  far 


SUMMARY  AND  CONCLUSION 

as  financial  theory  is  concerned,  base  their  arguments  more 
on  dialectical  and  legal  considerations  than  on  precedent  in 
the  wide  sense  of  the  Koran,  the  Prophetic  utterances 
and  conduct,  and  the  practice  of  the  early  califs.  The 
Shafiites,  on  the  other  hand,  put  the  emphasis  on  precedent 
at  the  expense  of  scholastic  reasoning.  Finally,  the  Mali- 
kites,  while  resembling  the  Shafiites  in  the  neglect  of  scho- 
lastic methods,  are  yet  not  quite  so  keen  on  precedent.  In 
short,  the  Hanifite  treatment  may  be  said  to  be  a  more  or 
less  abstract  and  schematic  statement  of  the  principles  and 
rules  of  conduct  pertaining  to  finance  involved  in  the  pre- 
cedent mentioned,  more  for  the  sake  of  scholastic  satisfac- 
tion than  for  practical  reasons;  the  Shafiite  treatment,  on 
the  other  hand,  is  an  ordered  statement  of  those  principles 
and  rules  of  conduct  with  a  view  to  attaining  as  faithful  a 
statement  of  the  divine  law  as  possible;  finally,  the  Mali- 
kite  treatment  is  an  attempt  at  a  more  or  less  ordered  state- 
ment of  those  same  principles,  however,  more  with  a  view 
to  practical  exigencies  and  the  solution  of  concrete  actual 
problems,  than  is  probably  true  of  either  of  the  other  two 
schools. 

Part  III.,  where  the  origins  of  the  Mohammedan  tax 
system  and  its  relation  to  theory  will  be  discussed,  will  con- 
stitute a  later  monograph. 


INDEX 


This  index  is  intended  primarily  as  a  glossary,  giving  therefore  only 
the  names  which  have  not  been  explained  every  time  they  recur.  It 
also  facilitates  reference  to  the  topics  treated,  especially  those  that  are 
not  indicated  in  the  table  of  contents  or  are  difficult  of  access.  Ex- 
pressions in  English  should  be  looked  up  under  the  principal  name, 
e.  g.t  article  of  trade,  under  article.  Numbers  indicate  pages. 


Abbreviations  and  signs,  8,  9,  158 

Abu  Hanlfah,  69,  70,  138 

Abu  Yusuf,  140 

ada,  115,  116 

'afw,  234. 

ahl  al-sadaqah,  473 

Ahmad  Ibn  Hanbal,  145 

ojza,  323  fn. 

a'mdl,  497 

amdn,  355 

'dmil,  316 

'dmmi,  127 

amr  bi  'l-ma'ruf,  350 

'aqd  (a/-)  dhimmah,  357 

'arad  (or  'ar</),  270 

'arif,  476fn. 

article  of  trade,  271 


'dshir,  314 

(a/-)  A  $1,  73,  177 

assignment,  485 

athar,  143 

al-Awza'i,   146 

'ayn,  208,  334fn. 

'azlmah,  in 

baqr,  251 

bdtil  (butldn),  in 

bayt-al-mdl,  423 

Bibliography,  157;  biographical, 
159;  bibliographical,  163;  lexi- 
cological, 165;  Koran,  167;  Tra- 
dition, 169;  science  of,  172; 
Principles  of  law,  173;  Appli- 
cations of  law,  177;  Hanifite, 
177;  fatwa  collections,  184;  Sha- 
fiite,  186;  Malikite,  190;  Other 
schools,  194;  Differences,  194; 
Sects,  194;  Miscellaneous,  195 


bid.d'ah.  322,  38sfn. 

bid'ah,  36 

bint  labun,  249 

bint  ma k had,  249 

Books,  the  six,  39 

booty   (revenue),  409,  425,  430 

bustdn,  379 fn. 

cause,  74;  (sabab),  109 

claims,  277 

collection,  of  zakdt,  296;  resort 
to  intuition  in,  339;  use  of  cun- 
ning in,  342;  of  fa'y,  396 

collectors,  kinds  of,  304,  305,  310; 
share  of,  443;  of  zakdt,  296;  of 
fa'y,  396;  audit  of,  498 

commentaries,  157 

Companions,  61 ;  books  on,  159 

condition,  109 

continuity,  39 

convenient,  81 

cunning,  use  of,  342 

custom,  106;  see  law. 

damdn,  236fn. 

ddr  al-'ahd,  354 

ddr  al-harb,  354 

ddr  al-isldm,  354 

Dawud  Ibn  'Ali,  146 

dayn,  334fn. 

debtors,  share  of,  447 

dhimmah,  292,  334fn. 

dhimmi,  357 

dimdr,  214 

dinar,  264fn. 

dirham,  264fn. 

discharge,  323fn. 

discontinuity,  45 

discontinuous  (report),  45 

dissolution,  of  year,  219 

537 


538 


INDEX 


diwdn,  477fn. 

diydnah,  5i7fn.,  323 fn. 

dogmatics,  27 

Domain,  Public:  development  of 
waste  lands,  502;  concession  of, 
500;  of  cultivated  lands,  507; 
of  mines,  511;  pastures,  516; 
reservation  of,  513;  forests,  516; 
fishing  and  hunting,  517;  water, 
518;  markets,  schools,  etc^  522 

effective  (cause),  77,  81,  109 

Emigrants,  473fn. 

evidence,  short  ah,  23 

expenditure:  of  zakdt,  439;  of 
booty,  465;  of  fa'y,  470;  mili- 
tary stipends,  477;  tax  grants, 
484;  public  treasury,  423 

faidah,  224 

faqih,  24 

for',  74       ' 

faraq,  291  fn. 

fard.,  112;  —  'ayn,  112;  —kifdyah, 
112 

fdsid  (fasdd),  in 

fdsiq  (fisq),  120 

fatdwa  or  fatdwi  (plural  of 
fatwa),  127;  fatwa  collections, 
157,  158,  184,  190,  194 

fa'y,  425 fn.;  — revenue,  425,  430 

fiqh,  24,  28,  71  fn.;  books  on,  177- 
194 

fishing,  517;  see  Domain. 

Followers,  62 

forests,  516;  see  Domain. 

ganam,  254 

ganimah,  409,  425  fn. 

gayr  Idzim,  mfn. 

hadith,  36,  71  fn.;  works  on,  169; 
science  of,  38;  works  on,  172 

hadith-fote,  68 

hdl,  49ofn. 

baldl,  114 

har dm,  115 

harbi,  354 

harim,  506 

Helpers,  475fn. 

Hijrah,  31,  474fn. 

fcikdyah,  2$fn. 

hima,  513 

bM,  286fn. 

hiqqah,  240 

hirz,  2iofn. 

hudnah,  355 fn. 

hukm,  24fn. 

huqiiq  allah,  28 


huqtiq  'ibdd,  28 
hwrmah,  no 
'ibdddt,  24 
ibdhah,  no 
i/fa,  127 
*£fa.sr,  5i8fn. 
ihtisdb,  494fn. 

lAy<*',  503 

t/aroA,  95 

t;w*^  60;  see  law. 

ijtihdd,  117 

ikhrdj,  49ofn. 

't//a/»,  74 

't/w,  25 fn.,  71  fn.,  99,  143 

'ilm-al-hadith,  38;  books  on,  172 

'Urn  al-tafsir,  34,  168 

imdm,  368 

imdn,  137 

impeachment   (of  a  hadith),  51 

indigent,  443 

individual   (report),  44 

intention  of  trade,  206,  271;  of 
payment,  323 

iqtd1,  484 

Islam,  136 

isndd,  45 

istidldl  (mursal),  102 

istifd',  494fn. 

istifddah,  222 

istihbdb,  307 

istihsdn,  73,  94  and  fn.;  see  law. 

isti$hdb,  73,  103;  —al-hal,  103; 
— al-mddi,  103 

istisldb,  73,  86,  102 

istisnd',  26fn. 

ithbdt,  490fn. 

/odto'  (a/t),  249,  255 

(/i  '/-)  /ad^rf,  187 

/a't^,  114 

;ar»fr,  395 

;i>ya/t,  399,  486fn. 

>M'/,  348 

just  (justice),  120 

kaffdrah,  2O9fn.,  337fn. 

kdfir,  137 

kaldm,  27 

karm,  379fn. 

khardj,  377,  486;  — tnuqdsamah, 
378 ;  — muqdta'ah,  378fn. ;  — m«- 
wazgaf,  378;  — wastfah,  378 

Kharijites,  136 

knowledge,  axiomatic,  43;  infer- 
ential, 43;  acquisitional,  43fn. 

khultah, 


INDEX 


539 


Koran,  30 ;  commentaries,  34, 167 ; 
concordance,  169 

kufr,  137 

lands,  tithe-,  360;  khardj-,  364; 
amiriyyah—,  375;  property  in, 
364  and  fn.,  365,  366,  367,  3^9, 
370,  371,  375,  376  and  fn.,  509 
and  fn.,  (in  Syria  and  Egypt) 
387;  tax-bearing  capacity  of, 
381,  waste  lands,  500.  Cf.  Do- 
main. 

lapse,  of  year.  218 

law.  sources  of :  Koran,  30 ;  Pro- 
phetic conduct,  35,  113;  con- 
sensus of  the  community,  60; 
analogy,  67;  istihsdn,  94;  isti- 
$db,  102;  istijhdb,  103;  con- 
duct of  Companions,  104;  of 
Followers,  106;  custom,  106; 
previous  dispensations,  107;  use 
of  opinion,  controversy  on,  68; 
rules  of,  117 

Idcim,   uifn. 

madh-hab,  133;  see  school. 

ma'dhun,  290 

madrasah,  524;  see  Domain. 

inahgur,  115 

makrth,  114 

mdl  (revenue),  200,  261,  273 

Malik,  141 

tnandub  (nadb),  114 

tnann,  286fn. 

man$u$  'alayh,  78 

markets,  522;  see  Domain. 

masdlih,  share  of,  469 

mash-hur,  44 

ma$lahah,  102 

mawquf,  uifn. 

milk,  207 

mine,  415  (cf.  Domain)  ;  conces- 
sion of,  511 

mithli,  334fn. 

mithqdl,  2O4fn. 

Moslem,  135;  orthodox,  135;  her- 
etical, 135 

mosques,  522;  cf.  Domain. 

mu'allafah  (qulubuhum),  449 

mu'dmaldt,  29 

mu'dratfah,  91 

mubdh,  114,  518 

muddrabah,  385 fn. 

mudlr,  275 

mufti,  127 

muhddanah,  35$fn. 

Muhammad  Ibn  al-Hasan,  140 


mubtasib,  302,  350 

mujtahid,  117;  kinds  of,  121 

mukallaf,  90 

mukdtab,  2i3fn.;  share  of,  446 

mukhdbarah,  38510. 

mukus,  199,  337 

muld'im,  83 

(al-khabar  a/-)  munqatf,  45 

muqallid,  126 

mursal,  45 

tnusaddiq,  316 

musdqdt,  385  fn. 

musinn  (ah),  252 

musnad,  46;  Musnad,  169 

mustafid,  44fn. 

tnustafti,  127 

mustahabb    (istihbdb),   114 

musta'min,  355 

mutawdtir,  40 

muwdda'ah,  355 

muzdra'ah,  385 fn. 

nadrah  (nadrat),  417 

ndfidh,  iiifn. 

t»a^,  114 

noqrrf  (aw),  206,  221 

naskh,  89 

wow,  79,  157 

(a/-)  Nawddir,  126,  179 

ntfafc,  205 

pasture  lands,  516;  see  Domain. 

poor,  440 

productivity,  206 

pronunciation  of  Arabic  words,  8 

property,  (non-)  apparent,  209, 
296,  301 

purpose,  useful,  102 

qabdlah,  377 fn. 

qadd',  115,  5i7fn. 

(fi  '/-)  qadim,  187 

qawl,   157 

qirdt,  2O4fn. 

qirbah,  291  fn. 

qiyds,  67,  73 ;  see  law. 

quantities,  stated,  75 

rabb  al-mdl,  38sfn. 

raf,  4^ofn. 

rail  (or  rill),  286fn. 

rdwi,  48 

ra'y,  69,  71 

ra'y-folk,  68 

refusers   (of  zakdt),  302 

Relations,  467 

revenue,  kinds  of,  200,  425;  (in 
detail),  429;  sources  of  reve- 
nue: sakdt,  203;  tithe,  282; 


540 


INDEX 


financial  contribution  for  war, 
348;  land-tax,  377;  poll-tax, 
398;  tax  on  spoils  of  war,  409; 
on  mines,  413;  on  treasure- 
trove,  418;  on  estates  and  tolls, 
422 

rikds,  414  and  fn. 
rivers,  519;  see  Domain, 
roads,  522;  see  Domain. 

rukh$ah}  in,  115 

rukn,  109 

fa",  286fn. 

sabab,  109 

sadaqah,  204,  439fn.;  see  revenue. 

sadaqat  al-fitr,  207 in. 

sahih,  in,  I27fn. 

Sahib,  39,  169 

Sai,  298,  316 

salaf,  49fn. 

salam,  95 

sawdb,  132 

sawaim,  244 

sawm,  206 

schools,  133;  followers  of  a,  130; 
change  of  a,  130;  orthodox, 
133;  differences  of,  137;  Hani- 
fites,  138;  Malikites,  141;  Sha- 
fiites,  142 ;  Hanbalites,  145 ; 
Zahirites,  146,  524  (Domain). 

science  0»/m),  meaning  of,  25fn.; 
classification  of,  27 

al-Shafi'i,  73,  142 

shakk,  I32fn. 

shariah,  23 

shart,  109 

shdt]  2S4fn. 

sign,  109 

sihhah,  no 

spoils   (of  war),  409,  425fn. 

sunnah,  35,  113;  of  the  Compan- 
ions, 104;  of  the  Followers,  106; 
established,  46 

siirah,  33 

tabi'  (ah),  252 

Taglib  (tribe  of),  241 

taharri,  131 ;  use  of,  339 

tahjir,  506 

ta'lil  al-usiil,  78 


tamakkun  (min  al-ada),  328 

tamlik,  203,  213 

taqlid,  126 

tatawwu',  114 

tawqi',  494fn. 

text,  157;  esteemed,  123,  181 

tithe,  283 ;  see  revenue. 

thaman,  206 

thani  (yyah),  254,  255 

thawdb,  no,  112 

al-Thawri,    146 

transliteration  (of  Arabic  words), 
8 

transmitter,  48;  books  on  — s,  159 

treasury,  public,  423 

umm  walad   319 

unknown,  48 

'urad  (pi.  of  'ar$,  'arad),  270 

'ushur,  337 

Usul,  125,  177 

usul-al-din,  27 

usul-al-fiqh,  26,  28;  works  on,  173 

usury,  227,  228.  229fn.,  333 

value  (shart'ah),  24fn.,  109;  clas- 
sification of,  109 

wajh,  157 

wdjib,  no,  112 

wdli  al-sadaqdt,  316 

waqf,  362;  sale  of,  433 

Wdqi'dt,  126,  180,  184 

waqs,  265;    (pi.  awqds),  253 

waif,  78 

wasq,  286fn. 

waste  (land),  500 

water,  kharaj-,  360;  tithe-,  359 

the  way  of  God,  447 

wayfarers,  share  of,  449 

weight,  septimal,  264fn. 

wujtib,  no 

yad,  207 

sdhir,  50 

Zdhir-al-madh-hab,  125,  177 

Zdhir-al-riwdyah,  125,  177 

^a^af,  203,  of  animals,  244;  of 
gold,  silver,  and  articles  of 
trade,  261;  of  produce  (tithe), 
282 

sann, 


VITA 


THE  author,  Nicolas  (son  of)  Prodromos  Aghnides,  was 
born  of  Greek  parents  at  Kayabashi  (suburb)  of  Nigdeh, 
vilayet  of  Koniah,  Turkey,  1883.  He  received  his  first 
education  in  the  Greek  Community  School  of  his  native 
place.  From  1900  to  1903  he  attended  the  American  mis- 
sionary college  at  Marsovan,  Turkey.  During  the  next  year 
he  studied  at  the  French  school,  ficole  St.  Joseph,  Kadi- 
keuy,  Constantinople.  Subsequently,  he  took  up  a  law 
course  in  the  Imperial  Law  School  of  Constantinople,  where 
he  was  graduated  in  1909.  During  1910  he  practiced  at 
law.  In  1911  after  competitive  examination  he  obtained 
a  Turkish  Government  scholarship  for  study  at  Columbia 
University.  He  registered  there  in  the  Faculty  of  Political 
Science  and  received  the  degree  of  M.  A.  in  1913.  In  the 
same  year  he  registered  for  the  degree  of  Ph.  D.  He  has 
taken  courses  chiefly  under  Professors  E.  R.  A.  Seligman, 
H.  R.  Seager,  H.  L.  Moore,  W.  C.  Mitchell,  J.  B.  Clark, 
V.  G.  Simkhovitch,  F.  A.  Fetter,  J.  Schumpeter,  Karl  F. 
Th.  Rathgen,  H.  R.  Mussey,  R.  E.  Chaddock,  F.  H.  Gid- 
dings,  J.  H.  Robinson,  J.  T.  Shotwell,  W.  A.  Dunning,  and 
John  Dewey.  He  attended  the  Seminars  of  Professors 
E.  R.  A.  Seligman  and  H.  R.  Seager. 

54i 


/-"""I 

& 

s 

U'J 

cc 

UNIVERSITY  OF  TORONTO 
LIBRARY 

<• 
00 
CO 

rH 

Do    not    / 

8 

•• 
«, 

/ 

1 

<t 

re  move   /  ^ 

| 

1 

| 

< 

•• 

the   card 

a 

I 

\  ^J 

H 
0 

| 

4 

from    this  \  - 

| 

$ 

\ 

<» 

1 

s 

•t 

S 
"C 
a 
f. 

•     C 

*c 
* 

,  Pocket.          \ 

•• 

Acme    Library    Card    Pocket 

- 

.  1  'at.  "  Kef.  Index  ' 

Made  b-  LIBRARY  BUREAU